Skip to main content

Full text of "American and foreign investment bonds"

See other formats


R3 



' e.-tv^— 0— t-f 




?tatc QloUege of JVgriculturK 

^t (StOtnsll IniaerattH 
Ktljara. N. ^. 



Slibracy 



Cornell University Library 
HG4651.R3 
American and foreign 'nvestmen| bonds, 




3 1924 013 899 509 




Cornell University 
Library 



The original of tiiis book is in 
tine Cornell University Library. 

There are no known copyright restrictions in 
the United States on the use of the text. 



http://www.archive.org/details/cu31924013899509 



AMERICAN AND FOREIGN 
INVESTMENT BONDS 



^ 



AMERICAN AND FOREIGN 
INVESTMENT BONDS 



BY 

WILLIAM L. RAYMOND 




BOSTON AND NEW YORK 
HOUGHTON MIFFLIN COMPANY 



R3 



COPYRIGHT, 1916, BV WILLIAM L. RAYMOND 
ALL RISHTS RBSERVSD 



Published April iqib 

(LI >70o 



PREFACE 

Tms book has been put together from talks given to the writer's 
salesmen. The aim has been to discuss clearly and simply the 
leading classes of investment bonds. 

In trying to carry out this aim, the writer has confined himself 
mostly to a discussion of the factors entering into the intrinsic 
value of such securities. The material available is vast, compli- 
cated, and always changing. At the same time the broad prin- 
ciples which govern the safety of investment bonds are simple and, 
like the laws of nature, forever the same. 

From the point of view of the intrinsic value of American se- 
curities, the Great War in Europe has brought into high relief the 
resources and development of the United States. With the open- 
ing of the Panama Canal, the creation of an adequate merchant 
marine, and the establishment of a new banking system, this 
country should be placed in a position with relation to the business 
and finance of the world which it never has held before. Further- 
more, the United States may become the market for a consider- 
able amount of foreign govenmient securities. It is to-day, of 
course, the principal market for the bonds of its own States, mu- 
nicipalities, and corporations. 

It is hoped that this book may suggest some pomts of view of 
interest even to seasoned investors. 

The writer wishes to thank Mr. Francis G. Goodale, who has 
done a large part of the legal work — especially in Chapters HI, 
IV, V, and VI. The writer wishes also to thank friends who have 
read the manuscript. 

W. L. R. 

October 23, 1915. 



CONTENTS 

INTRODUCTION ix 

I. THE FIELD OF INVESTMENT I 

II. UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 5 

III. STATE BONDS 94 

IV. COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 140 
V. STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 62 

VI. PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 1 98 

VII. INDUSTRIAL BONDS 25 1 

CONCLUSION 295 

APPENDIX 297 

INDEX 3" 



INTRODUCTION 

Investment in bonds is a comparatively modem development. 
It has arisen out of the needs of governments and corporations to 
finance themselves on a scale larger than that pos- ju^jstj^gnt -^ 
sible from annual taxes or annual earnings. Its devel- bonds is a 
opment has been connected with the development modem 

of banking. development 

The banking business, in some form or other, has been carried 
on practically continuously from a period six himdred years be- 
fore the Christian era in Babylon ^ down through The banting 
the periods of Athenian * and Roman * domination bee^SrHS on 
of the civilized world, and again through the periods t™™o^^°* 
of the rise and development of the Venetian and times 
Florentine States, and the growth and commercial expansion of 
such countries as modem England, France, Germany, and the 
United States. 

As early as the twelfth century, the Republic of Venice obtained 
forced loans from its people. The State paid interest on these 
loans, but deferred payment of the principal to a Early govem- 
time "when the situation of affairs should permit me°t loans 
it." * Later Venice obtained from its citizens loans secured by the 
revenue from salt and by the income of the treasury for a certain 
number of years. ^ Florence borrowed of its bankers and pledged 
as security certain taxes and other revenues.® 

Government borrowing, by the issue of bonds or other evi- 
dences of debt, assimied a more or less regular form Government 
in France in the time of Francis I^ (1515-47), in France, Eng- 
England with the Revolution of 1688 and the Wars udteTsiSts 

' The Bankers' Magazine, London, August, 1877, pp. 720-21. 

' Macleod, The Theory and Practice of Banking (London, 1892), vol. I, p. 171. 

' Ibid., p. 161. 

* Dam, Histoire de la Ripublique de Venise (Paris, 1853), tome I, pp. 146-47. 

* Ibid., p. 147. 

* Perrens, Histoire de Florence (Paris, 1877), tome m, pp. 261-62. 

' Vtihrer, Histoire de la Dette Publigue en France (Paris, 1886), tome i, p. 2. 



X INTRODUCTION 

of William m,^ and in what is now the United States during the 
Revolutionary War.* 

In the early part of the nineteenth century, we find in France 
Eariy local Small amounts of local loans or debts of the com- 
loans mimes ' and in the United States borrowing on a 

considerable scale by our States and to a less extent by our cities. 

In the United States, the bond business before and during the 
Civil War was concerned principally with United States govem- 
The bond mcnt, State, and to a less extent municipal bonds. 

{•"si^inthe After that period, bankers became interested in 
financing the building of many of our railroads and 
during the past thirty years in furnishing money for the building 
and development of gas, street-railway, electric-light, and tele- 
This book will phonc properties. The financing of industrial con- 
paflyof^ cems through the issue of bonds is a development 
^fi^ld^"^ principally of the past twelve or fifteen years, 
dasses of bonds Jq the following pages, we will concern ourselves 
less with the history of borrowing than with the principles govern- 
ing at present the intrinsic values of leading classes of bonds. 

* Macleod, vol. i, pp. 441-48. 

' TetM Census, voL vn, pp. 299-301. 

' Hirst, The Credit of Nations (Washington, 1910), p. 96. 



AMERICAN AND FOREIGN 
INVESTMENT BONDS 



AMERICAN AND FOREIGN 
INVESTMENT BONDS 

CHAPTER I 

THE FflELD OF INVESTMENT 

The investment of funds so as to have the principal safe and at the 
same time obtain a reasonable income is an extremely difficult 
matter. The field is so large, the possibilities of mis- „. . , , 

, ,. 1 Ml 1 The investment 

take so numerous, that more than ordinary skill and of funds is 

, , . , difficult 

knowledge are required. 

As a general rule, funds should be invested when received. K 
investment is made when market prices are low as pm,ds gho^jj 
well as when they are high, an average price will be be invested 
paid and none of the funds will be left without re- 
ceiving some income. 

Funds may be placed in any one or more of the following prin- 
cipal channels of investment: — 

(i) Real estate and real-estate mortgages; Ji^lffnv'^t- 

(2) Bonds; ment 

(3) Stocks; 

(4) Collateral loans, commercial paper, and ordinary notes of 
firms and individuals. 

About collateral loans, commercial paper, and ordinary notes, 
we will say only a few words. This class of paper short-tenn 
belongs not so much to the subject of investment as p^p" 
to the subject of ordinary banking or loaning money for short 
periods. 

The other three principal kinds of investment — that is, in 
real estate and real-estate mortgages, in bonds and The three 
in stocks — may be said to furnish the ordinary SmTISInv^- 
field for investment. ™^°* 

The principal advantage that real estate has over other mediums 



2 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

of investment is its tangibility. The great disadvantage which 
. , , , real estate has is that it is difficult to sell quickly. 

Advantages and 

disadvanuges Another disadvantage is that the income is liable 
to be imcertain and at times may cease altogether. 

Real-estate mortgages are somewhat different. These run or- 
dinarily from one to five years, — perhaps most commonly three 
Real-estate yeais, — are tax exempt in many States, and are 
mortgages written Usually for about sixty per cent of the as- 

sessed value of the property. Such mortgages, when given by 
responsible persons and after proper examinations, ought to be 
reasonably safe mediums for investment. Even with mortgages 
that are finally paid off, however, the payment of the interest often 
is irregular. 

There remain to be spoken of in this very general survey of the 
Bonds and fi^ld of investment only bonds and stocks. For con- 
stocks venience, we wiU speak of stocks first. 

In a general way, stocks stand for the ownership of the business 
and the right to receive the net profits, whereas real-estate mort- 
Nature of gages or bonds stand for the prior claim on the prop- 

stocks gj.^y a^Q^ ^Q right to obtain a stipulated amount in 

interest before anything is paid in dividends to stockholders. 
Stocks always are junior to bonds and notes of the same corpora- 
tion. Often they represent to a large extent merely capitalization 
of earning capacity. There is no promise to pay a definite sum of 
money and no promise, as a rule, even to pay any income. The 
stocks of any corporation have, in this respect, merely the right to 
participate in earnings above operating expenses and fixed charges, 
when, as, and if earned by the corporation and ordered distributed 
by the board of directors. 

Many corporations have two classes of stock, preferred and 
common. Preferred stock usually is entitied to a certain dividend 
Classes of before anything is paid on the common. Sometimes 

stocks ^jjjg dividend is cumulative — that is, unless paid 

regularly, it becomes an accumulated charge against earnings. 
Many preferred stocks are preferred not only as to dividends, but 
as to assets in case of liquidation. 

^vKtmentjn The remaining important form of investment — 
ject of this book investment in bonds — is the subject of this book. 



THE FIELD OF INVESTMENT 3 

The first thing to notice about bonds is that they represent, as 
a rule, a promise to pay a definite sxim of money at Bonds imply a 
a given time, with, usually, a regular rate of interest. ^^^^^ promise 

The principal large classes of investment bonds are as follows : — 

(i) Government bonds. 

(2) State bonds. Principal classes 

(3) County, municipal, and district bonds. bonds 

(4) Steam-railroad bonds. 

(5) Public-service corporation bonds, or bonds of corporations 
suppl3dng water, gas, electric light and power, street-railway, 
or telephone service. 

(6) Industrial bonds or bonds of manufacturing and mercantile 



It may be well here to speak of what may be called the frame- 
work of bond investment. If we think of the bonds of the leading 
civilized nations of the world; then of the bonds of our _ , 

The frame- 
States and of our leading cities; then of the bonds of work of bond 

the principal trunk-line railroads connecting those 
cities; and then of the bonds of the street-railway, gas, electric- 
light and power, and telephone companies serving those cities; and 
then, if we add to those securities the bonds of the great industrial 
concerns, we have the framework around which is built practi- 
cally the entire structure of bond investment. 

We cannot say that any one class of bonds is always and without 
exception safer than another class, any more than we can say that 
bonds are always safer than stocks or always safer one class of 
than real estate. Each individual bond issue must be aiwaysTafer 
judged on its own merits, yet with due reference to ''^*° another 
the whole structure of investment, just as each case in common 

' In view of the fact that we do not discuss in this book the methods of dealing in 
or marketing bonds, we will say here that the two great markets in the United States 
for all kinds of bonds are the New York Stock Exchange and private bankers or bond 
dealers. Of the two markets, the latteris far and away the larger. The great bulk of the 
state, municipal, and public-service corporation bonds is marketed by private bankers. 
Original issues of steam-railroad and industrial bonds usually are sold first to clients 
by private bankers. The New York Stock Exchange may be said to be the great 
secondary market for railroad bonds and such other bonds as are listed there. All 
the other stock exchanges in the country, including the Boston, Philadelphia, and 
Chicago Exchanges, deal to a greater or less degree in bonds. 



4 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

law must be judged on its own merits taken in connection with 
the previously existing body of law, 

wiUdiscusssafe- ^ *^^ following pages, we will take up in a general 
ty of various way the features bearing on the safety of these vari- 

kiDos of bonds ,.ip,, 

ous kinds of bonds. 



CHAPTER n 

UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 

Government bonds either are simply promises to pay or ac- 
knowledgments of indebtedness, or else are promises General de- 
to pay and have some special security. In Europe, |ovSent 
government bonds often are referred to as "stocks." ''°°<^= 

The government bonds of most of the so-called great powers,, 
notably the United States, Great Britain, France, and Germany, 
are simply promises to pay or acknowledgments of ^^^^ ^^ ^j^^ 
indebtedness. In many cases these obligations have United states,, 
no maturity, — as British consols, French 3% rentes, France, and 
and German Imperial 3% bonds, — although often "^ 

reducible by purchase, as are aU old German Imperial bonds, by 
drawings, as are French 3% redeemable rentes,^ or by redemption 
at the option of the Government, as are British consols and Ger- 
man Imperial bonds. ^ Government bonds of the class described- 
above are payable, as a rule, out of the ordinary revenues and 
resources of the Government, whether such revenues are derived 
from customs duties, excise taxes, income taxes, or from any other 
available resources. 

In the cases of certain nations that do not have high credit, 
there are often special provisions to secure the payment of interest 
and principal of their government bonds: for instance, in the case 
of the Japanese Govenament 4!% sterling loan, put Government 
out at the time of the war with Russia, the bonds are time^^'ha^e^ 
secured by a charge on the annual net revenues of spedai security 
the Imperial Japanese Govenmient Tobacco Monopoly; ' in the 
case of the Argentine Republic Port of Buenos Aires 5% deben- 
tures, the bonds, besides being a direct obhgation of the Ar- 
gentine Government, are secured by a charge on the harbor 
works and their revenues and on other property; * in the case of 

' The Stock Exchange Official Intelligence for 1914 (London), p. 109. 

» Ibid., pp. 3 and 109. ' Ibid., p. 113. * Ibid., p. 96. 



6 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the Bulgarian Government 6% state mortgage loan of 1892, the 
bonds are secured by a first mortgage on certain state railways 
and on the harbors of Varna and Burgas, together with the present 
and future revenues and dues of those harbors; ^ in the case of the 
Mexican 5% external consolidated gold loan of 1899, the bonds 
are secured by special hypothecation of 62% of the import and 
export duties of the United States of Mexico; ^ in the case of the 
Greek Government 4% loan of 1902, the bonds are secured by a 
prior lien on the surplus receipts from certain assigned revenues,' 
by the surtax on tobacco deposited at the National Bank, and by 
a first Men on certain railroad property and the share in its net 
earnings accruing to the Government.* 

Broadly speaking, however, government bonds are to be thought 
of as representing simply the good faith and ability to pay of the 
No legal rem- governments or nations issuing the bonds. There 
dfifaufS^^' is no known method of collecting, against the wiU 
nations Qf ^j^g nation indebted, a government bond issue or 

the interest on it, except force. In the words of Professor Bas- 
table, it rests with the Government " within its own discretion to 
say whether or not it will meet its obligations." Again, he says, 
"An Act of Parliament repudiating the national debt woxild be 
quite as valid as any other measure."' Against a sovereign state, 
the only remedy is what has been called "collection by warship." 

Furthermore, a nation can borrow for any purpose that it 
sees fit — from a strictly productive purpose, like construction 
of railways, to a highly unproductive and wasteful 
borrow for purpose such as war. It can and often does borrow 
any purpose ^^^^ ^^ meet deficiencies in the revenue in times of 
peace — in other words, it can borrow to meet running expenses. 
Such a use of the borrowing power is far from desirable, but some- 
times it is necessary. There is no authority that can place 
restrictions on the purpose of borrowing or curb in any way a 
sovereign state or nation. 

* The Stock Exchange Official Intelligence for IQ14 (London), p. 100. 
' Ibid., p. 114. 

» Ibid., p. log. Revenues from the monopolies on salt, petroleum, matches, play- 
ing-cards, cigarette paper, and Naxos emery, from tobacco dues, from certain stamp 
dues, and from import duties collected by the custom-house at the Pirsus. 

* Ibid., p. no. • C. F. Bastable, Public Finance (2d ed., London, 189s), p- 6ii- 



UNITED STATES AISTD FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 



PRICES OF GOVERNMENT BONDS, JAITOARY, 1913 



Issue 


Price 


rield 
about 
(per 
cent) 




United States 
Panama,! 3%, 
due June i, 
1961 


102J and interest 


2.92 


This issue is not available to secure circula- 
tion of national banks. Exempt from all 
taxes national, state, and local. 


British 2i%, 
consols, cash'. . 


TSAflat 


333 


Redeemable at option of Parliament on and 
after April 5, 1923, at par. Interest Jan- 
uary s, April s. July S. and October 5. 


French 3% per- 
petual rentes '. . 


88^ flat 


3-39 


Interest January i, April i, July i, and 
October i. 


Italian 3i% rentes* 


96 flat 


3.6s 


Interest January i and July I, exempt from 
all Italian taxes present and future. 


German Imperial 
3%» 


77|flat 


391 


Redeemable at option of German Empire, 
after notice' to be fixed by law, at pai. 
Interest April i and October i. 


Austrian gold 4% 
1876' 


9i| flat 


4-43 


Interest April i and October i. 


Hungarian 4% 
gold rentes'. ... 


87 flat 


4.61 


Redeemable at option of the Government at 
any time. Interest January i and July i. 
Principal and interest exempt from all 
Hungarian taxes. 


Russian 4%, 
SeriesH' 


9of flat 


44S 


Redeemable by drawings at par January i 
and July i for repayment April i and Oc- 
tober I within 81 years from 1890. In- 
terest January i, April i, July 1, and Oc- 
tober I. Exempt from all Russian taxes. 


Russian s%, 1906' 


104 flat 


4.84 


Redeemable by annual drawings at par on 
and after February i, 1917, for repayment 
on May i following. Must be repaid in 
full by May i, 1956. Until May i, 1916, 
loan caimot be converted or called for re- 
payment. Interest May i and November 
I. Exempt from all Russian taxes. 


Japanese 4% 
sterling, 1910,' 
due June i, 
1970 


82 flat 


4-9S 


Redeemable at option of the Govenmient, 
on six months notice, on or after June i, 
1920, at par. Interest June i and Decem- 
ber I. Interest exempt from Japanese 
Income Tax. 


Japanese 45% 
sterling, 1905 » 
(2d Series), due 
July 10, 1925... 


94§ flat 


S.36 


Redeemable at option of the Government 
at any time, on six months notice, at par. 
Interest January 10 and July 10. Inter- 
est exempt from Japanese Income Tax. 



« See Untied Slates Treasury Department, Circular 52, July i, 1912 (Washington, 1913), P- I7. 

> The Stock Exchange Official Intelligence for 1914 (London), p. 3- • •fWi., p. 109. « Ibid,, p. iia. 

• /6ii., p. 97. 'Ibid.iP. 111. '/ii/., p. 118. ' /6<a., p. 119. • /Wi., p. 113. 



8 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

In view of this fact the question is, What is the real security, or 
what are the factors that go to make up the ability and wiUing- 
what is the ness of a Government to pay the interest and prin- 

real security? ^^^-^ ^f J^g bonds? 

If we approach this question first from the point of view of 
what some of the leading government securities have been selling 
Credit of the ^^^> — °^ from what may be called the point of view 
leading na- of the Credit of the leading nations, — we shall be 

tions as shown . , , ,,. , __ 

by the prices able to discuss it more mteUigently. The table on 
mentTondr^' page 7 shows the prices and the approximate net 
January, 1913 j^come basis ^ On which certain leading government 
bond issues sold in January, 1913." We have chosen this date be- 
cause it corresponds most closely with the date of reliable infor- 
mation available in regard to the nations issuing the bonds. These 
prices, as compared with those of 19 12, evidently show to a con- 
siderable extent the effect of the events leading up to the Balkan 
Wars and of the outbreak of those wars in the preceding autumn. 

The income basis on which the above government bonds sell 
reflects in a general way the credit of the nation issuing the obli- 
gations. As may be seen from the table. United States Govern- 
ment bonds sell to yield a smaller income, or, in other words, sell 
at a higher price than the bonds of any other of the leading civil- 
ized nations. British consols rank next, then French rentes, then 
Italian rentes, and so on in the order of the list. What are the 
reasons for these differences in price? In other words, why is the 
credit of the United States or of Great Britain, for instance, higher 
than that of Austria or Japan? 

Before going any further it may be well to inqviire who and 
^^ ^ what are the people responsible for these obligations, 
people What is their origin? What briefly is their history? 

fS^Me * What kind of people are they? What is their place 

obligations? .^ ^^ ^^^j^p 

' In the cases of issues having definite maturities, net income is determined by use 
of the usual bond tables; in the cases of issues without definite maturity, net income 
is determined by dividing the per-cent interest which the bonds pay by the per-cent 
selling price. Flat quotations, or quotations including accrued interest, are reduced, 
in figuring the yield, to an "and interest" basis. Quotations of all bonds except 
United States Government bonds are in per-cent sterling. 

' Prices of January 3, 1913. Price of United States bonds from Commercial and 
Financial Chronicle (New York), vol. 96, p. 50. Prices of foreign government bonds 
from the Statist (London), vol. 73, pp. S and 59. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 9 

Some of the nations issuing these obligations have their begin- 
nings in a remote past. All are peopled to a greater or less degree 
by a mixture of races, and all have occupied terri- Racial origin 
tory with boundaries intermittently changing. In a modem^^"^ 
general way, with the exception of Japan and to a ^^°^^ 
less extent of Russia, all the great modem nations — the United 
States, Great Britain, France, Germany, Austria-Hungary, and 
Italy — come from a mixture in varying degrees of the Germanic 
or Baltic tribes which overran the Roman Empire — 375 to 476 
A.D. — with the Latin races of the Empire. The Slavs or Wends, 
who at an early date appeared to be settled northeast of the Car- 
pathians in the basins of the Vistula, Pripet, and upper Dniester, 
were closely related in stock to the ancestors of the Baltic tribes, 
Prussians, Lithuanians, and Letts. The Roman historian Pliny 
speaks of Slavs along the Vistula and the Venedic Gulf — prob- 
ably the Gulf of Danzig. The Goths and Huns at one time were 
the conquerors of the Slavs. The Eastern Slavs became the Rus- 
sian people. They attacked the Empire on the lower Danube 
and reached the Don and the Volga.^ Later there took place an 
amalgamation or absorption by the Slav race of a variety of 
Ural-Altaic stocks, Turko-Tatars, Turko-Mongols, and various 
Caucasian races.^ The origin of the Japanese is uncertain. The 
aborigines were called Ainu — suggesting a close aflSnity with 
Europeans. The bulk of the population to-day, however, seems 
to be derived from a mixture of the Malay, Mongolian, and Man- 
chu-Korean types — with the Malay element predominant. In 
the course of many centuries, practically complete amalgamation 
has taken place.' Apparently the islands were invaded from the 
mainland of Asia. The earliest date of what is believed in Japan 
to be authentic history is 660 B.C.* 

The territorial and strategic position occupied by the so-called 
great powers to-day is the result of centuries of change, usually 
of countless wars, in all cases of generations of painful develop- 
ment. Even now in the Great European War Europe is being 

1 Encyclopedia Britannica (nth ed., 1911), vol. xxv, pp. 228-30. 

2 Ibid., p. 873. 

' Ibid., vol. XV, p. 165. 

* Carl Ploetz, Epitome 0/ Ancient, MeduBvd and Modern History (12th ed., Boston), 
P-33- 



lO AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

remade. Not only the territory, but the population, resources, 
Chan • power, and prestige of the great nations of the world 

leadership of are in the blast furnace. It has ever been so. This 
great war, to be sure, appears to be one of the colos- 
sal upheavals that occur only at long intervals; but civilization 
like nature never stands stiU. The scepter has passed from Egypt 
to Babylonia and Assyria, from Ass3Tia to Persia, from Persia to 
Greece, from Greece to Rome; it has rested for a time with the 
Venetian and Florentine Republics; it has passed to Spain, to 
France, to England: it is passing now to the United States of 
America — or so it would seem. All that is certain is that the 
leadership of civilization and the relative rank of the nations of 
the world vnR not remain forever the same. 

If we glance at the history of the leading nations of to-day, we 
shall be in a better position to understand their present status and 
Development Credit. Everybody is familiar with the origin and 
and rf'Se' development of the United States, and almost every- 
United States body has a good idea of English history from Roman 
times to the present. These are preeminently the nations which 
have developed the individualistic ideal and have evolved through 
patient struggle free institutions and constitutional government. 
They have based their institutions on the common law;^ and they 
have fought steadily for liberty, self-sufficiency, and equality 
imder the law. 

Modem France is a product of many forces and of many condi- 
tions. After the great Frankish Empire of Charlemagne was di- 
Outiineof vided through the Treaty of Verdun in 843 a.d., 

French there developed Germany from the East Frankish 

portion and France from the West Frankish. The 
people of the East Frankish kingdom were predominantly of 
Germanic stock, those of the West Frankish were predominantiy 
of Romance or Latin stock.^ Gradually there arose in France 
the familiar struggle between the central authority or king 
and the great nobles. At first the nobles were too strong for 
the king, and the central authority developed late. This is 

' See A. Lawrence Lowell, The Governments of Prance, Italy and Germany (Cam- 
bridge, 1914), p. so, and note beginning on p. 65. 
« Ploetz, p. 187. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS II 

one of the striking differences between French and English 
history.^ The struggle in France ended, however, in the almost 
complete victory of the central authority under Louis XIV. In 
that reign, what Buckle ^ has called "the protective spirit" ex- 
tended to every phase of government and even to every phase of 
intellectual activity. Individuality and the spirit of independence 
were dead. The seeming unity, strength, and prosperity of France 
under Louis XIV were seeming only. There followed, after a con- 
siderable delay, to be sure, the fierce but purifying flames of the 
French Revolution.' Then from democracy, rampant, xmrea- 
soning, atheistical,* there had to be evolved again, slowly and 
painfully, order and Hberty under law. Centralization remained 
to a great degree, — perhaps greater than ever, — but it was a 
centralization deriving its authority from the people instead of 
from a hereditary king.* Now we have a chance to read the latest 
chapter — the effort of republican France to regain something 
of the power and prestige among the nations of the world that it 
had before 1870 and to evolve a workable and stable system of 
parliamentary government. 

From the death of Charlemagne (814 A.D.) to the crowning of 
William I of Prussia as German Emperor (1871), what is now 
Germany has been most of the time broken up into „ ,,. 

1 r 11 1 . 1 rm Outline of 

a large number of small kingdoms or states. The German 
Holy Roman Empire — which endured not only as ^°^ 
a name, but as an ideal for over a thousand years — imder Charle- 
magne and under Otto I (936-73 a.d.) and his successors of the 
Hohenstaufen line was a great reality — a powerful united Em- 
pire.* Modern Germany — or Germany under the leadership of 
Prussia — really derives from the old North mark, or the mark or 

' Lowell, p. SI. 

* Henry Thomas Buckle, History of CivilizaHon in England (New York, 1858), 
vol. I, chap. XI. 

' Ibid., chap. xn. 

* The reason why the French Revolution attacked religion — why it set up the 
"Goddess of Reason" — was that the prerevolutionary writers like Voltaire and 
Rousseau attacked the abuses of the clergy even before they attacked the abuses of 
the Government. Church and State were, moreover, closely intertwined. The clergy, 
as in England before the Great Rebellion, stood on the side of the conservative — 
the reactionary element. (Buckle, vol. I, chaps, xi and xn.) 

» Lowell, p. 35. 

* James Bryce, The Holy Roman Empire (New York, 1904), pp. 2x5-16, and 384. 



12 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

boundary lying along both banks of the middle Elbe established 
by the Germans against the Wends or Slavs; just as Austria de- 
rives from the Bavarian Ostmark or East mark along the south 
bank of the Danube east of the river Ems, founded about 800 A.D.* 
In 1415, the German Emperor invested Frederick, Burgrave of 
Nuremburg, a Hohenzollem, with the mark Brandenburg — ly- 
ing east and west of the Elbe in the district about the old North 
mark.^ From that time until the formation of United Germany 
under William I, the only rulers who stand out conspicuously are: 
Frederic WiUiam, the Great Elector of Brandenburg, who wrested 
East Prussia from Poland * and carried out various internal re- 
forms; Frederic William I, who established a formidable army, 
left an overflowing treasury, and laid the foxmdation of the future 
power of Prussia; * and Frederic 11, the Great (1740-86), who 
added Silesia and PoUsh Prussia to his kingdom and revived the 
political and intellectual life of Germany under the leadership of 
Prussia.^ The successful war of Prussia and Austria against 
Denmark, by which the victors obtained Schleswig, Holstein, and 
Lauenburg (1864);^ the war of Prussia against Austria in 1866, 
by which Prussia obtained Schleswig-Holstein, Hanover, and 
other territory and established her supremacy over Austria in the 
leadership of Germany; ^ and the Franco-Prussian War of 1870 
resulted in the imification of Germany imder the leadership of 
Prussia and the establishment of modem Germany as a great 
power. 

Italy like Germany, since the fall of the Western Empire (476 
A.D.), has been torn and pieced together again and again. Odo- 
OutUneof vakar (Odoacer), leader of German tribes, after the 

itaUan faU of the Western Empire became ruler in Italy.* 

Later the Ostrogoths under Theodoric conquered 
Italy; and stiU later the Lombards conquered the country as far 
south as the Tiber.' For a long period portions of Italy were 

' Encyclopedia Britannica (1910), vol. m, p. 5, and vol. iv, p. 420. Ploetz, pp. 
194-96. For map of the old marks, see F. W. Putzger's Historischer Schtd-AUas 
(Bielefeld und Leipzig, 1895), p. 15. 

' Ploetz, p. 252, and Putzger, pp. 18-19. 

' Ploetz, p. 373, and Price ColUer, Germany and the Germans (New York, 1914), 
P-3I- 

♦ Ploetz, p. 397, and Collier, p. 33. » Collier, p. 36. « Ploetz, p. 506. 

' Ibid., p. 510. ' Ibid., p. 173. • Ibid., pp. 174-75. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS I3 

included in the old German Empire. Modem Italy dates from 
the war of France and Sardinia against Austria (1859) and the 
liberation of Italy from Austria.^ The outstanding figures of 
this period are Count Cavour and Victor Emmanuel. In 1861 
practically aU Italy, except Venice and the Papal territory, were 
united under one scepter.^ 

The thrones of Austria and Hungary — which latter country 
was inhabited as early as the ninth century a.d. by the Magyars, 
a nomadic Fimiish tribe, which gradually had made its way from 
the Ural region toward Europe ' — were occupied by the same 
ruler, at intervals, as early as the fifteenth century. In 1687, 
the hereditary succession to the throne of Hungary was conferred 
on the male line of Austria; and by the Pragmatic Sanction was 
allowed to pass, in case of necessity, to the female line. In accord- 
ance with this settlement, Maria Theresa, archduchess of Austria, 
ruled also as Queen of Bohemia and Hungary from 1740 to 1780. 
Austria was the leader of the German Confederacy Austria- 
formed toward the close of the Napoleonic wars and Hungary 
later renewed or reestablished. On the abdication of his imcle in 
1848, Francis Joseph I, the present Emperor, became Emperor 
of Austria. The Hungarian Diet refused to recognize his acces- 
sion, and an uprising of the Magyars against the House of Haps- 
burg resulted in the practical independence of Hungary.* The 
revolt finally was put down with the help of Russia. In 1867 
the old constitution of Hungary — which had been abohshed by 
Austria in 1849 — was restored; and Francis Joseph I, Emperor 
of Austria, was crowned King of Hungary.^ The Dual Monarchy, 
as it is called, probably contains the greatest diversity of races in 
contiguous territory and imder one government of all the great 
powers. 

The history of modem Russia begins with Peter I, the Great 
(1689-17 2 5). In the ninth century, bands of Swedes settled around 
Novgorod, subjugated the Slavs and laid the foun- Q^y^^ . 
dation of the future Empire of Russia.* For two Russian 
hundred and fifty years, ending in 1480, Russia was "^ °^ 

' Ploetz, p. 502. * Ibid., p. 503. • Ibid., pp. 193-94 and 277. 

* See Encychpadia BriUmnica (1910), vol. xm, p. 916. 

« Ploetz, pp. 278, 372, 398, 400, 483, 49S, 498. Sio-"- ' I^H; P- 208. 



14 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

in the hands of the Mongols. In the fourteenth centxuy, Moscow 
became the national center of Russia.^ Toward the close of the 
sixteenth century, Russians began to emigrate into Siberia and 
within eighty years had reached the Amur and the Pacific.^ Peter 
the Great, in his effort to Europeanize or modernize Russia, 
founded the city of St. Petersburg (1703).' The reign of Catherine 
n added much to the power and prestige of Russia. During her 
reign there took place the three divisions of Poland (1772, 1793, 
and 1795) which have been the cause of so much discord in Europe 
since.^ Vast in territory, with a population of ovej one hundred 
and seventy millions, Rxissia lacks and always has lacked one 
thing — an ice-free port. For one hundred years she has set her 
eyes on Constantinople, and is fighting for it in the present war. 
Only one other of the great powers remains to be discussed — 
Japan. We have spoken of the origin of the Japanese. At the be- 
ginnin g of historic times, according to the Japanese 
Japanese 66o B.C., the form of government in Japan was that 

'^ of an empire imder a Mikado.^ In the seventh 

century A.D., changes took place which resulted in the military 
obtaining predominance over the dvil power, and the actual gov- 
ernment passed from the Mikado into the hands of a usurping 
military chieftain — later called the Shogun. The final outcome 
of this system of dual government was a feudal system correspond- 
ing in large measure to that of mediasval Europe.* After 1680, 
the Shogun became a shadow and the great mass of feudal chiefs 
likewise. The government really fell into the hands of the vassals. 
This state of affairs, with its oppression, weakness, and anarchy, 
lasted until 1868. The revolution which involved the fall of the 
Shogimate and ultimately of feudalism, though essentially im- 
perialistic in its prime purposes, may be called democratic with 
regard to the personnel of those who planned and directed it. 
There took place under the guidance of the nobles and the Samu- 
rai a restoration of the administrative power to the Emperor.^ 
Japan in 1854 had been reopened to the Western world by the 

' Ploetz, p. 277. 

' Encyclopadia Britannica (nth ed.), vol. xxv, pp. 17-18. 

* Ploetz, p. 395. ' Ibid., pp. 411, 413-14. 

* Ibid., p. 33. • Ibid., pp. 212-13. 

* Encydopadia Britannica (nth ed.), voL xv, pp. 264-65. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 1 5 

American naval officer Commodore Perry.^ She became one of 
the great powers by defeating Russia in the war of 1904-05. 
Later she established her rule over Korea and her dominance 
over China. 

Such described in a very brief way is the origin and develop- 
ment of the great modem nations — the nations whose credit is 
under special consideration in this chapter. In view Bearing of 
of the fact that national obligations depend princi- devek^ent 
pally for their payment on national good faith, we °° "^^^^ 
consider these historical facts of interest and of importance in 
attempting to estimate national credit. 

The credit of any nation at any given time may be said to be 
determined by three leading considerations: — 

(i) Its debt statement or the size of its debt compared with its 
resources and with its population. 

(2) Its debt history or its record of good or bad JoSS 

faith '" estimating 

national 

(3) Its general standing with the other nations credit 
of the civilized world. 

Under the last heading come such considerations as the mili- 
tary position of a nation, the form and stability of its govern- 
ment, the character of its population and of its institutions, its 
trade position and its general economic and financial status. 

In order to understand the abnormal conditions affecting 
credit created by the great war, it is first necessary j^^^^^i ^^^ 
to know the normal conditions or the conditions be- ditions vs. 

, , , the war 

fore the war. 

Let us consider first what may be called the obvious or natural 
reason for the credit of a nation or for the prices of its government 
bonds; that is, the size of the debt compared with population 
the estimated resources and with the population, wealth, and 
The accompanying table (Table I) gives recent leading dviiized 
estimates of population and wealth and recent figures "^ °^ 
of the debts of the United States, Great Britain and Ireland, Ger- 
many, France, Russia, Austria-Hungary, Italy, and Japan. 

It is very difficult to give figures of estimated resources suffi- 
ciently accurate to be of great value in figuring percentage of debt 

1 Ploetz, p. 563- 



l6 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

to resources. At the same time it is desirable to try to form at least 
some general idea of the proportion between wealth and debt. 
Percentages, figured from estimates of wealth which differ so much 



TABLE I 



Country 


Estimated 
PopultUion' 


Estimated WeaUh* 


Debt 


Weallh 
per capita 


Debt per 
capita 


ft.S 


United States 

Great Britain 
and Ireland 


95,411,000 

45,663,000 
66,146,000 
39,660,000 
167,920,000 
50,237,000 
35,026,000 
52,312,000 


$187,739,071,090 » 

86,400,000,000 ' 
76,800,000,000 ' 
62,400,000,000 ' 
40,000,000,000 * 

25,000,000,000 B 

20,000,000,000 * 

9,749,040,000 » 


$1,026,686,026 " 

3,479,070,854 " 
4,869,674,212 u 
6,343,622,400 M 
4.538,654,400 " 
3,812,798,400 " 
2,578,435,200 1» 
1,251,316,800 " 


$1967.69 

1892.12 
il6r.07 
1573-37 
238.21 
497.64 
571.00 
186.36 


$ 10.76 

76.19 
73.62 
159-95 
27.03 
75-90 
73-6l 
23-92 


-55 

4.03 
6-34 
10.17 
11-35 
I5-2S 
12.89 
12.84 


Russia 2 


Austria-Hungary. . 
Italy .:.. 







The figures in this table are reduced to dollars on the basis of 

Dollar = 4 shillings 2 pence English. Franc = 9.6 pence English. 

Mark = 11.8 pence Engusfa. Yen = 2 shillings ^ pence Blnglish. 

1 German Empire and States. * Exclusive of Finland. 

« Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Countries in each Year from iqoi to 1912, no. 
39 (London, 1914), PP- 12-13- Population of the United States estimated as of June i, 1912; of Great 
Britain and Ireland, Germany and Italy, as of June 30, 1912; of France, Austria-Hungary, and Japan, 
Z912; and of Russia, 1911. 

* Figures for estimated wealth as given by different authorities vary greatly. For instance, the Paish 
estimate for the United States in 1914 figures about $144,000,000,000, and the German estimate of 
Helfferich for igii (Germany's Economic Progress and Natiorial Wealth, 1888-IQ13, by Dr. Karl Helf- 
fericb, director of the Deutsche Bank [Germanistic Society of America, 1914], p. Z15) about $118,000,- 
000,000; the Paish estimate for Great Britain and Ireland in 1914 comes to about $81,600,000,000; the 
Helfferich estimate for Germany in 1911 amounts to about $70,800,000,000 (Helfferich, p. 113); the 
Paish estimate for France in 1914 amounts to about $48,000,000,000 and the estimate of Th€ry in 1908, 
$54,870,000,000 (see Helfferich, p. 114); the Economist estimate, by implication, for Russia and Austria- 
Hungary in 1913 amounts in each case to about $43,200,000,000. The estimates given from the Commer- 
cial and Financial Chronicle, for Russia, Austria-Hungary, and Italy, are given in the New Websterian Dic- 
tionary (1912, p. 1039), as coming from the Bureau of Statistics, Department of Commerce and Labor, 
but they do not so come. The original source of these estimates is unknown to the writer; but the esti- 
mates are reasonable in view of earlier estimates of the wealth of the same coimtries. 

B Estimate for 1912. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Estimated Valuation of Na- 
tional Wealth, i8so-ZQi2 (Washington, 1915), p. 15. 

8 Estimate for I9i3» Economist (London), vol. Lxxx, p. 51. 

' Estimate for i9i3.^«wmM/, vol. ixxx, p. 51; andPaish estimate for 1914, 5/a/t5i (London), vol. 
LXXX, p. 4x9. 

8 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 100, p. 932. 

« Encyclopcedia Britannica (nth ed.), vol. xv, p. 219. Estimated from Statistics for the Year 1004-05. 

10 Principal of the public debt, July i, 1912, less net available cash in Treasury (except agency ac- 
count), June 30, 1912. United States Treasury Department, Circular no. 52 (Washmgton, 1913), pp. 
xg, 22. 

" Aggregate gross liabilities March 31, 1912. Statistical Abstract for the United Kingdom in Each oj 
the Last Fifteen Years from iSgg to igi^, no. 61 (London, 1914), p. 10. 

» Total public debt of German Empire, year ending March 31, 1912. Total fxmded and floating pub- 
he debts of 26 States January i to April i, 1912. (Figures for Bremen and Hamburg include munici- 
pal debt.) Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Countries, no. 39 (London, 1914) 
p. 437. Debt of Empire, $1,165,166,400; debt of States, $3,704,507,812. 

"Total capital of the public debt Januaiy i, 1912, R6publigue Francaise, Minist^e du Travail et de 
la Prevoyance Sociale. Statistique G^n^ral de la France, Annuaire StaUstique (Paris, 1913, statistics for 
1912, Imprimerie Nationale), vol. xxxn, p. 133*. 

" Total public debt of Russian Empire January i, 1912. Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other 
Foreign Countries (1014), p. 431. 

" Total combineci Austrian and Hungarian public debts, 1912. Ibid., p. 450. 

" Total " effective " public debt, year ending June 30, 1912, Ibid.t p. 445. 

" Total public debt March 31, 1912. Ibid.^ p. 460. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS l^ 

in certain cases from other estimates, should be used only in con- 
nection with other data in estimating the burden of the debt. This 
table shows the United States by far in the lead of all other nations 
in the amount of total wealth or resources. The wealth of Great 
Britain and Ireland, while less than half that of the United States, 
is shown to be larger than that of any other great nation — with 
Germany a close third and France with a total wealth estimated at 
$14,400,000,000 less than that of Germany. The table shows also 
the United States with the smallest actual debt and very much the 
smallest percentage of debt to resources. Figured on this percent- 
age basis, the burden of debt is next lightest on Great Britain and 
Ireland, then on Germany, then on France, then on Russia, then on 
Japan, then on Italy, and heaviest of all on Austria-Hungary. In 
the matter of per-capita wealth, the United States is not greatly 
ahead of Great Britain and Ireland, but both these countries are 
considerably ahead of France, very much ahead of Germany, and 
in an entirely different class from all the other nations considered. 
The debts figured on a per-capita basis show a very small debt for 
the United States, moderate debts for Japan and Russia, large and 
substantially equal debts for Italy, Germany, Austria-Hungary, 
and Great Britain and Ireland, and an abnormally heavy debt for 
France. 

In estimating the burden of debt it is a matter of considerable 
importance to know what proportion of the debt represents income- 
producing property, such as railways, and what pro- Assets off- 
portion may be called non-productive or dead-weight someixteut 
debt. It is also important to know whether any other "atio°ai debts 
assets exist which properly may be considered as an offset to at 
least a part of the debt. For instance: from the debt of the United 
States in 1912, in estimating its true burden, we may fairly deduct 
$134,631,980 of Panama Canal bonds ;^ from the debt of Great 
Britain and Ireland we may fairly deduct estimated market value 
of Suez Canal shares, $211,420,800, and other assets, $17,781,053, 
or a total of $229,201,853; ^ from the combined debt of the German 
Empire and the twenty-six German States we may properly deduct 
$4,077,387,590 as the estimated cost of construction on a mileage 

* U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52, p- i7- 

' Statistical Abstract for The United Kingdom, no. 61 (London, 1914)1 p. 10. 



1 8 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

basis of the government-owned railways; ^ from the debt of France 
we should not only deduct the value of the state railways actually 
owned, say, $821,548,997, but should take into consideration the 
fact that between 1950 and 1958 practically aU the railways of 
France, valued in 1911 at $3,701,184,000, after amortizing them- 
selves win become the property of the Government;^ from the debt 
of Russia we may deduct $1,557,633,600 incurred on account of 
railways; ^ from the debt of Austria-Hungary we may deduct, say, 
$2,079,198,749 as the value of the 22,034 miles of state railways,* 
and also from the debt of Italy we should deduct, say, $1,131,300- 
000 as the cost of construction of the Italian state railways; ^ and 
from the debt of Japan we should deduct, say, $290,534,400 as the 
value of state-owned railways.^ In deducting the value of railways 
from national debts, it should be noted that there is a great differ- 
ence in the revenue-producing powers of the state railways in 
different countries: for instance, the railways of Prussia-Hesse 
in Germany are operated with such success financially as to be a 
source of considerable net income to the State above the charges 
on their capital; the railways of Japan also have been a financial 
success; those of Russia, on the other hand, have been up to date so 
unprofitable as to compel as a whole a large annual contribution 
from the State for their support.'' The government-owned railways 
of Italy have failed by a good deal to earn the interest on their 
capital; and those of Austria-Hungary usually have earned less 
than the interest on their debt.* The French lines are beginning to 
show a measure of prosperity.^ It is impossible to make statements 

^ Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Countries, no. 39 (London, 
1914), pp. 387, 407. As a further set-off against the debt of the German Empire, there 
existed in 191 2 a variety of invested funds as well as the war treasure at Spandau of 
about $28,320,000; and as a further set-off against the debts of many of the twenty- 
six German States, there existed a variety of funds and income-producing property 
other than railways. Statesman's Year-Book, igi^ (London, 1913), pp. 869, 900-50. 

* Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries, pp. 390, 407. Samuel O. Dunn, Govern- 
ment Ownership of Railways (New York and London, 19x5), p. 22. 

' Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries, p. 431. 

* lUd., pp. 396-97, 408. Dunn, p. 382. 

' Figures for 1910, Dunn, p. 30. Italy has various other income-produdng property 
including the Cavour Canals. Statesman's Year-Book (1913), p. 990. 

* Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries, p. 404. 
' Dunn, p. 317. 

* Ibid., pp. 313-16. 

* Ibid., p. 316. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS I9 

absolutely definite about such matters as these; but it is perhaps 
fair to say that, taking into consideration the value of income- 
producing property, the debt of Germany in 191 2 was less of a bur- 
den on the resources and population of the country than that of 
any other nation except the United States, and that the debt of 
Great Britain and Ireland was probably the largest dead-weight 
debt — with the possible exception of Russia — of any country in 
the world, but was not by any means the most burdensome on the 
resources and population of the country. 

There is another way in which we may estimate the burden of 
debt — that is, by comparing the annual debt charge with the 
estimated national income or earnings of the people Debt charge 
and with the annual government expenditure. Table ^^^^ ™"' 
II shows estimated national income, annual debt income 
charge and percentage of debt charge to national income, wherever 
recent reliable data can be obtained, of the countries under special 
consideration in this chapter. 

This table, omitting Italy and Japan from consideration, shows 
the burden to be by far the lightest in the case of the United States 
and the heaviest in the case of France. In connection with this 
table, as with the previous one, there should be borne in mind the 
income-producing powers of the various state railways and other 
productive works. T^ u. i. 

^ Debt charge 

Table III shows total government revenue and compared 
expenditure, debt charge and percentage of debt govermnent 
charge to total expenditure for the same countries. '^^^ ""'* 

This table shows the percentage of debt charge to government 
expenditure to be much the smallest in the case of the United 
States and the largest in the case of France — with Japan a close 
second. 

In the three tables referred to we have applied various tests to 
the debt statements of the leading civilized nations in an effort to 
estimate from this point of view their credit. It may „ , . 

1 » n 1 !• t trrowth in 

be of interest to trace bneny the growth m popula- population, 
tion, wealth, and income and the increase in debts of income, and 
the great nations of the world. It must be remem- ^^^^ 
bered that almost all figures of this kind, even figures of debts, are 
approximations. It is perhaps not unfair to say that hardly any 



20 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

two authorities agree on the amount of a nation's debt at any 
given time. 

As giving us some standard to appreciate from what small be- 
ginnings the great nations of to-day have developed, we would say 
Growth in ^^^ ^^ population of theRomau Empire at the death 

^pufation of of Augustus, 14 B.c.,has been estimated at 54,000,000, 
dviiized divided as follows: Europe, 23,000,000; Asia, 19,500,- 

°°* 000; Africa, 11,500,000.^ The popxUation of the 



TABLE n 



Country 



United States 

Great Britain and Ireland 

Germany 

France 

Russia 

Austria-Hungary 

Italy 

Japan 



EstimaUd na- 
tifnud income^ 



$33.600,000,000 1 

10,800,000,000 ' 

10,080,000,000 * 

6,000,000,000 * 

7,200,000,000 • 

4,320,000,000 < 



National 
debt charge * 



$22,616,000 7 
117,600,000 " 
2i5»o6s,o54 8 
244,358,400 • 
199,428.156 " 
162,286,000" 
86,606,400 « 
72,134^70" 



National in- 
come fer 
capUa 



$352.16 
236.52 
152.39 
iSi-29 
42.88 
85.99 



National 
debt charge 
per capita 



% .24 

2.58 
3-25 
6.z6 
i.ig 
3-23 
2.47 
1.38 



Percentage 

oSdM 

charge to 

income 



.07 
1.09 
2.13 

4.07 
2.77 
3-76 



Dollar = 4 shillings 2 jy ncp English. 
Mark =11.8 pence English. 
Franc «= 9.6 pence English. 



Austrian krone and Hungarian korona ■ 
Russian rouble = 2 shillings ij pence En§; 
Japanese yen = 2 shillings \ pence T 



I English- 



^ Estimate of Sir George Paish in 1Q14 in the Statist, voL Lxxx, p. 419. 

* Estimate for r9i3. Economist (London), vol. lxxx, p. 51. 

3 This is by implication the Economist estimate for 1913 (voL lxxx, p. 51). The total national income 
for the Unit&i Kingdom, France, and Russia is given as the equivalent of $24,000,000,000 with definite 
figures for the United Kingdom and France. 

* Economist estimate by implication for 1913 (voL LXXX, p. 51). 
fi These estimates, tike those for national wealth, should be used with f 



at care. As compared with 
the national income of Great Britain and Ireland as given in the table, Bir George Paish {Statist, voL 
LXXX, p. 419) estimates this in 19x4 at about $11,520,000,000; the Paish estimate for Germany made at 
the same time is about $9,600,000,000 and for France about $5,760,000,000 (Ibid.); the estimate of Helf- 
ferich for Germany in 191 1 was about $9,440,000,000 (Germany's Economic Progress, p, 99) and of Stein- 
man Bucher in 1908 (see Webb, New Dictionary of Statistics [1911], p. 630), about $8,400,000,000; and 
the estimate of A. de Lavergne and Paul Henry for France about 1907 (Webb ligiz]. P- 630) was from 
about $4,320,000,000 to about $5,280,000,000. The most recent estimate of the national income of Italy 
which we have found is that made by Mulhall, in 1888, about $1,747,200^000 (Molhall, Dictionary oj 
Statistics [London, 1899], p. 322). So mr as we know, there is no reliable estimate of the national income 
of Japan. 

* Unless otherwise stated, this is the total public debt charge for the calendar year 1912. 

7 Interest on the public debt for the year ending June 30, 1912. Statistical Abstract for the Principal 
and Other Foreign Countries, No. 39 (London, 1914), p. 456. 

3 Total public debt expenditure of the German Empire and States, year beginning April i, 1912. 5/3- 
tistisches JahrbuchfUr das Deutsche Reich, issued by Statistischen Amte igij (Berlin), p. 346. (Interest 
for 1912, $176,967,668.) 

' Total annual debt expenditure, 1912 (total interest paid $146,073,600), R£pubUque Francaise, Min- 
ist&-e du Travail et de la Prevoyance Sodale. Staiistique Genirale de la France, Annuaire Statistique 
(Paris, 1913. Imprimerie Nationale) vol. xxxn, p. 133*. 

^3 PubUc debt services, Russian Empire, 1912 (interest for 19x1. $188,688,743). Statistical Ahsiracf *or 
Foreign Countries (1914), p. 431. 

" Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (19x4), pp. 447i 440. 

" Interest on "effective" debt, year ending June 30, 1912. Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries 
(1914). P- 445- 

u National debt consolidation fund, year ending March 31, 1912. Stattsttcal Abstract for Foreign 
Countries (X914), p. 459. 

" National debt services for year ending March 31, 1912, Statistical Abstract for the United Kingdom, 
no. 61 (London, i9i4)> P- 5- (Interest <A funded debt for 1912, $73,972,969-60.) 



* Estimated by Bodio (Mulhall, Dictionary (^Statistics [London, 1899], p. 441). 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 21 

United Kingdom has been estimated at early dates as follows: 1066, 
3,500,000; 1381, 3,860,000; 1528, 5,676,000. The population of 
France in 1328 has been estimated at 10,000,000.^ The population 
of all Europe before the fifteenth century hardly exceeded 50,000,- 
000.* The following table * shows estimates of the population of 
what are now the leading countries of Europe at intervals of one 

TABLE m 



Country 


Total 
govemmmt 
revenue^ 


Total 
government 
expenditure • 


Govern- 
ment 
revenue 
per capita 


Govern- 
ment 
expendi- 
ture fer 
capita 


National debt 
charge " 


Debt 

charge 

per 

capita 


1"«£ 


United States 

Great Britain 
and Ireland 

Germany 

France 

Russia 

Austria- 
Hungary.. . 

Italy 


$ 992,249,000 ' 

888,433,373 • 

681,129,600* 

886,185,600 « 

1,586,784,000 • 

1,025,635,200 ' 
549,105,600 s 
322,024,080* 


$965,274,000 s 

857,016,480 ' 

681,129,600 * 

926,308,800 e 

1,606,670,400 ■> 

1.039.526,400 ' 
549,105,600 8 
286,833,930 • 


$10.40 

ig.46 
10.30 
22.34 
9- 45 

20.42 

15. 68 

6.16 


$10.12 

18.77 
10.30 
23.36 
957 

20.69 

15.68 

S.48 


$ 22,616,000" 

117,600,000 *8 

55,815,888 « 

244,358,400 " 

199,428,156 " 

162,286,000 " 
86,606,400 " 
72,134,370 " 


$.24 

't 
6.16 
1. 19 

3.23 
2.47 
1.38 


2.34 
13.72 
26:38 

12.41 

15.61 


Japan 


2S-IS 



Dollar = 4 shillings 2 pence English. 
" pence English 



Mark 
Franc 



9.6 pence English. 



Austrian krone and Hungarian korona = 10 pence English. 
Russian rouble = 2 shilhngs x^ pence English. 
Japanese yea = 2 shillings \ pence English. 



' Total government revenue and expenditure, unless otherwise stated, given for calendar year 1912. 
" Year ending June 30, igi2. Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. 455-56. 
" Year ending March 31, 1912. Statistical Abstract for the Umted Kingdom, no. 61 (London, 1914), p. z. 

* Budget estimate of German Empire only, year beginning April i, 1912. Statistical Abstract for For- 
eign Countries (London, 19x4), p. 436. 

s Budget estimate of 1912. StatisUcal Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, X914), pp. 440-4X. 

" Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries , 1914, pp. 430-31. 

7 Total combined revenue and expenditures of Austria and Hungary, X912. Statistical Abstract for 
Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. 446-47, 448-49. 

^ Budget estimate for year ending Jime 30, 1912. Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 
1914). p. 444- 

* Budget estimate for total revenue and expenditure lor year endiiig March 31, 1912. Statistical 
Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. 458-59. 

10 Unless otherwise stated, this is the total pxibUc debt charge for the calendar year X012. 

11 Interest on the public debt for the year ending June 30, 19x3. Statistical Abstract for the Principal 
and Other Foreign Countries, no. 39 (London, 1914), p. 457. 

13 Public debt charge, German Empire only, year beginning April i, igi2. Statistical Abstract for 
Foreign Countries (London, 1914.)* P- 436. 

13 Total annual debt expenditure, igj2 (total interest paid, $146,073,600), R6publique Fran^ise, 
Minist^e du Travail et de ui Prgvoyance Sociale, StatisUque Gin£rale ae la France, Annuaire Statistiqtte 
(Paris, 1913), Imprimerie Nationale, vol. xxxn, p. 133*. 

^* Public debt services, Russian Empire, 1912 (interest for 1911, $188,688,743). Statistical Abstract 
for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), p. 431. 

" Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914)1 PP- 447. 440' 

1* Interest on "effective" debt, 1912. Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, X9T4), p. 445. 

" National debt consolidation fund. Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), p. 459. 

13 National debt services for year ending March 31, 1912. Statistical Abstract for the United Kingdom, 
no. 61 (London, 1914), p. $. (Interest of funded debt for 19x2, $72,972,969.60-) 



' Mulhall (1899), pp. 444-45- 

2 Estimated by Bodio (Mulhall [1899], p. 441). 

' Mulhall, p. 441. In the table, England at present stands for the United Kingdom 
of Great Britain and Ireland, Prussia for the German Empire and Austria for Austria- 
Hungary. The 1912 figures are from table on p. 16. 



22 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

hundred years from 1480 to 1880 inclusive, and the estimated 
population in 1912. 

POPULATION 





1480 


isSo 


16S0 


1780 


1880 


zei2 


England. . . 

France 

Prussia. . . . 

Knssia 

Austria 

Italy 


3,700,000 
12,600,000 
800,000 
2,100,000 
9,500,000 
9,200,000 


4,600,000 

14,300,000 

1,000,000 

4,300,000 

16,500,000 

10,400,000 


5,532,000 
18,800,000 

Z,400,000 

12,600,000 
14,000,000 
11,500,000 


9,561,000 
25,100,000 

5,460,000 

36,800,000 
30,200,000 
12,800,000 


35,004,000 
37,400,000 

45,260,000 
84,440,000 
37,830,000 

28,910,000 


45,663,000 
39,660,000 
66,146,000 
167,920,000 

50,237,000 
35,026,000 



This table shows France greater in population than any of the 
other countries of Europe as far back as 1480 — twelve years 
before the discovery of America; it shows Austria in the lead in 
1580, France second, and Italy third. It shows France, Austria, 
Russia, and Italy all having a greater population than England in 
1680. It shows after the eighteenth century a great relative gain 
for Great Britain and Ireland as compared with France and a very 
large gain for Germany and Russia. The population of the Ameri- 
can colonies and of the United States at various dates has been 
as follows: ^ 

1673 160,000 

1701 297,000 

1750 1,161,000 

177s 2,803,000 

1790 3,930,000 

1810 7,240,000 

1830 12,866,000 

i860 31,443,000 

1880 50,156,000 

1912 95,411,000 

This table shows the growth in popidation of the American na- 
tion from little more than bands of colonists to nimibers larger than 
those of any of the coimtries of Europe except Russia. The accom- 
panying table (p. 23) ^ shows the population of the United States, 
Great Britain and Ireland, France, Germany, Austria-Hungary, 
Russia, Italy, and Japan for 1890, 1900, and 1912. 

• Estimates apparently of Mulhall until 1790, then census figures. Mulhall (1899), 
p. 4SO. The 1912 figures are from table on page 16. 

» Mulhall (1899), pp. 442, 450. Encydopadia Britannica (11th ed., 1911), vol. 19, 
p. 269. Table, p. 16. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 23 



United States 

Great Britain and Ireland 

France 

Germany 

Austria-Hungary 

Russia 

Italy 



j8go 



62,481,000 
38,200,000 
38,800,000 
48,600,000 
40,100,000 
92,000,000 
30,300,000 



igoo 



76,303,387 
40,909,925 

38,517,975 
56,345,000 
45,089,531 
129,211,113 
32449,754 
43,759,577 



igi2 



95,411,000 
45,663,000 
39,660,000 
66,146,000 
50,237,000 
167,920,000 
35,026,000 
52,312,000 



This table is remarkable chiefly as showing the great growth in 
population of Russia, the United States, and Germany and the 
practically stationary condition of population in France. The pop- 
ulation of all Europe in 1778 has been estimated at 150,000,000,^ 
in 1882 at 327,800,000,* and in 1912 at 450,000,000.' The popula- 
tion of the world in 1804 has been estimated at 640,000,000,^ in 
1883 at 1,433,000,000,^ and about 1912 at 1,732,000,000.^ 

The growth in wealth has been even more remarkable. The 
following figures ^ for the wealth of England and Wales or of the 
United Kingdom at different dates may be of interest: * 



Da 


te Country 


Estimated wealth 


Authority 


1660 


England and Wales 


$1,200,000,000 


Petty 


170^ 


England and Wales 


2,352,000,000 


Davenant 


176s 


Great Britain 


5,280,000,000 


Mulhall 


1812 


United Kingdom 


10,512,000,000 


Colquhoun 


1816 


United Kingdom 


11,520,000,000 


Mulhall 


18^^ 


United Kingdom 


18,000,000,000 


Pablo Pebrer 


j86o 


United Kingdom 


26,688,000,000 


Mulhall 


1865 


United Kingdom 


29,342,400,000 


Giffen 


1870 


United Kingdom 


33,984,000,000 


Mulhall 


1885 


United Kingdom 


48,177,600,000 


Gifien 


i8q8 


United Kingdom 


56,688,800,000 


MulhaU 


1913 


United Kingdom 


86400,000,000 


Economist 



' Estimated by Moheau (Mulhall [1899], p. 441). 
» Estimate of Behm-Wagner (Mulhall [1899], p. 441). 
' World Almanac (1915), p. 62. 
* Estimate of Malte-Brun (Mulhall [1899], p. 44i)- 
» Estimate of Behm-Wagner (Mulhall [1899], p. 411). 
' World Almanac (1915), p. 62. 
' Reduced at the rate of $4.80 to the pound sterling. 

8 Mulhall (1899), pp. 589, 700, and (1903), p. 262. Webb, The New Diclionory oj 
Statistics (London, 1911), p. 629. Table, p. 16. 



24 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 
Growth in wealth The Wealth ' of France at different dates has been 

of the leading ^. ^ j r n t 

nations estimated as follows: ■* 



Date 


Estimated wealth 


Authority 


1780 


$7,296,000,000 
8,640,000,000 
13,564,800,000 
20,928,000,000 
23,232,000,000 
33,600,000,000 
41,088,000,000 
46,512,000,000 
62,400,000,000 


La Voisier 


1815 


Chaptal 
Flaix 


182^ 


i860 


Guyot 
Guyot 


1865 


1871 


i88< 


Guyot 
Mulhall 


1808 


TOT2 









Estimated figures for the wealth of the United States at different 
dates are as follows: ' 



Date 


Estimated wealth 


Dale 


Estimated wealth 




$619,200,000 

1,065,600,000 

1,497.600,000 

1,680,000,000 * 

1,881,600,000 

2,649,600,000 

3.753,600,000 


1850 

i860 

1870 

1880 

1890 

1900 

1912 


$7,135,780,228 
16,159,616,068 
24,054,814,806 
43,642,000,000 

65.037,091,197 

88,517,306,775 

187,739,071.090 


1800 


1810 


1814 

1820 


iS-jo 







• Estimate of Sir George Faish {Statist, vol. Lxxx, p. 419). 

Comparisons of early with recent estimates of the wealth of cer- 
tain of the other coimtries under consideration are: Aggregate of 
the German States in 1814 probably less than that of France, or 
say less than $9,600,000,000 compared with $76,800,000,000 in 
1913-14; * Italy, in 1868, about $9,283,200,000, and in 1884, from 
$10,272,000,000 to $11,712,000,000 (Pantaleoni), compared with 
say $20,000,000,000 in 1912; and Austria-Himgary, in 1880, about 

' Reduced at the rate of $4.80 to the pound sterling. 

' Mulhall (1899), pp. 591-92, 700. Table, p. 16. 

' Figures from 1790 to 1840, inclusive, except those of Sir George Paish, from 
Mulhall (1899), p. 593. Figures from 1850 to 1912, inclusive, from Department of 
Commerce (Bureau of the Census, Estimated Valuation of National Wealth 1850- 
IQ12 [Washington, 1915], vol. i, pp. 20-21, 24-25). — Census figures are not always 
comparative. The figures for 1850, i860, and 1870 are exclusive of exempt real es- 
tate. Figures for 1870 are on a gold basis. 

* Sir George Paish, Statist, vol. lxxx, p. 419, and table, p. 16. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 2$ 

$18,240,000,000 (Beer), compared with say $25,000,000,000 in 
1912.^ The following table ^ shows estimates by Mulhall of the 
wealth of the United States and of the leading nations of Europe in 
1888 and 1898 compared with estimates from the table on p. 16 
for 191 2-13: — 



1888* 



1898^ 



1912-1 3t 



United States 

Great Britain and Ireland . . 

France 

Germany 

Russia 

Austria-Hungary 

Italy 



$61,536,000,000 
51,840,000,000 
42,720,000,000 
36,000,000,000 
27,840,000,000 
20,160,000,000 
13,920,000,000 



$78,480,000,000 
56,668,800,000 
46,512,000,000 
38,649,600,000 
30,840,000,000 
21,657,600,000 
15,168,000,000 



$i87,739,07r,090 
86,400,000,000 
62,400,000,000 
76,800,000,000 
40,000,000,000 
25,000,000,000 
20,000,000,000 



* Michael G. Mulhall, Dictionary of Statistics (4th ed., London, zSgg), p, 589. 
t Mulhall (1899), p. 700. t Table, p. 16. 

Certain recent estimates * of the wealth ' of the United States, 
Great Britain and Ireland, the British Empire, Germany, and 
France may be grouped as follows: — 



United States. 



Great Britain and Ireland . 

British Empire 

Germany 

France 



1903 
1904 
191 2 

1903 
190S 
1913 

1903 

1902 
1908 
1908 
1913 

1908 



1908 
1913 



(Giffen) 
(Census) 
(Census) ' 

(Giffen) 

(L. G. Chiozza Money) 

(Economist) 

(Giffen) 

(Schmoller) 
(Balled) 

(Steinman Bucher) 
(Economist) 

(Lavergne 
& Henry) 

(Th6ry) 
(Economist) 



$86,400,000,000 
107,104,192,410 
187,739.071,090 

72,000,000,000 
54,720,000,000 
86,400,000,000 

106,800,000,000 

48,000,000,000 
60,240,000,000 
76,800,000,000 
76,800,000,000 

43,200,000,000 

(Private wealth 

only) 

54,870,000,000 

62,400,000,000 



1 Mulhall (1899), p. 592, and table, p. 16. 

' Reduced at the rate of $4.80 to the pound sterling. 

• Webb, New Dictionary of Statistics (1911), pp. 629-30, and Department of Com- 
merce, Estimated Valttation of National Wealth (Wasldngton, 1915)1 p. 15, and table, 
p. 16. 



26 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

From the time of the close of the Napoleonic wars until the dates 
of the most recent estimates, the wealth of France has increased 
between six and seven-fold; that of Great Britain and Ireland, over 
seven-fold; that of Germany, about eight-fold; and that of the 
United States, nearly one himdred and twelve-fold.^ These figures 
are startling and explain in great measure the ease with which 
Europe has borne the debts inherited from the Napoleonic wars 
or created in the one himdred years since, and the ease with which 
the United States paid off its Civil War debt. 

The development of the national income, or what is sometimes 
called the total earnings of the people, has been no less remarkable 
than that of wealth. The national income of the 
national United States has increased from less than $480,000,- 

"""""^ 000 in 1814 to about $33,600,000,000 in 1914; that 

of the United Kingdom has iucreased from about $1,440,000,000 in 
1814 to about $11,520,000,000 in 1914; that of France from, say, 
$1,200,000,000 in 1814 to about $5,760,000,000 in 1914; and that of 
Germany from a figure probably less than that of France in 18 14 
to about $9,600,000,000 in 1914.^ 

The increase of national debts has been very great but very 
irregular. As wiU be shown later, large increases in debt usually 
took place for the purposes of war. The table on 
national page 27 shows approximate figures for national debts 

at selected dates from 1713 to 1912 inclusive. These 
dates, with the exceptions of 1889 and 191 2, are those of important 
historical events; namely, 1713, the Treaty of Utrecht which 
ended the War of the Spanish Succession; 1763, the Peace of Paris 
ending the Seven Years' War; 1793, the beginning of the Reign of 
Terror in France; 1816, the end of the Napoleonic wars; 1848, the 
year of Revolution in Europe; and 1870, the outbreak of the 
Franco-Prussian War. 

In 1889, Spanish America, according to Mulhall, had debts 
amounting to about $1,598,400,000; India had a debt of about 

* Comparisons are made on the basb of Sir George Paish's figures for 1814 and the 
figures in table on p. i6. 

* Estimates of Sir George Paish in the Stalist, vol. Lxxx, p. 419. These estimates 
may be compared with those of the Economist, vol. ixxx, pp. 50-51. For estimates 
of national income of various countries at different dates, see Webb, New Dictionary 
of Statistics (1911), pp. 629-30, and Mulhall (1899), pp. 320-22 and p. 747. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 2/ 



m 
Q 
u 

H-l 





















(• 






? 


























s 


























4J 




1 


1 s 1 1 1 1 1 

>S £; ^ 1 3 a S 


i 


1 1 §. 
? i I 




1 


2 a 00 eT " " 

^ *0 to H 
<2 00. U{ 00 


00 M O 

K !? S 


li i II 




»o 


« 


^ ■* m « 




M 


H 











•» 




















„ , 1 




§ 


§ 




§ 


. § 


. 1 


§ 


§ 








§ 


f 


i 


1 




i 


\ 




1 


1 




j 




§" 


o" 


N 


« 


0( 


i 1 








S V3 


00 






? =8 


tc 


^ t 


1 ^ ? -a 1 




;; 


<c 


« 


(O « 


«i 




H 


H 








§ 


1 


1 


~Y^ 


§ 


§ 


§ 


1 


~l 






§ 


1 


1 


i 


II 


§ 


1 § 


§ 


I 






i 


■is 


J 


i S 


H « CO CO 00 

■* (O o» ^ « 


g 


i "s 


1 




CO 


t *- « 


« 


u- 




M 


" 


^ 






W 


« 




H 


^ 


^ 




« 


H 






00 




•» 




















M 


H 




§ 






§ 




§ 


I 


§ 


~i 


1 


§ 


1 


t 


i 






{ 




J 


i 


1 


I 


§ 


i 


1 




o 




h 


c 


c 


* 


0> 00 


c 


t* 


^ 


M 




H 


N V 


9 .8 


H 




t 


s 


3 


« 


^ 




a 




















r- 


00 




§ 






{ 




I 




§ 


~\ 


1 


§ 


§ 


1 


I 






i 






1 


4 


J 




I 


1 




Q 




r. \a 


v) n 




■* 


¥ 


OC 


N 


«n 




n 


t^ 00 


O. IN. M 




« 


\c 




V 


H 




m 


« 




« 


■* H 




H 




V 


V3 


o> 




^ 




















e- 


*^ 




4» 


























§ 


1 




§ 


§ 






§ 


1 


\ 




§ 


1 


§1 


. 1 


II 


1 


1 


1 


§ 






§ 






s 


S E 






£ 


-a -g, s 's 1 




R 


H 




« 


O 










«0 00 


o> 




^ 




















ei 


« 




M- 


























§ 
















1 




§ 


. § 


^ 


1 


i 


, 1 


1 




. 1 


1 


I 


i 


1 


i 1 1 


H 


»o 


o 


















00 


00" 




o 








to 






to 


to to 




t^ 


lO 
















n M 1 




4* 




















H 


M 




g 


§ 






I 








1 




§ 


. 1 


§ 


8 


1 1 


1 




1 


1 


1 


1 


1 


8 


g 




a 


m 




'■', 






to 


H M 1 




M 


o 


















Vt lO I 




4* 






















1 




J 














1 














i 






C 

1 


i 


1 


c 

i 


» 


.! 


J 




3 






<3 




i 


P« 


< 


li 


D 


B 


'• B 




^ 





fill 









19=?! 



Bl{ 






'^ 1 i , 






e^ 






6 OiM^ 



28 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

$892,800,000; Turkey, about $864,000,000; Australia, about 
$826,800,000; Portugal, about $542,400,000; and Egypt, about 
$494,400,000. As Mulhall remarks, the debts of the world increased 
from 1793 to 1889 — a period of ninety -six years — just about 
tenfold.^ The origin of these debts or the purposes for which they 
were created has been given by Mulhall " as follows: — 

Armaments $17,328,000,000 

Railways and telegraphs 6,960,000,000 

Roads and bridges 3,744,000,000 

Smidries 772,800,000 

Total $28,804,800,000 

There is, it is to be noticed, a discrepancy between the total 
amounts of this table and the one on the preceding page, but un- 
doubtedly the second table tells in a general way for what pur- 
poses the money borrowed was expended. Figures are not available 
showing the purposes for which debts were created up to 191 2 ; but 
probably they would show somewhat the same proportion between 
debts for the various purposes. The debt increase by periods has 
been somewhat as follows: — 

DEBT INCREASE OF WORLD FROM 1713 (TREATY OF 
UTRECHT) » 



Period 


Increase 


Per annum 




$787,200,000 
1,569,600,000 
4,987,200,000 
417,600,000 
10,272,000,000 
10,771)200,000 
12432,000,000 


$15,840,000 




';2, ^20,000 




216,960,000 


t8t7-i8a8 


12,960,000 




4,67,04.0,000 




566,880,000 




540,i;2I,7M 








$41,236,800,000 


$207,220,100 





1 Dudley Baxter has called attention to the fact that the laige debt of Holland in 
the eighteenth century compared with her resources led to the loss of her commerce 
and political power. National Debts (1871), pp. 42 and 95-96. 

« Mulhall (1899), p. 260. 

• Hid. Mulhall's figures for the increase by periods are given in millions of 
pounds only. The figures, therefore, are merely approximate. See also our table 
" PubUc Debt." 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 29 

As Baxter remarks, — treating of a period subsequent to the 
Napoleonic Wars, which so greatly increased the debt of Great 
Britain, — the rate of increase in debts was very different before 
and after i860. Up to i860 national borrowing was chiefly in 
Europe. The revolutions of 1848, the Crimean War of 1854, and 
the French-Austrian War of 1859 caused most of the increases in 
debts. After i860 there was the American Civil War, the Prussian- 
Austrian War of 1866, and the Franco-Prussian War of 1870. 
Immense loans were made in America and in Europe. There took 
place what might be called an epidemic of borrowing. The average 
annual total loans were about as foUows: 1848-54, $96,000,000 a 
year; 1855-60, $240,000,000 a year; 1861-73, $960,000,000 a year; ^ 
1874-1912, $500,900,000 a year. It is to be remembered that a con- 
siderable portion of the debts in the later periods were for produc- 
tive purposes such as railroads. The public debts of the countries 
under special consideration in this chapter in 1900, at the end of a 
long period of peace, compared with the debts in 191 2, were sub- 
stantially as foUows: 

PUBLIC DEBTS IN 19002 AND 1912 



Total dat 



Debt 
per capita 



igoo 



Total debt 



Debt 
per capita 



United States.. .. 
Onited Kingdom . 

France 

German Empire. . 

Prussia 

Austria 

Hungary 

Russia 

Italy 

Japan 



$1,402,638,073 
3,019,098,154 
5,193,834,520 

569,062,987 
1,582,003,200 
1,720,502,400 

886,080,000 
3,148,800,000 
2,812,800,000 

253,934.400 



$18.12 
73.80 

135-36 
10.10 
45. 00 
66.46 
46.56 
24.48 
86.40 
5.80 



$1,026,686,026 


$ 10.76 


3,479,070,854 


76.19 


6,343.622,400 


15995 


1,165.166,400 


17.63 


2,225,214,264* 


55.40' 


2,494,228,800 


86.02 


1,318,569,600 


62.08 


4,538,654.400 


27.03 


2,578,435.200 


73.61 


1,251,316,800 


23.92 



* Population December i, 1910 {Statistical Abstract Jot Foreign Countries^ p. 8). Debt Z912 (StatisfiS' 
ches Jahrbuch [Berlin, 1913], p. 34fi)- 

These figures show fairly recent changes in the debts of the vari- 
ous countries under special consideration. 

The debt charges have not always varied in direct proportion to 
the size of the debts themselves. This is owing prin- changes in 
cipally to a change in the rate of interest. There have ^^^^ charges 

> Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, March, 1874, pp. 2-3. 
' Encyclopcedia Britannica (nth ed., 1911), vol. xix, p. 269. 



30 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

been many conversions, especially in English and American debt 
history and some forced reductions in interest, as in the cases of 
France in early times, Austria, and other coimtries. We will take 
up this question when dealing with the debt histories of the sepa- 
rate countries. 

We have outlined the relations between the population, re- 
sources, and debts of the leading civilized nations of the world. 
We will take up now their debt history or record of 
good or bad faith. When it is remembered that there 
is no legal method of collecting a national debt or the interest on 
it against the will of the nation indebted, the importance of a 
nation's record becomes apparent. 

Of the nations under special consideration, the debt history 
which goes back the farthest is that of France. Although there are 
records of earlier royal borrowings, the foundation of 
the French national debt was laid early in the fif- 
teenth century.^ Later Francis I (1515-47) obtained various sums 
through the city of Paris, which kept a list of the creditors and 
distributed the interest.^ Part of this money he borrowed for his 
ransom. An extensive revision of the debt was carried out by Sully 
in 1604. Other attempts were made by Mazarin and Colbert.' 

Throughout French debt history, owing partly to the various 
forced reductions and conversions, particularly in early days, and 
partly owing to lack of clearness in the records, the facts are very 
difficult to establish. Viihrer has described the history of the vari- 
ous French loans previous to the nineteenth century as " a history 
of bankruptcies." * All forms of loans were tried and all possible 
methods of evasion were used to escape payment. There were 
forced reductions and debasements of the ciurency. To costly 
wars and internal disturbances was added ignorance of financial 
and economic conditions. 

Louis XrV spent great sums in war and in building Versailles. 
In. this reign, the interest on the debt was reduced to 4%.^ At the 

' Encyclopedia Britannica (nth ed., 1910), vol. x, p. 794. 

' C. F. Bastable, Public Finance (1895), p. 576. 

' Encyclopaedia Britannica (nth ed., 1910), vol. x, p. 794, and Bastable, Public 
Finance (London, 1895), p. 596. * Viihrer, vol. i, p. 220. 

' Leone Levi, Journal of the Royal StaHstical Society (London, 1862), vol. xxv, 
p. 322; Mulhall (1899), p. 264. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 3 1 

death of Louis XIV, in 1715, the capital of the debt amounted to 
about $595,200,000. This was arbitrarily reduced by the Regent in 
1716 to about $384,000,000.^ The debt increased with John Law's 
State Bank and through his schemes for the creation of paper 
money. In 1 72 1 , by a series of measures both violent and arbitrary, 
the debt was reduced by half. In 1764, the Comptroller-General 
de Laverdy "so reduced the capital of the debt as to cause a new 
bankruptcy." ^ After this reduction, the debt amounted to $460,- 
200,000 and the annual charge to $18,135,000.* In 1784, a sinking 
fund was established, but soon after was suppressed. 

During the convention and revolutionary periods, "the famous 
assignats and all kinds of government papers were issued of fabu- 
lous amounts and utterly worthless." ^ The public debt was consoli- 
dated in August, 1793. The use of paper money and forced loans, 
however, destroyed any benefit that might have been obtained.^ 
In 1798, Napoleon introduced a proper system of finances, but did 
not recognize the debt incurred during the Revolution. AU per- 
petual and life annuities, old and new, were changed for two thirds 
of the amount into notes called dette publique mobilisie — exchange- 
able for land — and one third was entered in the Grand-Livre 
under the title of Hers consolidi. The two thirds exchangeable only 
for land soon lost all value and the one third became the origin of 
the present national debt of France.* After some reductions for 
confiscations, the balance in annual interest was ascertained to be 
about $7,680,000, representing a capital debt of about $153,600,- 
000. As illustrating French credit at this time, a price of seven 
francs per cent for the 5% rentes is interesting.^ The financial 
administration of Napoleon I had two great merits — (i) it refused 
to issue inconvertible paper money, and (2) it refused to meet war 
expenditure to any large extent by borrowing.^ It made up the 
deficiency by levying contributions on other nations. The debt at 
the close of the First Empire, including floating debt of about 
$96,000,000, amounted to, say, $339,096,000.* 

» R. Dudley Baxter, National Debts (London, 1871), p. 49. 
' Levi, vol. XXV, p. 322. ' Bastable (1895), p. 597. 

* Levi, vol. XXV, p. 322. ' Bastable (1895), p. 597. 

' Levi, vol. XXV, p. 322. See also loth Census of the United States, vol. vn, p. 269. 
Bastable (1895), p. 597. 
' Annuaire Statistiqtte (1912), p. 74*. ' Bastable (1895), pp. 597-98' 

» Baxter, National Debts (1871), p. 50. 



32 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The Government of the Restoration was obliged (i) to meet the 
war indemnity levied on France by the Allies; (2) to compensate 
the Emigres or dispossessed proprietors; and (3) to take up the bal- 
ance of the imperial outlay or deficits. These problems were 
handled with honesty and firmness. The Government refused to 
repudiate. To meet these expenditures, the Government between 
1815 and 1830 made a net increase in interest on the debt of about 
$19,200,000, representing a net capital increase of about $432,000,- 
000.^ It was in 1825 that the 3% rentes were created.* The French 
debt in 1830 is given by Baxter as amounting to about $680,- 
496,000.' 

The Orleanist Government began its career by borrowing. It 
created loans to clear off deficits, to prepare for war, and to carry 
out public works. During this period, however, the redemption of 
the debt was carried on. These were years of profoimd peace, dur- 
ing which the public credit stood high.* The debt in February, 
1848, according to Baxter, amounted to about $873,600,000.^ The 
price of the 5% rentes in 1844 reached 126.30.® 

The Second Republic added about $10,176,000 to the interest 
charge, and brought the total charge up to nearly $44,160,000 a 
year. This was a time of hazardous experiments on the part of the 
provisional government and of complete disorganization of the 
financial system.^ During this period, there were forced "con- 
versions" or arbitrary reductions of interest.* By loans, consolida- 
tions, and an indemnity for the emancipation of slaves, the Second 
Republic raised the capital of the debt to about $1,177,200,000.' 
In 1848, both the 5% and the 3% rentes sold at the lowest prices 
since the close of the Napoleonic wars. The 5% rentes were quoted 
at 50 and the 3% rentes at 32^.'° 

Under Napoleon HI, even from the time of his presidency, 
"debts were accumulated as never previously." The apparent 

1 Bastable (1895), pp. 598-99. Baxter (1871), p. 51. 

' Annuaire Statistique (191 2), p. 74*. 

' Baxter (1871), p. 51. (In all Baxter's figures of the French debt after 1798, the 
s inkin g fund is excluded, but the caution money and floating debt are included.) 

* Bastable (1895), p. 599. » Baxter (1871), p. 51. 

' Annuaire Statistique (1912), p. 74*. ' Bastable (189s), p. 599. 

" Francis W. Hirst, The Credit of Nations (National Monetary Commisaon, 
Washington, 1910), p. 84. 

9 Baxter (1871), p. 51. w Annuaire Statistique (1912), p. 74*. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 33 

decrease between 1866 and 1868 was fictitious — caused by manip- 
ulating the accounts.^ Through continued deficits and the Cri- 
mean, Italian, and other wars, France again heavily increased its 
debt." The total cost of the Crimean War to France was about 
$316,800,000, of which about $295,200,000 was added to the debt. 
Further loans were issued much under par for the Italian War and 
the Mexican Expedition. The total addition to the debt between 
1852 and July, 1870, was represented by an interest charge of about 
$24,768,000. The total annual payment had risen to about 
$69,120,000 and the capital to a little less than $2,304,000,000. 

The Franco-Prussian War was as marked in French debt history 
as the war with Napoleon I in the case of the English debt. In 
addition to the expenses of carr3dng on the war, there was an in- 
demnity of about $960,000,000. The total expense of the war has 
been estimated at about $1,886,400,000, of which about $1,632,- 
000,000 was raised through loans.' As showing the effect of the 
Franco-Prussian War on the credit of France, it is interesting to 
note that the 3% rentes sold in 1870 at a high price of 75.10 and 
in 1871 at a low price of 50.35.* 

After the war, there were fresh loans for public works and to 
meet budget deficits. There had been in 1862 a conversion of the 
debt which had reduced the interest, but had increased the capital 
by about $307,200,000. There were also conversions in 1883 and 
1894.= 

The French debt in 191 2 was the largest in the world and nearly 
twice that of Great Britain and Ireland. The "faUing-in" of the 
railway property, referred to earlier in this chapter, will lessen 
considerably the burden of the debt. Baxter in 1871 estimated the 
French debt charge,* compared with the national income for differ- 
ent periods, as follows: 1818, 3.5%; 1837, 2.3%; 1870 (before the 
Franco-Prussian War), 2.3%; after the war, about 5%.^ These 
percentages compare with our figure of 4.07% ia 1912. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 270. ' Baxter (1871), p. 51. 

' Bastable (1895), p. 600. * Annuaire StatisHque (1912), p. 75*. 

' Bastable (1895), pp. 600-01. There was a successful conversion in 1852 by wMch 
a large amount of $ P^r cents were converted into 4^% stock with a considerable 
saving in interest to the State. (Hirst, Credit of Nations, p. 93.) 

' The French debt charge for 1870 includes railway guarantees and the bridge and 
canal fund. (Baxter [1871], p. S3.) 

' Baxter (187 1), pp. SS-S7- 



34 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

After France, the debt history of England or of the United 
Kingdom is older than that of any other country under special 
consideration. In 1672, the Exchequer was closed by 
rea n in (^]ja^j.jgg jj^ ^nd about $6,376,924, which had been 
advanced on the credit of supplies voted by the House of Com- 
mons, was seized. Later this so-called "bankers" debt was con- 
solidated with other debts and interest paid at the rate of t%} 

The British debt began in earnest after the Revolution of 1688 
and with the wars of William III against France." The principal of 
the debt at the time of the Revolution has been given as about 
$3,188,462.' The first loan raised by WiUiam III was for four years, 
with interest partly at 7% and partly at 8%, and was a charge on 
certain excise duties.* The debt at the Peace of Ryswick (1697), 
exclusive of annuities, amounted to about $103,275,562. During 
the five years of peace which succeeded, nearly one quarter of the 
debt was paid off.* 

In 171 1, there was established the celebrated South Sea Com* 
pany, which has a curious connection with the history of the 
English debt. This company was formed to assist the Government 
in its financial operations. On government obligations amounting 
to about $43,200,000, httle or no interest had been paid. The secu- 
rities were greatly depreciated. The South Sea Company was em- 
powered to receive these obligations as subscriptions for its stock. 
The amount of the stock thus created was about $44,054,246, 
which in 1715 was increased to about $48,000,000 by the addi- 
tion of certain arrears of interest.* The wars of Marlborough 
under Queen Anne raised the debt at the time of the Peace of 
Utrecht, in 17 13, exclusive of interest and annuities, to about 
$250,297,742.' During this reign, the system of raising money by 

' Robert Hamilton, An Inquiry concerning The Rise, Progress, Redemption, Present 
State, and Management, of the National Debt of Great Britain and Ireland (3d ed., en- 
larged, Edinburgh, 18 18). (In Samuel Jones Loyd, Select Collection of Scarce and 
Valuable Tracts and Other Publications on the National Debt and The Sinking Fund, 
[London, 1857], p. 474.) 

' Baxter (1871), pp. 7-8. 

' Hamilton, p. 499. 

« Ibid., p. 475- 

' Ibid., p. 499. 

' Ibid., p. 478, and Fenn's Compendium of the English and Foreign Funds (gth 
ed., London, 1867), p. 2. 

1 Hamilton, p. 500. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 35 

mortgaging particular branches of the revenue was continued. 
Large amounts also were raised by annuities and by means of lot- 
teries. The debt created was considerably larger than the amount 
of money received.^ 

The reign of George I marked an important recovery of national 
credit, owing to the conditions of peace and to economy. In 17 16, 
there was established the first sinking fund, usually called after Sir 
Robert Walpole. In 1717, after negotiations with the Bank of Eng- 
land and the South Sea Company, a general reduction in interest 
on the public debt to 5% was agreed upon. Ten years later, in 
1727, the Government arranged to reduce from 5% to 4% the 
interest on its debt to the Bank and to the South Sea Company; 
and in 1732, the Government made a similar arrangement with the 
East India Company. The irredeemable annuities also were con- 
verted into redeemable debt, and a reduction of interest to 4% was 
agreed upon for this new capital. At the end of the reign of George 
I, the total debt, funded and unfunded, was estimated at about 
$249,600,000 and the charge for interest at about $5,844,245." 

During the first part of the reign of George II (1727-60), under 
the wise administration of Walpole, peace and financial progress 
continued. In 1739, however, there began a long war, first with 
Spain and afterwards with France and Spain together, which even- 
tually added some $144,000,000 to the national debt. Even under 
these conditions the Government was able to borrow at from 3% 
to 4%. In 1749, a law was passed providing for an important con- 
version of the public debt. All the public creditors who had been 
receiving interest at the rate of 4% were to have the rate reduced 
after December 25, 1750, to 3!%, until December, 1757, and after 
that date to 3%. Most of the creditors ultimately accepted this 
offer, and those who refused were paid off. Debts originally con- 
tracted at 3% were united in another fund called the 3% consoli- 
dated annuities. This latter operation was the origin of the 3% 
consols. It is a startling fact that British credit at this time stood 
as high as it did in 1910-12.' 

The debt in 1756, at the begiiming of the Seven Years' War, 

» Hirst, The Credit of Nations, pp. 15-16. 

* Ibid., pp. 16-17. for an account of Sir Robert Walpole's Sinking Fund, see 
Hamilton, pp. 526-30. 
' Ibid., pp. 17-18. 



36 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

exclusive of interest and annuities, was about $356,794,334.* 
About $288,000,000 was added to the debt by the Seven Years' 
War, which was far more costly than its predecessors; and 3 per 
cents fell far below par.^ The principal of the debt at the Peace of 
Paris in 1763 was about $666,554,064. After a considerable reduc- 
tion during the years of peace, the debt stood at the beginning of 
the American War, in 1775, at about $617,201,448 of principal and 
about $21,463,541 of interest and annuities.' By this time it was 
. dear that the national debt was growing at a dangerous rate; and 
it had all been spent on war. From a financial point of view, how- 
ever, the war with the American colonies proved more disastrous 
than any of its predecessors. This was partly owing to the mis- 
management of the finances. In 178 1, a fimding operation was put 
through by which about $100,800,000 was added to the capital of 
the debt and only about $57,600,000 reached the Exchequer. The 
credit of the coimtry went from bad to worse. In August, 1774, 
before the beginning of the American Revolution, 3% consols had 
stood at 89. They had fallen more or less steadily during the war, 
imtil at the surrender of Lord ComwaUis they were quoted at 54.* 
The debt at the Peace of Versailles in 1783, which ended the Ameri- 
can War, stood at about $1,199,287,814 of principal and about 
$45,368,506 of interest and annuities. 

At the beginning of the French Revolutionary wars in 1793, the 
principal of the British debt, according to Hamilton, stood at 
about $1,171,769,448.^ In September, 1815, — before the Peace of 
Paris which closed the Napoleonic wars, — the principal of the 
debt, including apparently floating or unfunded debt, amounted 
to the enormous sum of $4,132,987,435, and interest and annuities 
to $156,698,966, or a total, funded and unfimded debt, of about 
$4,289,686,401.^ In the opinion of Professor Levi, England would 
have done better to have fought the Napoleonic wars more with 
taxes and less with borrowings.'' A large part of this debt had been 
contracted at "ruinous rates." Between 1793 and 1815, on an 
average $830.40 of stock was created for every $480 of money 
obtained, so that the country reaUy received only $1,627,831,200, 

« HamUton, p. 500. « Hirst, p. 18. 3 Hamilton, p. 500. 

• Hirst, pp. 19-20. » Hamilton, p. 500. 

« Fenn (1867), p. 6. ' Levi (1862), p. 314. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 37 

or $1,188,316,766 less than it engaged to pay.^ Between 1800 
and 1810, taxation amounted to nearly 25% of the estimated na- 
tional income.* In 1816, the charge for interest was more than half 
of the whole public revenue from taxes. The national credit was 
much impaired. During the French wars, the price of 3% consols 
fluctuated between a maximum of 73 and a minimimi of 47.' In 
June, 181 5, the month of Waterloo, the lowest price reached for 
consols was 53I.* 

After Waterloo, the condition of Great Britain was very bad and 
the financial recovery slow. In 1822, Vansittart introduced a 
scheme which led to the conversion of the 5 per cents with a large 
saving of interest and which also provided for the establishment of 
a real sinking fund. This was created through making provisions 
for net surpluses in the revenue and applying the same to the reduc- 
tion of the debt — the only sort of national sinking fund which 
means anything.^ Between 1823 and 1832, consols fluctuated be- 
tween 72 for the lowest and 97 for the highest.® The amount of the- 
debt in 1854 as given by Baxter was about $3,842,400,000, a con- 
siderable reduction from the debt at the close of the Napoleonic 
wars. The Crimean War which lasted about two years (1854-56) 
raised the debt, including annuities, to about $4,003,200,000.' The 
low point for consols during this period was 85I in March, 1854.* 

In the next twenty-one years, about $336,000,000 of debt were 
extinguished; and in the twenty years after 1877, the reduction 
amounted to about $590,400,000.' These relatively large reduc- 
tions of debt, combined with generally favorable financial condi- 
tions, led to the record high price for British consols on July i, 
1896. At this time, as 2I per cents, they sold at 114, or on an in- 
come basis of about 1.95%.^° In 1899, the debt stood at about 
$3,048,000,000.^^ 

From this figure in 1899, the lowest point in the British debt 

' Levi (1862), pp. 315-16. ' Ibid., p. 319. " Hirst, p. 21. 

' Messrs. Frederic C. Mathieson & Sons, London, England; enclosed in letter 
dated April 29, I9r3. 

' Hirst, p. 21. ° Mathieson letter dated April 29, 1913. 

' Baxter (1871), p. 9. ' Mathieson letter dated April 29, 1913. 

' Hirst, p. 22. 

*" Figures from F. C. Mathieson & Sons. This yield is allowing for loss, if redeemed 
at due date (1923) at par, and for a reduction of interest in 1903. 

'' Hirst, p. 22. 



38 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

since the Napoleonic wars, the national debt rose in consequence 
of the Boer War to $3,374,400,000 in 1901 and to $3,830,400,000 in 
1903. This was the largest debt since 1867, "so that the national 
savings of thirty-six years of peace were swept away by national 
borrowings during three years of war." ^ In the opinion of Mr. 
Hirst, editor of the "London Economist," more immediate injury 
was done to British credit by the financial policy which preceded 
the war than by the actual outbreak and carr)dng on of the war. 
The increasing expenditure before the war, the mismanagement of 
the sinking fimd, and the apprehension of trouble in South Africa 
led to a greater fall in consols than did the actual outbreak and 
progress of the war.^ Between March 31, 1906, and March 31, 
1909, with Mr. Asquith as Chancellor of the Exchequer, the na- 
tional liabilities were reduced by about $201,600,000.' In spite of 
this fact and owing probably to general financial conditions, the 
price of consols continued to siok until they reached a figure of 
72I on October 14, 1912.* 

Baxter has estimated the percentage ^ of debt charge to national 
income of Great Britain and Ireland at different dates as follows: 
1700, 2.3%; 1712, 4.5%; 1736, 2.3%; 1784, 6.2%; 181S, 9%; 1843, 
5.5%; 1870, 2.8%. These compare with our figure of 1.09% in 
1912. 

As Professor Bastable remarks, the growth of the English debt 
has been due altogether to war expenditure. It is all what may be 
called a "dead-weight" or improductive debt.* Writing in 1895, 
Professor Bastable considered that the reduction in the English 
debt during years of peace had been far from satisfactory. He held 
that the continued existence of such a big debt must be attributed 
largely to financial weakness.^ At the same time, while the British 
debt up to 1 91 2 had not been reduced to the extent that it might 
have been, the burden of the debt, owing to reductions in interest 

' Hirst, pp. 24-25. ' Ibid., pp. 23-24. 

' Ibid., p. 25. (For the various conversions of the English debt and for the history 
of the sinking fimd, see Hirst, pp. 26-39.) 

* Figures from F. C. Mathieson & Sons. 

6 In estimating the debt charges from 1784-1870, Baxter has deducted the amounts 
estimated as paid for reduction of capital. (Baxter, National Debts, p. 18.) 

» With the exception of "Other Liabilities," which represent mostly productive 
objects. {Statesman's Year-Book [London, 1913I, p. 49.) 

' BasUble (1895), p. 594. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 39 

and to the great increases in national wealth and national income, 
was becoming steadily less. The great European War wiU add a 
new and extremely interesting chapter.^ 

If we foUow the historical order, the debt of Austria probably 
should be considered next. The financial and debt history of Aus- 
tria is far from pleasant reading. From the latter part 
of the eighteenth century until the latter part of the 
nineteenth century (say, 1789-1870), there was not a year in which 
the revenue of the State equaled its expenditure. In 1763, at the 
end of the Seven Years' War, the capital of the debt, according to 
Baxter, was about $72,000,000. In 1789, it had increased to about 
$168,000,000. During the disastrous wars of the French Revolution 
and of the First Empire, the debt increased rapidly. Inconvertible 
bank-notes were issued on a large scale. ^ From 1799, the bank-bills 
feU lower and lower until they sank to about one seventeenth of 
their normal value. An imperial mandate of February, 181 1, con- 
tained these words: "I give my imperial word that the bank-bills 
shall never be reduced in value." ' March 26, six weeks later, the 
Government reduced the value of the paper money, which had 
increased to $515,849,000, to one fifth of its previous amount. By 
this process the paper money was reduced to $103,169,800. This 
was increased again in 1816 to $310,969,350. The new paper 
money soon fell to one quarter of its nominal value — thereby 
making the total loss nineteen twentieths. The owner of what 
had been originally $48.67 reaUy possessed but the value of $2.40.* 

The total Austrian debt in 1811 was about $392,570,822. The 
wars of 1813 to 1815 required fresh sacrifices. There was also ex- 
travagance on the part of the Government. In order to get rid of a 
burdensome floating debt, new operations were begun in 18 16 
nearly equal to a second bankruptcy. The owners of paper money 
were given the option (i) of exchanging it for two sevenths of its 
value in bank-notes and accepting State paper at 1% for the re- 
maining five sevenths; or (2) of exchanging the paper money for 

' For detailed official history of the British national debt see: National Debt History 
oj the Early Years of the Funded Debt from l6g4 to 1786 (London, 1898) ; National Debt; 
the report by the Secretary and Comptroller-General of the Proceedings of the Com- 
missioners for the reduction of the national debt from 1786 to 31st March, 1890 
(London, 1891). 

" Baxter (1871), p. 65. " Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 275. * Ibid. 



40 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

shares in the newly established "National Bank."^ In 1820, 
according to Baxter, the debt amounted to about $473,760,000.^ 
Between 1820 and 1840, loans followed one another rapidly — in- 
cluding lottery loans. The Mettemich system, adopted from 181 1 
to 1840, increased the debt so that the annual interest rose from 
$3,747,205 to $19,806,665. After the pressing financial embarrass- 
ments in 1846 and 1847, the Revolution followed in Vienna, Hun- 
gary, and Italy in 1848. Paper money again was issued to an enor- 
mous extent.^ Baxter speaks of the successive deficits as having 
brought the debt in 1848 to about $600,000,000.* 

The wars with Himgary, Italy, France, and Pnissia and the 
large miHtary establishments in the intervals caused an enormous 
increase in the Austrian debt, and raised it in 1868 to about $1,444,- 
800,000.^ Writing a few years earlier. Professor Leone Levi spoke 
of the financial condition of Austria for a long series of years as 
" ruinous in the extreme." * 

At one time the Government unfairly reduced the interest on the 
debt to one half its original percentage, and then forced creditors 
to contract a further loan imder threat of loss of their previous 
claim.^ Mulhall gives the combined debts of the Austro-Hungarian 
Empire in 1875 and 1889: 1875, about $1,948,800,000; 1889, 
$2,785,920,000.8 

Comparatively recent large additions to the Austro-Hungarian 
debts have been made for the acquisition of state railways and for 
public works.^ Baxter has estimated the percentage of debt charge 
to national income for Austria at different periods as follows: 
1815-20, 1.8%; 1837-43, 2.2%; 1868-70, 2.2%."' These com- 
pare with oiu: figure in 1912 of 3.76%. Since the beginning of 
the present war, Austria has refused to pay interest or princi- 
pal of notes held by citizens of enemy countries. Later on in this 
chapter, we give highest and lowest prices of Austrian rentes by 
ten-year periods from 1873 to 191 2 inclusive. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 275. ' Baxter (1871), p. 65. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 275. ♦ Baxter (1871), p. 65. 

» IbU. 

' Journal oj the Royal Statistical Society (1862), vol. xxv, p. 327. 
' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 275. ' MulhaU (1899), p. 267. 

' Hirst, p. 9. See also Encydopadia Britannica (nth ed., 1910), vol. n, p. 976; 
vol. xm, pp. 899-900. 
" Baxter, pp. 89-92. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 41 

The debt of what is now the United States originated during the 
American Revolution.^ In July, 1776, Silas Deane, political and 
commercial agent for the United States in France, . , 

,^ T-r. ,. ,,,., ,, United States 

met Caron de Beaimiarchais, who had mduced the 
French king to aid the American colonies — perhaps partly in 
revenge for the loss of the great French Empire in America in the 
Seven Years' War. Apparently $195,000 had been advanced by 
the French Treasury, June 10, 1776. Later, Beaumarchais ar- 
ranged, under the guise of an ordinary commercial contract, to 
furnish the colonies with arms, ammunition and supphes. This, 
with the early domestic loans of the Continental Congress ^ and 
the loans of the separate colonies or States for war purposes, was 
the origin of our national debt.* 

The first foreign loan negotiated by the Continental Congress 
was obtained in 1777 from the "farmers-general of France," a 
private corporation engaged in the collection of the national reve- 
nue of France. Up to that time the expenses of the Revolutionary 
Govermnent in Europe had been met by small subsidies from 
France and Spain and by such remittances in specie as could be 
spared from home.* From 1778 to 1782 various sums were ad- 
vanced or loaned the United States by France. A contract for the 
repayment of these sums was drawn up and dated July 16, 1782. 
The total amount — $3,510,000 — was to bear 5% interest and to 
be repaid in twelve annual payments of about $292,500 each, be- 
ginning the third year after the conclusion of peace. The arrears of 
interest to the date of the contract and then to the date of the 
treaty of peace were to be made a gift by France.^ Although peace 
was made in 1783, the repayment actually began in 1791, and was 
made to the Revolutionary Government of France. The last 

' From the close of the seventeenth and the early part of the eighteenth century 
unta the time of the Revolution, Massachusetts, South Carolina, New York, and 
other colonies had outstanding at times varying amounts of so-called bills of credit or 
paper money. For the history of these issues, see Horace White, Money and Banking 
(Boston, 1902), pp. 103-114. 

2 After March i, 1782, interest on the domestic debt was not met, and certificates 
of interest indebtedness, receivable for taxes by the States, were issued. (Davis R. 
Dewey, Financial History of the United States [New York, 1915], p. 46.) 

' Rafael A. Bayley, The National Loans of the United States from July 4, 1776, to 
June 30, 1880. Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 299-301. Davis R. Dewey, Financial His- 
tory of the United States (New York, 1915), pp. 4S-47- 

« Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 304. ' Ibid., p. 305. 



42 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

payment was made in 179S, at which time the small balance due 
was converted into s|% stock. All this loan was repaid.^ 

The financial situation of the Continental Congress was at its 
worst in 1779 and 1780. Over $200,000,000 in Continental cur- 
rency had been issued — which in 1780 "quietly expired in the 
hands of its possessors." The army was badly in need of food and 
clothing.^ In 1781, a loan of $1,950,000 was obtained in Holland 
on the credit of France.' This loan was provided for in the contract 
drawn up July 16, 1782, — signed by the Comte de Vergennes and 
Benjamin Franklin.* The repayment of the principal of this loan 
was begun in 1792, and a small unpaid remainder ($176,000) was 
converted in 1 795 into 4!% stock. Later this stock was redeemed.* 
In 1783, another loan was obtained from France; and between 1782 
and 1794, eleven loans were raised in Holland and one in Antwerp 
(1791). These loans were all repaid in fuU.® 

On assuming the position of Secretary of the Treasury, in 1789, 
Alexander Hamilton found himself temporarily without funds to 
meet the ordinary expenses of the Government. Under these cir- 
cumstances, he decided to negotiate temporary loans with the Bank 
of New York and the Bank of North America. These loans were all 
repaid by 1790.^ 

The indebtedness of the United States at the organization of the 
present form of government, including arrears of interest to Janu- 
ary I, 1790, was: — 

Principal of foreign loans $10,098,706.02 " 

Balance due France for military supplies 24,332. 86 

Arrears of interest to January i, 1790 1,760,277. 08 ' 

Debt due foreign officers i86,q88. 78 ' 

Arrears of interest to January i, 1790 11,219. 32 

Principal of domestic debt (estimated) 28,858,180. 65 

Arrears of interest to January i, 1790 11,398,621. 80 

Arrears and claims against the late government outstanding and 

subsequently discharged 450,395. 52 

Total debt of the United States January i, 1790 $52,788,722.03 

1 Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 306. * Ihid. See also Dewey, pp. 36-41. 
' There was also in 1781 a small loan or advance of moneys from Spain. The 
Spanish debt — $174,011 — was repaid in 1792-93. {Tenth Census, vol. vil, p. 306.) 

* Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 307. ' Ihid., p. 308. 

» Ibid., pp. 309-22. ' Ibid., pp. 322-24. 

' Not only had the United States been delinquent in the payment of interest on the 
foreign loans for periods varying from four to six years, but it had failed to pay the 
installments of principal which began to be due in 1787. (Dewey, p. 89.) 

• Part of the amount due foreign officers who had fought in the Revolution was 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 43 

To this total should be added the debts of the several States — 
estimated by Alexander Hamilton at that time to aggregate about 
$25,000,000. 

There were two kinds of debt about the settlement of which there 
was no dispute: (i) the foreign debt loaned in gold on the faith of 
the Continental Congress; and (2) paper money issued by Congress 
and by the several States. The foreign debt was paid in full; the 
paper money sank to no value and passed out of circulation.^ 

By an act approved August 4, 1790 (Acts of ist Congress, Session 
2, chap. XXXIV, I Stat. L., p. 138), provision was made for the 
payment of the debt of the United States. Section 2 of this act 
authorized a loan of not over $12,000,000, to be applied to the pay- 
ment of principal and interest of the foreign debt. Section 3 author- 
ized a loan to the full amount of the domestic debt, payable in certi- 
ficates issued for the said debt according to their specie value and 
computing the interest upon such as bore interest to December 31, 
1790.^ Section 13 authorized a loan of $21,500,000 to take care of 
the debt incurred up to January i, 1790, by the respective States 
for the expenses of the war. Section 21 pledged the faith of the 
United States to make good any deficiencies in income necessary 
for interest on the debt, and section 22 provided for the creation of 
a siiiking fund from the proceeds of the sales of western lands. 

The evidences of the domestic debt and of the debts of the sev- 
eral States were taken in exchange on a basis which resulted as 
follows: In the case of the domestic debt, the National Goverrmient 
paid the interest immediately, on two thirds of the principal only, 
at 6%; it deferred interest on the remaining one third for ten years; 
and it allowed 3% interest on the arrears of interest — making up 
nearly one third of the whole debt. In assuming the debts of the 
various States, the Government paid immediately interest at 6% 
on four ninths of the entire sum; on two ninths it deferred interest 
for ten years ; and it allowed only 3% on three ninths.* The amount 
of State debts actually assumed was $18,271,786.47.* 

paid in cash in 1782 and part in 6% certificates of indebtedness. By 1803 most of 
these certificates had been redeemed and by 1828 all. {Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 322.) 

1 Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 325. 

' This section also authorized refunding United States bills of credit or Continental 
currency on the basis of $100 of currency to $1 of specie. 

' Alexander Hamilton, Works (1851), vol. IV, pp. 251-52. Dewey, p. 95. 

• Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 327. 



44 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

By an act of August 12, 1790 (Acts of ist Congress, Session 2, 
chap. 47, I Stat. L., p. 186), provision was made for reducing the 
debt by purchase at market price — not exceeding par or the true 
value thereof — from the surplus revenue derived from the duties 
on imports and the tonnage of ships or vessels to December 31, 
1790.^ This was followed by acts approved May 8, 1792, and 
March 3, 1795, establishing a formal sinking fund.^ 

On January i, 1801, the debt of the United States stood at 
$80,038,050.' Under Jefferson's administration, with Gallatin 
as Secretary of the Treasury, the poHcy of public retrenchment 
with a view to the reduction of the debt and of taxation took the 
field. The result was a remarkable reduction of debt between 1801 
and 1812. The net reduction was $38,000,000, but the real amount 
paid off was larger; for the Louisiana Purchase was responsible for 
an increase of $11,250,000 in the indebtedness.'* 

The increase in the public debt caused by the War of 1812 was 
nearly $88,000,000.^ A committee of the House of Representatives 
estimated years afterwards that during this war the actual value 
in specie of the Treasury receipts for over $80,000,000 par value 
of loans was only $34,000,000. As illustrating the credit of the 
United States at this time, a 6% loan was put out in August, 
1813, at 88|. Afterwards portions of a 6% loan were sold as low 
as 65 measured in specie.® In January, 1816, the debt stood at 
$127,334,933.7 

After 1822, owing to constant surpluses in the revenue, the 
reduction of the debt was rapid; ^ and in 1836 the United States 
for the first time in its history was practically out of debt. There 
was a small unpaid balance, — $328,582.10, as estimated Decem- 
ber 8, 1835, — which remained unpaid solely because payment had 
not been demanded. Under an act of June 23, 1836,^ surplus reve- 
nue to the amount of $28,101,644.91 was distributed to the several 
States. 10 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 327. 

' Acts of 2d Congress, Session i, chap. 38, i Stat. L., p. 281.' Acts of 3d Congress, 
Session 2, chap. 45, i Stat. L., p. 433. 
' Financial Review (1915), p. 90. * Hirst, p. 106; and Dewey, pp. 119, 121, 124. 
^ Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 352. ' Dewey, p. 134. 

' Financial Review (1915), p. 90. ' Hirst, pp. 109-10. Dewey, pp. 170-71. 

• Acts of 24th Congress, Session i, chap. 115, s Stat. L., p. 52. 
" Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 361. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 45 

In 1837, a year of general suspension of specie payments by the 
banks, Treasury notes were issued by the Government on a large 
scale. ^ There was a considerable deficit — amounting in Septem- 
ber, 1837, to about $2,000,000. Further issues of notes were made 
from 1838 to 1843 inclusive, and longer loans were made in 1841 
and 1842. These, like the Treasury notes, were put out to take care 
of constantly recurring deficits and the constantly accimiulating 
debt.2 

The net indebtedness created by the Mexican War (1846-48) 
was $49,000,000. All the loans, bearing 6% interest, were floated 
at par or better.^ Among these was a loan of $16,000,000 issued 
under an act approved March 31, 1848,* to take care of deficits 
occasioned by the war.^ 

On July I, 1851, the debt stood at $68,304,796. From that year 
it was reduced until in 1857 the net debt — principal of the debt 
less cash in Treasury — was only $9,998,622. The panic of that 
year, followed by the failures of the revenue imder a system of low 
tariffs, caused an increase in the debt until it reached $59,964,402 
on July I, i860.* 

The Civil War bears much the same relation to American debt 
history as do the Napoleonic wars to British debt history. This 
great struggle caused an enormous increase in the debt of the 
United States; but owing to the great prosperity which followed 
the war, this large debt was reduced until it ceased to become 
much of a burden. In acts approved July 17 and August 5, 1861,^ 
Congress authorized a loan of not over $250,000,000 — the first 
important loan authorized to carry on the Civil War. There were 
issued under these acts $150,000,000 Treasury notes bearing 7.3% 
interest and $50,000,000 twenty-year 6% bonds.* On December 30, 
1861, the banks suspended specie payment and were followed in 

' There had been consideiable issues of Treasiuy notes dviiing the War of 1812. 
(See Dewey, pp. 136-37.) 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 361-63. In 1841, the Secretary of the Treasury in- 
formed Congress that during the previous four years, the expenditure had exceeded 
the revenue by $31,310,014. (Ibid., p. 362.) 

' Dewey, pp. 255-56. * Acts of 30th Congress, Session i, 9 Stat. L., p. 217. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 367. 

' Financial Review (1915), p. 90; and Hirst, p. iii. 

' Acts of 37th Congress, Session i, chaps. 5 and 46, 12 Stat. L., pp. 259, 313. 

• Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 375-84. Dewey, pp. 276-81, 306. 



46 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

this by the Government.^ February 25, 1862, there was passed 
the famous Act ^ authorizing among other things: (i) the issue 
of $150,000,000 legal-tender United States notes; (2) the issue of 
$500,000,000 6% bonds payable in twenty but redeemable after 
five years — familiarly known as the "five- twenties"; and (3) the 
creation of a sinking fimd. Under this and later acts, there were 
issued something like $450,000,000 of legal-tender notes or paper 
money. There were also issued enormous amounts of short-term 
Treasury notes. Long- and short-term loans followed each other in 
rapid succession in 1863, 1864, and 1865. In July and August, 1864, 
the average price in gold of the paper money or "greenbacks" was 
thirty-nine cents on the dollar. On July i, 1864, the premium on 
gold measured in paper currency reached one himdred and eighty- 
five per cent. The total effect of paper issues in increasing the cost 
of the war has been estimated at between $528,000,000 and $600,- 
000,000.' The following prices,* during the Civil War, of United 
States 6% bonds due in 188 1 may be of interest: — 



Lffuj 



High 



1861 (outbreak of wax) 

1861 

1862 

1863 

1864 

i86s 



84i (April) 
83 Qune) 
87^ (January) 
gif Qanuary) 
102 (July) 
103I (March) 



94 (April) 
QSf (October) 
107} (June) 
iiof (October) 
118 (April) 
iizf (January) 



The debt reached its maximum on August 31, 1865, when it 
amounted to $2,756,431,571.^ Of the gross debt, about $1,110,000,- 
000 was funded debt, about $460,000,000 inconvertible paper, and 
about $1,276,000,000 floating debt. The cash reserves in the Treas- 
ury amounted to about $88,000,000.* The annual interest charge 
on the debt was about $151,000,000.^ 

The problems which faced the new Secretary of the Treasury 
after the war were: (i) How to pay off or fund the floating debt, 
and (2) how to provide a permanent scheme of debt reduction. 

' Dewey, p. 281. ' Acts of 37th Congress, Session 2, chap. 33, 12 Stat. L., p. 345. 

" Dewey, pp. 284-97 and 306. ♦ Financial Review (1915), p. 91. 

' Ibid., p. 90. 

• Bastable (1895), p. 606. See also Dewey, pp. 316-17 and 332-33. 

» Bastable (1895), P- 6o7- 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS \^ 

Soon after the dose of the Civil War, the revenues began to show a 
surplus over expenditures. This surplus was applied from time to 
time to the redemption of short-term obligations.^ Such portion of 
these obligations as could not be redeemed for lack of ftmds was 
converted into five-twenty bonds as authorized by the Acts of 
March 3, 1865,^ and April 12, 1866.' In a little over two years, the 
floating debt was reduced to $408,000,000 and the inconvertible 
issues reduced by over $20,000,000, while new funded debt to the 
amount of $686,000,000 in 6% bonds had been issued. These 
transactions were completed by May i, 1869.^ The Government 
then began using the surplus revenues in the purchase of its un- 
matured bonds at the market price in currency. It paid, in terms 
of gold, $307,702,207.64 for bonds so purchased. The average 
price in gold was $95.19.^ R. Dudley Baxter has estimated the 
burden of the American national debt and the American state 
debts on the basis of annual debt charge to estimated annual in- 
come for 1868-70 at 2.7%.^ 

Under Acts of July 14, 1870 ^ and January 20, 1871,^ there were 
authorized to be sold, at not less than par in coin, $5op,ooo,ooo 
5% ten-year bonds, $300,000,000 45% fifteen-year bonds, and 
$1,000,000,000 4% thirty-year bonds, the proceeds to be applied 
to the redemption of the war debt. The refunding operations under 
these acts began in 1871 and continued until the summer of 1879. 
A total of $1,395,345,950 bonds were refunded under these acts; 
and the annual saving in interest to the Government was $19,900,- 
846.50. On January i, 1879, specie payments were resumed. As 
the remaining Civil War debt matured, it was either continued at 
a lower rate of interest or redeemed in gold. The continued bonds 
also were redeemed from time to time as the surplus revenues per- 
mitted until no bonds remained outstanding except those author- 
ized by the refunding acts. These last-mentioned bonds from 

' V.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), p. 8. 
' Acts of 38th Congress, Session 2, chap. 77, 13 Stat. L., p. 468. 
' Acts of 39th Congress, Session i, chap. 39, 14 Stat. L., p. 31. 
' U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), p. 8; and Bastable 
(1895), pp. 606-07. 
' U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), p. 8. 
' Baxter, National Debts (1871), p. 92. 

' Acts of 4rst Congress, Session 2, chap. 256, 16 Stat. L., p. 272. 
' Acts of 41st Congress, Session 3, chap. 23, 16 Stat. L., p. 399. 



48 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

time to time were purchased with surplus revenues or redeemed 
as they became redeemable. The last of them — the residue of the 
4% bonds of 1907 — were called for redemption April 2, 1907, and 
ceased to bear interest July 2 of that year.^ The redemption of the 
American Civil War debt has been regarded by experts as Httle 
short of astoimding. It makes the reduction of the British debt in 
the himdred years after the Napoleonic wars seem relatively in- 
significant. The methods by which the United States reduced its 
debt have been criticized;^ but the result everywhere has been 
admired. The United States paid off its Civil War debt in the 
wholesale, wasteful, imscientific, but effective American way. 
The following figures give an idea of the extent and rapidity of 
the reduction of the debt: — 

NET DEBT' 

July I, 1865 $2,674,815,856 

July I, 187s 2,090,041,170 

July I, 1885 i,37S>352,443 

July I, 1893 838,969,476 

We have closed the statement with 1893 because in the following 
year new borrowings began. 

The protective tariff, whether wise or unwise from any other 
point of view, undoubtedly was one of the chief factors which made 
possible the large reduction in the Civil War debt. The Wilson 
Tariff Act of 1894, on the other hand, combined with the effects of 
the panic of 1893 and the fijiandal heresies which followed, led to 
a considerable enlargement of the United States debt. Between 
1894 and 1896, $262,315,400 of bonds were issued either to main- 
tain the gold reserve of the Treasury or to redeem obligations of the 
United States.* On July i, 1896, the net debt stood at $955,297,- 
254. The war with Spain in 1898 brought the debt on July i, 1899, 
to a net figure of $1,155,320,235. From this date, there was a more 
or less steady reduction until 1908, when the debt stood at $938,- 
132,409.^ Since then there has been a moderate increase in the debt 

' U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), pp. 9-11. 
' Baxter (1871), p. 31, and Hirst (pp. 122-23). ' Financial Review (1915), p. 90. 
* U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), pp. 11-12. See also 
Dewey, pp. 449-55- 

' Financial Review (1915), p. 90. Dewey, pp. 465-68. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 49 

through the issue of bonds for the construction of the Panama 
Canal ^ and for the postal savings banks. As illustrating the high 
point which United States credit has reached, the Government was 
able in 1900 to issue 2% bonds at not less than par to refund issues 
bearing higher rates of interest.^ These bonds were, to be sure, 
particularly attractive as a basis for national bank-note circulation. 
Their issue, however, together with the prices of aU United States 
bonds for the past ten or a dozen years, showed the credit of the 
United States to be as high as, if not higher than, that of any other 
nation in the world. 

Russia, like Austria, has been a country of paper money and of 
more or less continual deficits. Paper money was issued as early 
as the reign of Catherine II, under a manifesto dated 

Russia 

December 29, 1768. At the death of the Empress, 
there had been issued assignats for $124,749,686. These became 
largely depreciated as compared with coin.' Mulhall gives the 
total debt of Russia in 1799 as about $225,600,000.* There were 
further issues of paper money during the wars with Napoleon and 
with Turkey. In 1810, the amount of the debt outstanding was 
estimated at $456,295,206. The Czar Alexander I declared the 
whole property of the State to be security for it. Three years of 
war — 1812-15 — required $253,058,000 above the ordinary ex- 
penditures. In 181 5, the assignats were exchangeable for silver 
rubles on the basis of 418 to 100. After the Napoleonic wars, the 
amount of the state debt acknowledged was not much above 
$98,850,781, but the paper money in circulation amoimted to 
something like $661,114,025.^ 

Loans payable in paper — 6% at 83^ — were contracted at 
home in 1817 ; in 1818, paper loans abroad were contracted with 6% 
interest at 85; in 1820, there was a silver loan abroad with 5% in- 
terest at 72. For $31,632,250 of loans, the Government actually 
received only $22,933,381. Later further loans were contracted at 
77 to 77|. In 1823, the assignats or paper money in circulation 
amounted to $471,320,525.* In 1839, an attempt was made to 
restore the silver standard, and the exchange of the silver ruble for 

> U.S. Treasury Department, Circular 52 (Washington, 1913), pp. 16-17. 

' See Dewey, p. 471. ' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 272. 

* Mulhall (1899), p. 266. ' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 272. • Ibid. 



50 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

assignats was fixed at 350.^ Mulhall gives the total Russian debt 
in 1840 as about $720,000,000.* In 1843, the former bank assignats 
were withdrawn entirely from circulation by the creation of impe- 
rial bills of credit, which, with the forced exchange, were to circulate 
equally with the silver ruble. There came into existence $131,160,- 
205 of such biUs, with which the 461,496,035 assignats which were 
still current in 1843 had been redeemed. In this way was carried 
through the compromise of the debt.' 

The whole of the state property was to form security for the 
newly created imperial credit notes, and was to form sufficient 
capital for redemption. This state property was estimated at 
$3,063,903,399, but the redemption fund was not sufficient. 
Meanwhile the deficits in the state finances continued. In 1849, 
the paper money was reduced to $237,505,474. During the Cri- 
mean War, the issue of paper money increased greatly. In 1855, 
there were issued temporary bills of credit for "all the extraordi- 
nary expenses of the War " ! The Treasury did not wish to increase 
taxes. The export of gold was forbidden, and the mass of paper 
money issued was to be called in within three years after the resto- 
ration of peace. As a matter of fact, however, the amount was not 
diminished until long after this.* Dudley Baxter estimated the 
Russian debt in 1858, two years after the Crimean War, at about 
$1,152,000,000.^ 

In 1862, there was put out a silver loan to furnish means of re- 
storing a metal standard. The paper money was to be exchanged 
from May i, 1862, with a loss of io|%; afterward it was to be 
exchanged at a higher rate so that it should be at par by January 
I, 1864. A beginning was made, but the means available proved 
insufficient. By a decree of November 19, 1863, payment of the 
paper money again was deferred. The forced rate of exchange 
returned and with it the variation of the standards. The Russian 
state debt for many years increased in a most serious manner. 
Deficits were becoming a permanent evU.* MuIhaU gives the total 
Russian debt in 1875 as about $1,776,000,000 and in 1889 as about 
$3,628,800,000. He gives the origin of the debt existing at this 
time as follows:^ — 

• Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 272. ' Mulhall (1899), p. 266. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 272. * Ibid., pp. 272-73. ' Baxter (1871), p. 68. 

• Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 273. ' Mulhall {1899), p. 267. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 5 1 

Redemption of the serfs (1858-63) $408,000,000 

RaUways and telegraphs 816,000,000 

Crimean War 681,600,000 

Turkish War 638,400,000 

Sundries 1,084,800,000 

Total $3,628,800,000 

The Russo-Japanese War (1904-05) was responsible for a con- 
siderable increase in the Russian debt. This debt has been huge 
for many years; but the population and the resources of Russia 
have also been huge — although the latter still are largely unde- 
veloped. Baxter estimated the burden of the Russian debt, includ- 
ing railway guarantees, for 1868-70, on the basis of debt charge 
to estimated national income, as 2.5%.^ Our figure for 191 2, with- 
out deducting debt incurred for railways, is 2.77%. So far as the 
writer knows, Russia never has failed to fulfill her obligations to 
foreign creditors.^ As illustrating the fluctuations in Russian credit 
for the past forty years, Russian 4% railroad bonds (Nicolai) 
sold in 1877 — at the outbreak of the Turko-Russian War — on 
about a 6.49% income basis; in 189 1, they had recovered to about 
a 4.06% basis; and in 1896, 4% railroad bonds sold to yield only 
about 3.76%. In 1907, after Russia's defeat by Japan, Russian 
4% rentes sold to yield about 5.89%. 

The Italian Republics, as we mentioned in our introduction, 
very early inaugurated the system of funded debts. Early in the 
nineteenth century, the Kingdom of Naples was a large 
borrower in proportion to her means and developed ^ 
a debt of about $120,000,000. The Kingdom of Sardinia before its 
era of annexation was very economical, and In 1847 had a debt of 
only about $24,000,000. The troubles of 1848 and the wars with 
Austria and Russia increased the debt by 1858 to about $192,000,- 
000. On the constitution of the Kingdom of Italy in 186 1, the con- 
solidated Italian debt,' including more than $120,000,000 for that 
of Naples, amounted, according to Baxter, to about $403,200,000,^ 

• Baxter (1871), p. 92. * Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 273. 

• A decree of July, i86i, for altering all former bonds into new 5% bonds for the 
purpose of the unification of the state debts affected the creditors of the former states 
in very unequal degrees, though generally very seriously. The market price of the 
older bonds varied greatiy, but all were higher than the exchange for the new paper. 
(Tenth Census, vol. vii, p. 274.) 

• Baxter (1871), p. 58. 



52 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

and according to Professor Levi, to about $432,000,000.^ Thus 
Italy entered the family of nations burdened with a heavy debt 
in proportion to her resources, which at that time were compara- 
tively undeveloped.^ 

From 1 86 1 the debt increased rapidly. MulhalP gives the total 
debt in 1870 as $1,598,400,000; in 1880, as $1,886,400,000; and in 
1890, as about $2,208,000,000. A considerable part of this increase 
was caused by continual deficits.* Mulhall gives the debt^ about 
1890 as made up as follows: — 

Railways, about $384,000,000 

War and military expenditure 1,296,000,000 

Sundries 528,000,000 

Total $2,208,000,000 

The participation of Italy in the Triple Alliance and the ambi- 
tious colonial schemes under Crispi were responsible for a large 
part of the increase in the Italian debt and for the decline in her 
credit which at one time was so marked. In 1873, Italian 5% 
rentes sold to yield an income of about 7.80%, and in 1894, sold on 
about a 6.05% basis. Later, with the abandonment of her ambi- 
tious schemes of expansion, Italian credit recovered. In July, 1906, 
there took place a successful conversion of the 5% gross (4% net) 
and the 4% net rentes into 3!% stock, to be reduced after five 
years to 3!%. The amoimt converted was about $1,555,283,486, 
and the saving in interest was about $3,840,000 per annum for the 
first five years and about double that afterwards.® In January, 
1913, Italian 3!% rentes sold to yield only about 3.65%. The na- 
tional debt of Italy ever since the foundation of the modem king- 
dom has been a heavy burden on the population and resources of 
the country. Deficits have been frequent and the burden of taxa- 
tion very great. ^ The interest on the debt has absorbed a large part 
of the government expenditure. Yet Italians have repurchased a 
large part of their national debt formerly held in other countries. 

At the death of Frederick the Great in 1786, Prussia not only had 

' Levi, Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (1862), vol. xxv, p. 327. 

^ Hid. » Mulhall (1899), P- 268. < Baxter (1871), p. 58. 

» Mulhall (1899), p. 268. 

' Encyclopedia Briiannica (nth ed., 1911), vol. XV, p. 23. 

' Bastable (1895), p. 603. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 53 

no national debt, but had about $52,500,000 in the government 
vaults at Berlin, which money afterwards was used in „ 

,, .'_, -ri-.-^ ■, • ■, r Germany 

the wars agamst Napoleon I.^ In 1800, the capital of 
the debt, according to Baxter, was only about $25,200,000. By 
1820, however, on account of the Napoleonic wars, it had risen to 
about $148,800,000. This debt weighed heavily upon a nation of 
10,000,000 to 11,000,000 people ruined by invasions and warfare. 
Yet in 1842, nearly $48,000,000 had been paid off, and the debt 
was reduced to about $100,800,000.^ This was done through the 
sale of public property and through taxation. In 1848, the interest 
charge was only about $3,120,000.' 

After the Revolutions of 1848, a series of deficits took place 
which increased the debt rapidly. Between 1850 and 1864 a num- 
ber of loans were contracted for military preparations and for the 
construction of great lines of railway. These loans brought the 
debt in 1866 to about $201,600,000. The war with Austria brought 
the debt in 1870 to about $272,160,000, to which should be added 
the debts of the States aimexed in 1866, amounting to about 
$46,560,000 — making a total debt for Prussia and annexed States 
in 1870 of about $318,720,000.^ The total debt of the German 
Empire and States in 1870 has been given by Baxter as follows: — 

Prussia and annexed States $318,720,000 

Remaining North German States 137,760,000 

South German States 236,160,000 

German Confederate loans of 1867 and July and Decem- 
ber, 1870 127,680,000 

Total capital debt, German Empire and States, 

1870, about $820,320,000 

Of this total capital, about $327,912,000 represented expendi- 
tures for railways and pubUc works, so that the unremunerative 
debt was only about $492,408,000. The total interest of the debt 
in 1870 was about $35,232,000. To take care of this charge, the 
German States had the net receipts of their railways and the pro- 
duce of the public mines and iron works, which in Prussia, Saxony, 
and other States balanced the interest of the debts.^ The accom- 

1 Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 277. ' Baxter (1871), p. 38. 

» Bastable (1895), p. 604. ♦ Baxter (1871), pp. 38-39, 

' Ibid., pp. 39-40. 



54 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

panying table ^ shows the debts of Prussia and of the prindpal 
German States combined, including Prussia, for 1881, 1891, 1901, 
1908, and 1912. 



DEBTS OF THIRTEEN GERMAN STATES 





zSSi 


iSffi 


igoi 


1908 


ifii 




$463,740,000 
760,864,000 


$1,376,824,000 
791,780,000 


$1,558,072,000 
981,524,000 


$1,879,268,000 
1,236,168,000 


$2,225,214,264 


Twelve other states 


1,471,428,046 


Total 


$1,224,604,000 


$2,168,604,000 


$2,539,596,000 


$3,115,436,000 


$3,696,642,310 



$1.00 = so pence English 
z mark = zx.8 pence English 

Owing to the fact that such a large proportion of the debts of the 
German States is for productive purposes, these debts have been a 
very slight, if any, burden on the States. We have called attention 
to this fact in estimating the burden of debt earlier in this chapter. 
Baxter has estimated percentage of debt charge to national income 
for Prussia and the German States, 1815-20, at 1.3%; for Prussia 
and Germany, 1837-43, at .6%.^ If we deduct from the debts of 
the German States the value of the railways, the burden of the 
debt in 191 2 wiU prove very slight. 

The imperial debt, however, is much more a dead-weight debt. 
It has been created largely for military purposes. In 1881 , the debt 
of the Empire was only about $63,200,800; in 1891, it had risen to 
about $311,000,800; and in 1908, to about $1,003,826,000. Between 
1881 and 1908, the imperial debt has been multiplied more than 
fifteen times.' The expedition to China, the wars in Southwest 
Africa, and the construction of the Kaiser-Wilhelm (Kiel) Canal 
were responsible for an increase of about $195,408,000 in the 
imperial debt.* By far the largest single item added to the debt on 
behalf of all the States of the Empire is that for the imperial army 
and the next largest item for the imperial navy.* In addition to the 
funded debt of the Empire, there is a considerable floating debt 
consisting of long-term and short-term Treasury issues. The first 

' Hirst, p. 67, and Statistisches Jahrbuch (Berlin, 1913), p. 346. 

' Baxter (1871), pp. 89-91. 

• Hirst, p. s6. * Ibid., p. 57- ' Ibid., p. 58, 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 55 

class increased greatly between 1898 and 1908.^ The debt charge * 
of the German imperial debt was estimated by Baxter for 1868-70 
at about 1% of national income. Our figure for the Empire in 1912 
is .55%, and for the Empire and States combined, 2.13%. 

It can be seen that the debt burden of the German States and 
of the German Empire throughout their history has been compara- 
tively shght.* The record of good faith and of debt payment also 
has been in both cases excellent. The great European war wiU put 
the German people, however, to a test of a severity never before 
experienced or even probably clearly conceived. The credit of 
Prussia and of the German Empire during recent years has corre- 
sponded very closely.* It reached its highest point since 1873 ia 
April, 1903, when Prussian 3^% consols sold to yield a net income 
of about 3.48%. 

The Japanese debt, like that of the German Empire, is a matter 
of comparatively recent history. When the fiefs were surrendered 
to the sovereign at the beginning of the Meiji Era 
(1867), it was decided to provide for the feudal nobles 
and the Samurai by the payment of lump sums in commutation or 
by giving to them public bonds. On this account there were issued 
$93,835,000 of bonds. This was the foundation of the Japanese 
national debt. It represented the bulk of the State's liabilities dur- 
ing the first twenty-five years of the Meiji period. There were 
issued also $10,535,000 bonds in part payment for the debts of the 
fiefs. The Satsuma Revolt in 1877 was responsible for a loan of 
$7,350,000. Other loans were raised as follows: For public works, 
$16,170,000; $6,370,000 for naval construction, and $7,105,000 in 
connection with fiat currency — making a total of $149,450,000. 
This represented the whole national debt of Japan for the first 
twenty-eight years of her new era under imperial administra- 
tion.' 

The war with China (1894-95) caused a large increase in the 
Japanese debt. The direct expenditures on account of the war were 

' Hirst, p. 63. 

' Baxter takes the debt charge exclusive of sinking fund and surpluses applicable 
to a reduction of the debt. (1871), p. 44. 

' Imperial taxation per head, however, almost quadrupled in the thirty-six years 
between 1872 and 1908, having risen from about $1.42 to about $5.19. (Hirst, p. 52.) 

* Hirst, p. 69. ' Encyclopcedia Britannica (nth ed., 1911), vol. xv, p. 218. 



56 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

about $98,000,000, of which about $66,150,000 were added to the 
national debt. Following the war there was begun a large pro- 
gramme of armaments and public works. The expenditures for 
the unproductive purposes, including coast fortifications, dock- 
yards, and similar works, came to $153,860,000. The total for 
productive expenditures — $93,100,000 — was made up partly 
as follows: For railways, telegraphs, and telephones, $58,800,000; 
$9,800,000 for riparian improvements; and $9,800,000 in aid of 
industrial and agricultural banks and similar enterprises. The 
whole programme, which, with trifling exceptions, was to be in 
operation by 1905, involved an outlay of $246,960,000. Of this the 
Chinese indemnity, the surplus of the annual revenue, and other 
assets furnished about $147,000,000. It was the intention to raise 
the remaining $99,960,000 through domestic loans. It was found 
impossible to obtain the money necessary at home without paying 
an excessive rate of interest. In 1899, a loan of about $48,000,000 
at 4% was obtained in London. These bonds were sold at 90. In 
1902, all Japanese domestic loans were on a uniform basis. They 
carried 5% interest, ran for five years without redemption, and 
were then to be redeemed within fifty years at the latest. The 
redemption was to be by purchasing the stock in the open market 
or by drawing lots. It was expected that the national debt would 
reach its maximum — $281,750,000 — in 1903.^ 

The war with Russia, however, upset these calculations. Peace 
came in the autumn of 1905. Japan had been obKged to borrow 
$198,450,000 at home and $516,460,000 abroad. In 1908, the total 
debt amounted to $1,115,240,000. Of this, $543,900,000 was 
domestic debt and $571,340,000 represented foreign borrowings. 
The debt had grown from $274,890,000 in 1904 to $1,115,240,000 
in 1908, or from $5.54 per head in 1904 to $21.46 per head in 1908. 
The debt carried interest of from 4% to 5%.* Soon after the war 
with Russia, seventeen private railways were nationalized at a 
cost of $245,000,000. This brought the state debt to $1,360,240,000 
in all. In 1908, a scheme was adopted for appropriating at least 
$24,500,000 annually for the purpose of redeeming the debt.' Ow- 
ing to the undeveloped character of her resources and to the more 

^ Encydopcedia Britannica (nth ed., 1911), vol. xv, pp. 218-19. 
' Ibid. p. 219. ' Ibid. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 57 

or less confused condition of her finances, the debt incurred during 
the war with Russia has been a very heavy burden upon Japan. 
With her expansion in Korea and China, however, provided she 
keeps out of further wars for some time, Japan probably will be 
able to take care of this debt without serious trouble. The present 
great war, in which Japan has been a participant, has added only 
moderately to her financial burdens. 

We have dealt at greater or less length with the debt histories of 
the nations which to-day are considered the great Powers. We 
have traced also in a general way the origin and devel- 
opment of national debts in Europe and America, national 
We have referred also to the epidemic of borrowing 
which broke out in the second half of the nineteenth century and 
which did not subside until aU the South European states, such as 
Spain, Portugal, and Italy, and the Spanish and Portuguese states 
of South America, had entered the money market. Some nations 
borrowed for war, others for railways — but all borrowed. Be- 
tween 1848 and 1873, the debts of the defaulting states of Spain 
and her colonies tripled. They probably stopped even at this figure 
only from the impossibility of further borrowing.^ In discussing 
this situation ia 1874, Dudley Baxter divided the nations of the 
world in debt matters into the following four classes: 

(i) Economical states, whose debts grow less in proportion to 
their resources. 

(2) Vigorous borrowing states, that borrow freely but not beyond 
their resources. 

(3) Over-borrowing and declining states, whose debts are heavy 
and continually increase more rapidly than their resources. 

(4) Defaulting or insolvent states. 

In the first class — that is, the economical states — Baxter at 
that time placed the United Kingdom, Denmark, HoUand, Bel- 
gium, the German States, the British Colonies and Sweden;^ in 
the class of defaulting or insolvent states he listed Spain, Greece, 
Ecuador, Mexico, Venezuela, San Domingo, and Honduras. Bax- 
ter spoke of zones of credit around the center of good credit, 

• Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (1874), vol. xxxvn, p. 8. 
' He does not include the United States, which was then struggling to pay off its 
great Civil War debt. 



58 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

London. He referred to the countries of low interest as being all in 
the North and all Teutonic, such as England, Denmark, Holland, 
Germany, and Sweden.^ These observations have an interesting 
bearing to-day. 

Principal loans ^^^ accompanying table (page 59) shows the amount 
in default, of loans of independent governments listed by the 

1877-1914, as . 

Usted by the Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders as 
of°^dgn " being in default as to principal at various periods 
Bondholders between 1877 and 1912. 

The figures for 1912 show only Guatemala and Honduras in 
default as to the principal of their loans. Since 191 2, however, 
Mexico again has joined the hst of defaulting states with an ap- 
proximate amount of principal in default of $170,531,102.^ 

Perhaps, as bearing on credit, more important even than the 
record of good faith is what may be called the general standing of 
General ^ nation in the civilized world. This factor, indeed, 

standing of a more than any other, may be said to determine na- 

nation the . ■' ' , •' . 

most important tional Credit at any given time. How do the great 
nations of the world stand to-day? What are the 
forms of their governments, the nature of their institutions, the 
character of their people, and their military and economic posi- 
tions? Are they developing or are they declining, or, as we some- 
times say, are they "coming" or "going"? 

We have indicated earher in this chapter the nature of the insti- 
tutions of the United States. Its government, of course, is that of a 
Forms of federal republic of independent or balanced powers, 

f°™™s™tu- legislative, executive, and judicial. In the early days 
CTeatpLwere— °^ ^^ RepubHc, pubhc Opinion was formed largely 
United States through the exchange of views among a few leading 
men. Actually the government was aristocratic rather than dem- 
ocratic. After the people of the Eastern States crossed the Alle- 
gheny Mountains, however, and settled the West, actual democ- 
racy under the conditions of frontier life developed rapidly. From 
the time of Andrew Jackson until the present, popular government 
or government controlled by the will of the great mass of the people 

' Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (March, 1874), vol. xxxvn, pp. 2-13. 
' Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, Forty-First Annual Getieral 
Report, p. 369. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 59 



< 

a 



CO 



> 
O 

o 

H 

I 
P 

W 

a 



o 



s 



3 

9\ 



I I I I I ^|l I I I I 



I I 



I III Is 



tC CO 

■ M 



11 II i I II 



I 



o 









'8 I I E?J?| I 



O I I H 

vo ' ' a« 



8 §§ 

ill I I I i€l I I I I M 



ovo g 


00 o 


vo CO 5 






o« 






CO O 1 


1 o'oo" 






VO »•* 


" ^ 



1 1 



s 



^ 



8 Q OvO Q O O Q Ovo C 
O Q'O cog «*■« O^t^T 

«^ ci^ q^ lo M^ q^oq^ o; •^•o w < 
ioio« o MOO tI-w ^*« t^< 
looo" i-T cT lo 



is 2 

IliliillJ 







5 

•a 



^ ^ 



II 



M tS 







■-J S.8,a 

.2S"3.Si 




6o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

has grown steadily.^ To-day public opinion, instead of being 
formed from the top downwards, is formed through newspapers 
and otherwise from the bottom upward to the highest ofl&dals of 
the Government. This, in our opinion, is a great factor in national 
safety and in national credit. It means that back of any important 
move on the part of the American Government is the opinion of a 
majority, if not practically aU, of the American people. 

Much the same situation prevails in England — though the 
actual form of the Gtovenmient is that of a constitutional monarchy 

with a ministry responsible to the House of Commons. 

The Reform Bill of 1832 represented the spread of the 
democratic idea in England. The Government of England before 
that time had been a Government largely of country squires. With 
the growth of manufacturing and of the cities and with the repeal 
of the Com Laws, there developed a democracy based on indus- 
trialism. Great impetus has been given to the democratic move- 
ment in England during the past ten years. 

The Government in France is a curious compromise between the 
English and the American systems. The French Government of 

to-day is more or less of a makeshift. It grew out of 

the critical necessities of the French people after their 
defeat by Prussia in 1871. Its efficiency remains to be proved. 
The paternal nature of the Government, the centralization of 
power, and the system of administrative courts, by which the acts 
of the Government are dealt with under a different system of law 
from that of the acts of individuals — aU are imfamiliar to the 
Anglo-Saxon mind. In the Chamber of Deputies there exist a large 
nimiber of groups of various shades of opinion instead of the two 
parties with which Englishmen and Americans are familiar. Presi- 
dent LoweU makes the point that since the Third Republic there 
have been frequent changes in ministries, but no real changes in the 
party in control of the Government.^ Incoherent as the French 
govermnent sometimes seems, it has this one great underlying 
virtue: it derives its authority from the people. 
The Govermnent of Italy is that of a constitutional monarchy 

' See E. L. Godkin, Unforeseen Tendencies of Democracy (Boston and New York, 
1898), pp. 1-47 and 183-223. 

' A. Lawrence Lowell, The Governments of Prance, Italy, and Germany (Cambridge, 
1914)1 P- 114. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 6l 

with a parliamentary system. The ministers are responsible to the 
popular House. Owing to the system of groups, however, rather 
than parties, — which we have spoken of in connec- 
tion with France, — the parliamentary system in 
Italy does not work with anything like the smoothness and preci- 
sion that it does in England. The power of the King sometimes is 
considerable.^ 

The Government of Germany, imlike that of the others so far 
mentioned, instead of being democratic in its general character, is 
aristocratic and autocratic. There is, of course, a 
popular house, the Reichstag, but the real power in 
the government of the Empire and in practically all matters of 
common interest of the various German States is exercised by the 
Bundesrath or Federal Council — "that extraordinary mixture of 
legislative chamber, executive council, court of appeal, and perma- 
nent assembly of diplomats." * The Bundesrath is composed of dele- 
gates appointed by the princes of the States and the senates of the 
Free Cities.' Owing to the position of Prussia in the Bundesrath 
and in the Empire, the German Emperor as King of Prussia is in a 
position to control pretty largely the affairs of the Empire. There 
is lacking any effective method of bringing to bear the force of pub- 
lic opinion in matters of government. In Germany as in France, 
moreover, there exists an extreme centralization and paternalism. 
This is carried sometimes to the smallest matters in the daily lives 
of the people.* Suppression of newspapers and of public meetings 
for expressing sentiments contrary to the opinions of those high in 
authority has been common.* Price CoUier has referred to the 
conditions in Germany as " the governing of the people by suppres- 
sion and strangulation." * All this has been done in the name of 
efficiency. There is, in a broad way, an ominous similarity between 
the relation of the German people to their Government at present 
and that of the French people to their Government before the 
French Revolution.^ The German people have a splendid record 

» Lowell, pp. 125-27. ' Ibid., p. 191. ' Ibid. 

* Price Collier, Germany and the Germans (New York, 1914), p. 399. 

» Ibid., pp. 163-65. ' I^i^-> P- 498- 

' For tie alternative of revolution under an extreme development of the protective 
system, see Buckle's remarks on Spain, History of CivUizaUon (New York, 1861), vol. 
n, pp. 123-24. 



62 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

for the payment of their debts; but what will be their attitude if 
they find themselves saddled with a debt of unprecedented and 
almost unimagined size, incurred for a purpose which has proved 
fruitless of results, disastrous to their economic and financial condi- 
tion, and unfortunate in its effect on the relations of the German 
people with the people of other nations? 

The Government of Austria-Himgary is that of a constitutional 
Empire composed of two autonomous kingdoms — Austria and 
Austria- Hungary. Each retains a large measure of indepen- 

Hungary dence. The personal power of the present Emperor, 

Francis Joseph I, has been great. The bond between Austria and 
Hungary, however, with their many divergent and sometimes an- 
tagonistic races, is at best a weak one. If the present war should 
have an unfortunate outcome for Austria-Hungary, it would leave 
that country with its large debts in a situation which would offer 
very little inducement to make new loans and perhaps even make 
doubtful the collection of a large part of her present obligations. 
The very existence of Austria-Hungary as one, or even as two 
nations, is at present an enigma.^ 

The Government of Russia still is almost entirely autocratic — 
though the machinery has been furnished for a later 
development of something like popular government. 
The rulers of Russia have shown a disposition to make concessions, 
even though small ones, to the people. It is doubtful whether the 
Russian people at present are fitted for a greater degree of self- 
government than they now possess, though there are signs of dis- 
quiet and discontent with present conditions. Many agrarian and 
economic problems remain to be worked out, and the great natural 
resources of Russia remain to be developed. Progress toward popu- 
lar government in Russia will be either through concessions granted 
by the Czars and the governing class or by revolution. There is 
nothing at the moment, as far as the relations of the people to their 
Government go, which would lead one to fear for the payment of 
their national debt. 

The Government of the only other coimtry under special con- 
sideration — that of Japan — is a constitutional monarchy with a 

■ For the system of government in Austria-Hungary, see Encydopadia Britannica 
(nth ed., 1911), vol. ni, p. 2. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 63 

large amount of power in times of crisis or of great importance 
in the hands of a small group of men known as the Elder States- 
men. The Ministers of State or the Cabinet are ap- 
pointed by the Emperor and are responsible to him 
alone. ^ There is a diet of two houses. The Government seems to 
work reasonably well. 

The character of the population has an important bearing on 
credit. The population of the United States is, on the whole, better 
than that of any other great civiKzed nation. It has character of 
vigor and ability, resourcefulness, knowledge, and the population 
general individual efficiency of a high order. During the past one 
hundred years the population of Great Britain has been much the 
same. The English-speaking race as a whole has been during that 
time the most remarkable of all the races of the world. The popu- 
lation of France and Germany is highly intelligent and efficient. 
That of Russia, while vigorous and patient, is lacking in resource- 
fulness and adaptability. It is what may be called relatively unde- 
veloped. It was not until 1863 that serfdom was completely 
abohshed.^ The population of Austria-Hungary is the least homo- 
geneous of aU the nations under consideration. Germans, Magyars, 
Serbs, Czechs, Poles, and Croats live imder one scepter in a condi- 
tion sometimes bordering on anarchy. The people of Japan are 
notably homogeneous and have shown a remarkable adaptability 
to modem ideas and methods. In the matter of education or liter- 
acy, Germany, the United States, and Great Britain make the best 
showing, and Russia, Hungary, Italy, and Japan ' the poorest.* 
IlUteracy or ignorance is a bad companion for financial responsibil- 
ity, though the two sometimes are found together. The character 
of the population of many Central and South American countries 
probably is the main reason not only for the instability of their 
governments, but for their relatively low credit. 

' Encyclopmdia Britannica (11th ed., 1911), vol. xv, p. 203. 

' Ploetz, p. 500. 

' Elementary education in Japan is now, however, compulsory. (JStatesman's Year- 
Book [1915], p. 1091.) 

* MuLhall (1899), p. 231. Webb (1911), p. 219. Statesman's Year-Booh (1915), 
passim. In some parts of Russia, illiteracy is over 50%; in Hxmgary it is between 40% 
and 45%; and in Italy between about 33% and about 49% as against 7.7% in 1910 for 
the United States. {Statesman's Year-Book (i9iS),PP- 434> 700, 1060 and 1281.) 



64 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Another important factor in credit is the military standing of a 
nation. History has shown that no nation that is not in a condition 
Miutary of actual or potential military efficiency long con- 

position tinues to have good credit. A striking illustration is 

that of China with its immense population and wealth and its rec- 
ord of good faith. The inability or unwillingness of China to defend 
itself has kept its credit at a relatively low point. Germany, France, 
Russia, Austria-Hungary, Italy, and the Balkan coimtries all have 
adopted the policy of imiversal liability to military service.^ The 
United States and Great Britain have followed the policy of main- 
taining small standing armies and depending on volimteers in time 
of war. If all countries adopt the plan of universal military service, 
it will lose its value for any one coimtry; if all finally renounce it, 
all countries will be equal in this respect and will have the advan- 
tage of being able to use their resources for productive purposes. At 
the same time, ability and willingness to fight when necessary are 
absolutely essential imder any conditions known to human history 
for the continuance of successful national existence. Without the 
ability to defend its territory, population, and resources, a nation 
has the least secure of all foundations for national credit. In this 
respect the United States, with its enormous resources, its at- 
tempted maintenance of the Monroe Doctrine, and its participa- 
tion in the affairs of the Old World, is in a weak position at the 
moment.^ At the same time it is only fair to say that the United 
States, no less than the other great nations of the world, — Great 
Britain, France, Germany, Italy, Austria-Hxmgary, Russia, and 
Japan, — may be called actually or potentially a first-class military 
nation. 

Another important consideration in determining national credit 
is the economic situation. This may be said to embrace the position 
General ^^ ^ country in regard to farming and to its food sup- 

economic plies, its position as to manufacturing and its position 

as to internal and foreign commerce. That country 
which comes the nearest to economic self-sufficiency is in the safest 
position and has, other things being equal, the best basis for good 

* Statist (London), vol. ixxxi, p. 350. 

' Steps are being taken to remedy this condition. (See Commercial and Financial 
Chronide, vol. loi, p. 337.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 65 

credit. Of the nations under discussion, probably the United 
States and Russia come the nearest to complete economic self- 
sufficiency. In this respect, however, the position of the United 
States is immeasurably better than that of Russia. The United 
States produces within its own continental borders almost every- 
thing it needs, not only in the way of food supplies, but in raw 
materials for its enormous and constantly increasing industries. 
Great Britain is in the weakest position in this respect. She is 
obhged to import from three quarters to four fifths of her food and 
a large part of her raw materials.^ France, owing to its system of 
intensive farming, usually imports only a moderate amount of food. 
Germany, Austria-Hungary, Italy, and Japan all have a consider- 
able degree of economic self-sufficiency. The great manufacturing, 
foreign commerce, shipping, and banking of Great Britain, pro- 
tected by her navy, in her case have removed farming as a factor of 
any significance. On account of being, however, absolutely de- 
pendent on her navy even for her food supplies. Great Britain is in 
a more precarious position than some of the other countries under 
consideration. Throughout the nineteenth century and the open- 
ing years of the twentieth, there has been a constantly increasing 
development of the great nations of the world in manufacturing or 
industry at the expense of farming. Great Britain, France, and 
Germany particularly have developed their manufactures and in- 
creased their foreign trade with the other nations of the world. 
They have purchased food or raw materials from the younger and 
less developed coimtries, such as the United States,^ Russia, and 
Argentina, and have sold them their finished products, such as 
cotton and woolen goods, iron and steel manufactures, and many 
other articles required. They have also loaned largely of their ac- 
cumulated capital to the countries which were in a position to fur- 
nish them with food or raw materials. The extraordinary develop- 
ment of the United States during the past fifty years has been 
possible largely through obtaining capital from Europe — espe- 
cially England. Russia has been financed for many years largely 
by France.^ 

* See the Statisl, vol. lxxxi, p. 533. 

2 Of recent years the United States, while still an enonnous producer of food and 
raw materials, is coming to be more and more a manufacturing or industrial nation. 

» For an interesting discussion of this subject, see Sir George Paish in the Statist, 
vol. LXXXI, p. 463. 



66 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The trade or commerce of a nation shows in a broad way its 
economic position. The domestic trade of the United States is 
Trade many times greater than its foreign trade. The 

position Bureau of Statistics, Department of Co mm erce, has 

estimated our domestic commerce in 191 1 at $33,000,000,000, or 
nearly ten times our foreign trade for the same year. The same 
authority has estimated our domestic commerce in 1914 at $40,- 
000,000,000 * made up as follows: — 

Manufactures $24,000,000,000 

Agricultural products 10,000,000,000 

Mineral products 2,500,000,000 

Fisheries 500,000,000 

Value added to all this by 

transportation 1,000,000,000 

Imports 2,000,000,000 

$40,000,000,000 

This huge total largely has made possible annual savings esti- 
mated at $6,720,000,000 a year.^ It shows on how broad and firm 
a basis the credit of the United States rests. In a broad way, the 
trade position of a nation is not merely the domestic or the foreign 
commerce in merchandise, or both together, but rather the position 
as debtor or creditor in toto. In other words, we must examine the 
position of a nation not only as to its domestic conmierce and its 
merchandise imports and exports, but also as to whether it is a 
debtor or creditor in the matter of interest on securities, whether it 
receives a large portion of the freight charges in international trade, 
whether it receives an excess of banking or other conunissions, and 
other similar considerations. 

We give below table showing merchandise imports and exports, 
excess of either, and total foreign trade of the principal commercial 
Foreign nations of the world for the year ending December 31, 

commerce 1912. We take this year in order to show fairly normal 

conditions and in order to correlate the figxires with our figures of 
estimated resources and debt. 

' This compares with only $7,000,000,000 as the internal conunerce of the United 
States in 1870. (From address of O. P. Austin, chief of the former Bureau of Statistics, 
Department of Commerce, enclosed with letter from Department, May 20, 1915-) 

' Statist, vol. Lxxxi, p. 608. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS (>J 



Q 
< 
Pi 

I— I 
W 
(4 
O 



•f 8 



I 
It 



§1. 



I 






=^ 8 



8 § § 



O M 



00 
NO 



i i I 






I 



O VO 



o 



8 8 8 8 8 

« Tj- O \0 00 



i-i o» 

H CO 






8> 



o 



8 8 



o 
o 

»o_ 
to 



o 


O* 


t^ 


VO 


^0 


o 














H 


O 


fO 


M 


H 


o 



I 



•c 

pq 



I 

i 



O O 



CO 

I 



tn 



•H 








g 




M 


^ 





rt 


's 


¥ 




3 


P4 


< 



3 I 






w J3 



•SiiB 



. . I. . s = a 



68 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

On a merchandise basis, of recent years at any rate, the United 
States and Russia are the only great nations that have shown a 
normal excess of exports over imports. In other words, not only 
Great Britain, France, and Germany, but also Austria-Hxmgary, 
Italy, and Japan have shown of recent years an excess of imports 
over exports.^ 

On the other hand, the United States and Russia have been 
heavy annual debtors in the matter of interest on securities, 
Invisible whcreas Great Britain, France, Holland, and probably 

trade balance Germany have been creditors in this respect. The 
United States has been a heavy debtor also in the matters of 
freights, commissions, money sent abroad by immigrants, and 
taken abroad by travelers — in fact, in almost every item which 
enters into what is caUed the "invisible trade balance." Great 
Britain, on the other hand, has been a creditor in all or almost all 
these respects. She has had a surplus fund invested in securities all 
over the world. She has done a very large percentage of the carry- 
ing trade of the world and a very large proportion of its banking 
business.^ In other words, while the merchandise foreign trade of 
the United States has appeared to show her the largest creditor and 
that of Great Britain has appeared to show her the largest debtor, 
the factors in the invisible trade balance have resulted in a situation 
actually very different. Great Britain and the United States offer 
the two most striking examples of the interplay of foreign com- 
merce and the invisible items of the trade balance. Sir George 
Paish has estimated Great Britain's capital investments in foreign 
and colonial countries as about $i5,ooo,ooo,cx>o.^ He has estimated 
more recently that Great Britain receives from colonial and foreign 
nations a total income of about $1,680,000,000 a year. On the basis 
of a difference between merchandise imports and exports of, say, 

* statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. 99-111. 

* Until recently practically every transaction in American foreign exchange 
amounting to $100,000 or over has gone, the writer has been told, through London. 

* He gives (reduced from pounds sterling at the rate of $4.80 to the poimd): — 

Total investments in Colonies, India, and foreign countries $15,320,813,800 

Investments in British Colonies and India $7,450,929,600 

Investments in foreign coimtries 7,860,883,200 

Capital investments exceeding £50,000,000 ($340,000,000): — 

In the United States $3,303,774,400 

In Argentine 1,295,078400 

In Brazil 453,312.000 

In Mexico , 419,203,300 

In Japan 257,784,000 

(Jourtul djlhe Royal Statiitical Society, Jtauiuy, igii, p. 186.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 69 

$625,000,000, Great Britain is able to purchase something like 
$1,000,000,000 a year of securities from abroad.^ The amount of 
European capital invested in what may be called permanent securi- 
ties in the United States before the war has been estimated by the 
National City Bank of New York — taking into consideration the 
figures of Sir George Paish in 1910, the recent figures of Mr. L. F. 
Loree for railroads, and the recent figures of the New York Clearing- 
House for industrials — at between $5,000,000,000 and $6,500,- 
000,000.^ The net payments by the United States to other coun- 
tries of items entering into the invisible trade balance have beea 
somewhat as follows: — 

Net interest on foreign capital $250,000,000 

Net balance of expenditure of American 

citizens in other lands 170,000,000 

Net remittances of foreign-bom citizens 

to friends in Europe and elsewhere . . . 150,000,000 
Net sum paid to other countries for ocean 

freights 25,000,000' 

Total of items owed on the invisible 

trade balance $595,000,000 *" 

This accoimts in a general way for the normal excess of merchan- 
dise exports over imports shown by the United States. All foreign 
trade must be settled finally with merchandise, services, or gold. At 
any given time, however, the import or export of capital to be set- 

* Statist (London), vol. LXXXi, pp. 393-94. 

' Letter of National City Bank, dated July 3, 1915. — See also Economist (London), 
July 17, 191S (vol. Lxxxi), p. 84. The amoimt of American securities held abroad 
necessarily is a matter of opinion. 

' Trade Balance of the United States (jgio), p. 191. Figures of Dr. E. E. Pratt, chief 
of the Bureau of Foreign and Domestic Commerce, as given in an address at the an- 
nual meeting of the California Bankers' Association, San Francisco, May 27, 1915, 
gave the total estimated debt of the United States to Europe as $7,000,000,000 owing 
principally to the following coimtries: — 

England $4,000,000,000 

France 1,000,000,000 

Germany 1,250,000,000 

Holland 650,000,000 

Dr. Pratt estimated: — 

Net interest on securities $300,000,000 

Tourist expenditures 250,000,000 

Remittances to friends 150,000,000 

Freights 50,000,000 

Total $750,000,000 

For the fiscal year ending June 30, 1914, Dr. Pratt estimated that we had to make 
payments to Europe amoimting to $55,000,000 more than the total amount of mer- 
chandise exported. 



70 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

tied with securities may play a large part. The great lending coiin- 
tries have been Great Britain, France, Holland, Germany, Belgium, 
and Switzerland. Of these countries Great Britain has been by far 
the most important lender, with, as stated above, foreign invest- 
ments in the neighborhood of $15,000,000,000. Germany and 
France come next with investments of, say, about $8,000,000,000 
each.^ The investments of HoUand, Belgium, and Switzerland are 
of much smaller amount, but are nevertheless considerable. The 
merchandise imports of all these five coimtries largely exceed their 
exports in consequence of receipt of interest and of tourist expendi- 
tures. In the case of Great Britain, excess is paid for further by the 
earnings of British ships, the toimage of which forms such a large 
part of the world's international shipping facilities.* A large excess 
of merchandise imports over exports usually indicates that a coim- 
try is in a position to receive a large amount of interest on capital 
invested in other countries; a large excess of exports over imports 
usually indicates that a country is forced to pay heavy simis in 
interest and dividends on its securities owned abroad. Sometimes 
an excess of merchandise imports over exports means the import of 
capital in the form of merchandise to be paid for with securities. 
The amount of American securities held abroad has been consider- 
ably reduced since the opening of the great war, though probably 
not to the extent that many accounts would lead one to believe.' 

' These facts should be borne in mind in estimating the ability of these nations to 
pay for the costliest war in history. 

' Trade Balance of the United Stales (igio), pp. 169-70. 

' A letter received from the National City Bank of New York, July 3, 19x5, sti- 
mates the amount of American securities repurchased from abroad since the beginning 
of the war at between $300,000,000 and $500,000,000. There has also been purchased 
in this coimtry a considerable amount of foreign government securities. 

We give below a list of loans to foreign nations raised in the United States from the 
beginning of the war up to October 23, 1915: — 

Russian Government acceptances $25,000,000 

French Government one-year notes 10,000,000 

French one-year 5% loan 50,000,000 

Dominion of Canada 5% one- and two-year notes 40,000,000 

Canadian Provincial and municipal loans 85,500,000 

Gennan nine-months 5% notes 10,000,000 

Swedish Government two-year notes 5,000,000 

Argentine National one-three-year loan 15,000,000 

Argentine five-year 6% bonds 25,000,000 

Norway short-term loan 3,000,000 

Bolivian loan j ,000,000 

Republic of Panama thirty-year 5 per cents 3,ooo'ooo 

Swiss Government one-five-year notes 15,000,000 

Anglo-French five-year 5% loan 500,000,000 

Italian one-year 6% notes 25,000,000 

Total $812 500 000 

(Slalisl [London], vol. utxxv, pp. 65 and 180.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 7I 

The United States also has purchased considerable amounts of 
foreign securities. 

All these naatters have an important bearing on the economic 
and financial status of a nation and therefore on its credit. The 
present war may change appreciably the relative rank „. . ^ 
of the great nations of the world. We will sketch theieading 
briefly their situation as it appears to-day. 

The United States, in the size and character of its territory and 
population, in the stability of its government, and in its general 
pohtical, commercial, and financial strength, holds . 
to-day an almost unique position. It has the almost the United 
unparalleled advantage of having been settled by a 
vigorous and intelligent population, possessed of all the knowledge 
of Europe at tJie time of settlement and then placed in possession 
of a vast territory with resources practically untouched. The devel- 
opment of these resources by such a population has brought the 
United States to its present commanding position. The opening of 
the Panama Canal, the new banking system, improved relations 
with South America, and the great war have given the United 
States an opportunity that comes to few nations at any time. Un- 
less the unforeseen happens, it is even more favorable than the 
situation of Great Britain after the Napoleonic wars; for the United 
States has one great advantage which was conspicuously absent in 
the case of Great Britain at that time — an exceedingly small 
national debt. The United States, moreover, not only is now ex- 
porting an excess of merchandise of something like $1,000,000,000 
a year (June 30, 1915), — which on such a scale as this is a tempo- 
rary state of affairs, — but is in a position to increase greatly its 
permanent or normal foreign trade. This is often the forerunner of 
a commanding financial position.^ The weak point in the economic 
situation of the United States is the lack of an adequate merchant 
marine. This should be remedied. With her enormous farming and 
manufacturipg interests, — greater than those of any other coun- 
try, — the United States is in a fair way to become the leading 
commercial and financial nation of the world. From almost any 
angle that one looks at it, this country is entitled to credit as high 
as that of any nation in the world. 

' See George J. Goschen, The Theory of the Foreign Exchanges (London, 1896), 
pp. 32-35- 



72 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

During the past one hundred years, Great Britain has been con- 
sidered, on the whole, the leading civilized nation in the world. 
. After the Seven Years' War in Europe and the French- 

and-Indian War in America, England became pre- 
dominant in the New World. By the final defeat of Napoleon, she 
established herself as the first nation in Europe. In a broad way 
this is the reason why British consols have sold for most of this 
period higher than the bonds of any other Government. As indi- 
cated earlier, however, the economic and political position of Great 
Britain to-day is by no means secure. On account of being abso- 
lutely dependent on her navy for the maintenance of her great 
position in the world, Great Britain is in a precarious and at times 
dangerous position. A serious impairment of her naval power 
might lead to the breaking-up of the British Empire as at present 
composed. The English-speaking, self-governing dominions, such 
as Canada, Australia, and South Africa, probably would grow in 
power and might remain strongly attached by ties of affection to 
the mother country; but the center of gravity of the Empire would 
be shifted. 

France in the early part of the eighteenth century was the first 
nation in Europe. In population, wealth, power, and prestige she 

clearly led all other nations. The long revolutionary 

wars of France, however, and her final defeat by the 
Allies left her greatly weakened. She never again recovered her 
leading position; but ia the thirty or forty years preceding the war 
of 1870 she showed a notable expansion in industry and wealth. 
With the halting of her own development after the war with Prus- 
sia, France became one of the principal lending nations of Europe. 
The French people have been exceedingly saving, and have not 
only made possible the wide distribution of French rentes in 
France, but the lending of large smns to Russia and other foreign 
countries. Since 1870, France has succeeded in building up a very 
respectable Colonial empire. 

Germany has shown an extraordinary growth in popvdation and 
wealth during the past forty years. She has not only made herself 
German *^^ Strongest single military power in Europe, but has 

developed her industries and her foreign trade to a 
point which threatened the supremacy of England. This extraor- 



XJNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 73 

dinary development made necessary also efforts toward outside 
expansion. The pressure of population in Germany probably has 
been greater than anywhere else, except possibly in Japan. ^ Ger- 
many's burdens for mihtary preparation have been great. Her 
colossal policies of expansion by force — sometimes described as 
Pan-Germanism ^ — have placed her in a precarious position. 
During the present war, she has not only increased enormously the 
burden of her debts, but has alienated to a large extent the friend- 
ship of the rest of the world. This cannot but react imfavorably 
on her credit. 

Italy and Austria-Hungary are relatively poor countries with 
heavy burdens of taxation and heavy debts. The financial condi- 
tion of each at many times has been precarious.* itaiy, Austria- 
Italy is making strenuous efforts to extend her bound- R^laTnd 
aries at the expense of Austria — particularly in what J^p^° 
are called " the unredeemed provinces," which include Trent and a 
portion of the eastern shores of the Adriatic. Russia is a country 
continental in area with by far the largest population of all the 
great powers. The resources of the country, however, are largely 
undeveloped, the railways are comparatively few, and the general 
economic and financial condition leaves great room for improve- 
ment. Her army has been to her a considerable burden.* Owing to 
her great resources, even though they are now undeveloped, 
Russia probably will be able to take care of her debts. Japan is a 
coimtry in which the best part of the population devotes itself to 
military pursuits. Business is regarded as a means to an end and 
business men as inferior to the military class. Japan has a large 
population for the size of its territory and the scantiness of its 
resources. Unless it can find and develop in Korea, and perhaps in 
China, a wealth that will enable it to become a rich and powerful 
industrial nation, "it cannot hope to satisfy its national ambitions 
to say nothing of its European creditors." ^ 

' Statistical Abstract for Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. S-ii. 

^ According to Professor Usher, the German dream of to-day has been the estab- 
Kshment of an empire comprising Germany, Holland, Belgium, Denmark, Switzer- 
land, Italy, Austria-Hungary, the Balkans, Turkey, and Asia Minor — a new world 
state bounded by the North Sea, the Baltic, the Persian Gulf, and the Mediterranean. 
(American Review of Reviews, November, 1914, p. 616.) 

' Economist (London), vol. Lxxix, p. 874, and vol. lxxx, p. 56. Statist (London), 
vol. Lxxxi, pp. 158-59, 349-50, and 552. 

* Statist (London), vol. lxxxi, p. 530. ' Economist (London), vol. lxxx, p. 671, 



74 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

We have discussed in a general way the credit of the leading civ- 
ilized nations of the world. We have gone into the leading factors 
Prices of making up their credit under what may be called 

foTs'an/of" normal conditions. Before discussing the bearing of 
French rentes ^jjg present great war on national credit, we wish to 
give an idea of the course of prices of some of the leading govern- 
ment bonds for a series of years. Since the close of the eighteenth 
century, the credit of Great Britain has been most of the time 
higher than that of any other nation. France for most of the time 
has held second position — though at times French credit has been 
strained severely. The accompanying table (on page 75) shows 
the highest and lowest prices by ten-year periods for a long series of 
years of British consols, and French rentes. 

An examination of these prices makes one feel that government 
bonds should be thought of more as one thinks of stocks — that is, 
as being liable to great fluctuations. In fact, the common European 
name for government securities is stocks. We should think of these 
securities, especially as there is no legal means of enforcing pay- 
ment, as fluctuating with the position and prosperity of the nation 
almost as much as does the common stock of a railroad or an indus- 
trial concern. This may seem an extreme statement; but the record 
of national good faith and the fluctuation in the prices of govern- 
ment securities make it entirely reasonable. 

Still more will this appear when we extend our investigations to 
the prices of government bonds other than English and French. 
Prices of The accompanjdng table (on page 77) shows the high- 

omnent^bonds, ^st and lowest prices on an income basis for ten-year 
1873-1912 periods, mostly siace 1873, of United States bonds, 

British consols, French rentes, Prussian consols, Italian, Austrian, 
Russian, and Japanese bonds. 

In discussing the debt histories of the individual nations, we 
have referred at times to the prices of their bonds. It is not always 
possible to correlate closely the prices of govenmient bonds with 
the condition of the national finances or with historical events of 
favorable or unfavorable import. The effect of such matters on 
prices for a series of years is modified by general economic or finan- 
cial conditions, by the relation between supply and demand for a 
country's securities, and by other considerations. It must be borne 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 75 



CO 

a 
o 

O 



Ph 



CO 
CO 

8 

w 

CO 

(—1 

p< 

M 
O 

CO 

O 









^ ^ 0? 3 

«) * « K 


-S" 


■^s 


«o 


M 


^ 


















1 






g -S 00 =3 


M 


,►■ 


H 


H 


H 


4 






& a a 


1/1 






5 














M 


« 








vo w M d 






^ 










1 




m 




*- 








? i "5 s 


R 


S 


s; 


ft 


1 


J 




1 














w i vi ^ 




H 


M 


H 


H 


tq 


















M xO "^ w 




to 


Co 




^ 






Si 




w> 


^ 


8 


i? 


8 






3 










M 


M 






; 




























^ 






■B 13 'B '2 


00 




CO 






Q 






kikkk 


u 


i^ 


i, 


A, 


Aj 
















H 








■S IS "S 'S 


00 

M 


H 


w 


H 






•S -3 














1 


K 




s s s 
















" » 














to 




a s a 


































is* 




























1 




00 00 






























i5 


s 


3 S 


£" .8 a 
2 s -g 

M H M 












6? 


fes 


ss ss 


6S SS SS 














lO »o 


»o lO »o 


































M M 


















































"^ 


i 


1 J? 

05 00 

M M 


ff s ? 














H 


00 00 GO 
H H IH 
















































^ 




»0 

1 « 

6 e 


3 '^ --^ 

^ ! 1 1 


to 
00 

M 

1 


1 

M 


1 

H 








!? 


1 1 1 i 


1 


1 


1 








** 


•*« 


H« rt« Hco «tga 


•>«« 


wm 




>«* 






























o. 




































^^ 


^^ 




1 












M 


to 






1 




|l 


S *« "m ^ 
n m to «o 

OO 00 00 00 
M H H M 

S o 5 & 


00 
H 

1 


w 

M 

«o 


00 
M 

M 

1 


1 








1? - 




•*J 


vM 


^ 


>^ 










o> o o o. 


a 


a 


M 
M 






^ 


^ 


ts ts 


^ feS 6? feg 


^ 


SS 


BS 


fe 




(O 


«o m 


*o <o w «o 


«o 


«i 


ir 


N 












: 


M 








1 




,a .5? 


00 00 00 00 


SS 


■Si 


8, 






^* 


T T 


7 1* V 7 


r 


r 




M 




■s, 


i S? 


h k k h 


R 


i? 


!5 


i 






H 


B 'B 


•S S 13 "S 


■a 


M 


M 








•S-SlJ. 



SiS-?1? 



'jS AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

in mind that, aside from and before the great war, there have been 
certain factors during the past twelve or fifteen years which have 
led to an almost steady decline in the prices of aU low interest- 
bearing securities. Among these factors may be mentioned the 
increase in the production of gold, the increase in the cost of living 
and in the scale of living, and the output of enormous amounts of 
securities of all kinds coincident with rapid industrial expansion 
and private and public extravagance. The lowest price of British 
consols during the past one himdred years was, however, in June, 
1815, at the time of the battle of Waterloo; the highest was on July 
I, 1896, at a time when England's supremacy in almost every 
respect was unquestioned and when there was a relatively large 
accumulation of capital in Europe seeking investment. The lowest 
price for French rentes since the close of the Napoleonic wars 
occurred ia the troublous days of the Second Republic (1848), and 
the next lowest was after Sedan; the highest price was in 1897, 
when France and the world were at peace and capital was seek- 
ing investment aU over the world. The lowest prices for United 
States bonds since the early days of the Republic were in the spring 
and early summer of 1861 at the beginning of the Civil War; the 
highest prices as a rule were in 1902, when the United States had 
greatly extended its territory as a result of the Spanish War, was 
in a strong economic and financial condition, and when there was 
a large accumulation of capital seeking investment. 

It remains only to discuss, as far as it can be seen, the effect of 
the present great war on national credit. In niunber of men en- 
Estimated gaged, population and resources of nations at war, 
^^ISm of and total expenditure, the present war is in a class by 
presentwar \\s,eii. Ancarly estimate of the Loudou "Economist"^ 
placed the direct total cost of this war for six months for the 
leading coimtries at about $8,232,000,000, divided somewhat as 
follows: — 

Germany about $2,040,000,000 

Austria-Hungary " 1,440,000,000 

Russia " 2,040,000,000 

France " 1,560,000,000 

Great Britain " 1,152,000,000 

» Vol. Lxxx, pp. 50-51. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS ^J 

These figures were at the rate of about $16,464,000,000 as the 
total direct cost of the war for the nations listed for one year. Mr, 
Edgar Crammond, Secretary of the Liverpool Stock Exchange, at a 

PRICES OF GOVERNMENT BONDS* 



Securily 



United States 

6%i88i 

4% 1907 

4%i<)ci7 

4%I92S 

Great Britain 

Consols 3% 

Consols 2}% 

Consols 2!% 

Consols 2i%» 

France 

Rentess% 

RenteS3% 

Rentes 3% 

Rentes3% 

Germany* 
Prussian consols 4% , 
Prussian consols 4% 
Prussian consols 4% '. 
Prussian consols 3i% . 

Italy 

Rentes s% ' 

Rentes 5%' 

Rentes 5%' 

Rentes 3i%-34%»... 

Austria-Hungary 
Austrian rentes 4%. . . 
Austrian rentes 4% . . . 
Austrian rentes 4%- . . 
Austrian rentes 4%. . . 

Russia 

Nicolai 4% 

Nicolai 4% 

Railroad 4% 

Rentes 4% 

Japan 
Sterling 4) % (ist series) 



Period 



1873-1882 
1883-1892 
x8g3-zgo2 
1903-1912 



1873-1882 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 

1873-1882 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 



1873-1882 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 



1873-1882 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 



lS73-l882>» 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 



1873-1882 
1883-1892 
1893-1902 
1903-1912 



High 



a.08% 
I.S8% 
1-93% 



a-95% 
2.53% 
1-95% 
2.66% 



4.24% 
3.03% 
2.86% 
2.98% 



3.88% 
3.76% 
3-79% 
3.48% 



4.70% 
4.36% 
3-94% 
3.84% 



4.85% 
4.14% 
3.81% 
3.93% 



4.64% 
4.06% 
3.76% 
3-99% 



4.83% 



Dale 



June 16, 1876 
March 29,1889 
March 14, 1902 
October 13,1905 



May 24, z88i 
March 29, 18S8 

July 1, 1896 
anuaxy 5, 1903 

May 14, 1881 
SeptemDer i3» 1892 
July 22, 1897 
January 12, 1903 



1881 

December 7, 1888 
June 17, 1893 
April 17, 1903 



June 8, 1881 
December 3, 1886 
December 24, 1902 
June 1, 1905 



May 9, 1881 
September 30, 1892 
September 6, 1897 
June 26, 1903 



September 21, 1S75 
Feoniary 13, 1891 
August 18, 1896 
June 2, 1903 



April, 19x0 



Low 



Date 



4.50% 
s.94% 
3-39% 
2.80% 



3.34% 
2.95% 
3.03% 
3.45% 



4.95% 
4.05% 
3.20% 
3-40% 



4.13% 
4.09% 
3.86% 
4.13% 



7.80% 
5.08% 
6.05% 
3.86% 



6.11% 
5.05% 
4.30% 
4.71% 



6.49% 
5.48% 
4.28% 
S.89% 



October 17, 1873 
June 23, 18S4 
August 7, i8g6 
June 15, 1910 



December, 1874 
November 14, 1890 
July IS, 1901 
October 14, igi2 



May 18, 1877 
December 17, 1883 
January 4, 1893 
October 8, 1912 



October 2, 1900 
December 19, igx2 



1873 

January 23, 1883 
January 18, 1894 
May 3, 1912 

June 17, 1879 
January 5, 1883 
November 13, 1893 
October s, 1912 



April 23, 1877 
January 13, 1883 
January 11, 1893 
August 19, 1907 



6.10% October, 1907 



' Highest and lowest prices for United States bonds taken from the Financial Review (New York, 1914}, 
pp. 83 to 87, and from the Commercial and Financial Chronicle (New York), vol. xvn, p. 621, vol. xxiv, p. 
5, vol. xxxvm, p. 757, vol. XLVin, p. 421, vol. Lxm, p. 217, vol. lxxiv, p. 562, vol. ucxxi, p. 1154, vol. 

LXXXX, p. 1596. 

Highest and lowest prices and yields for foreign government bonds, except Japanese, furnished by 
Messrs. F. C. Mathieson & Sons, London, England. 

Highest and lowest prices for Japanese government bonds from the Financial Renew (New York, 19x2), 
p. 8x. 

' Allowing for loss if redeemed at due date (X923) at par and for reduction of mterest in X903. 

■ 2i% from April, X903. 

* In view of the fact that the credit of Prussia and of the German Empire has been very much the same, 
and that reliable quotations for Prussian securities covering a fairly long period are more easily obtainable 
than for German imperial bonds, we have used the Prussian consols table. 

» Prices from x88o to 1882 only. • From 1898^}%. 



' S% less 13.20% of income tax, 
' 3i% from January, 19x2. 



S%I 



1° 1879 to 1882 only. 



t income tax. 



78 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

meeting of the Royal Statistical Society, March i6, 1915, esti- 
mated the direct costs for one fuU year of war as follows:^ 

Great Britain about $3,398,400,000 

France " 2,656,320,000 

Germany " 4,502,400,000 

Austria-Hungary " 2,697,600,000 

Russia " 2,880,000,000 

These figures show a total direct cost for one year of war to 
the leading nations involved of $16,134,720,000. The London 
"Statist" ^ has given the probable cost of the first twelve months 
of war for Great Britain as about $3,192,000,000. The cost of the 
first twelve months of war for France probably will be in the neigh- 
borhood of $3,500,000,000.^ Perhaps it is not far wrong to say that 
the cost of the war for the first twelve months to the leading na- 
tions involved will be in the neighborhood of from $16,000,000,000 
to $17,000,000,000. The figures probably need not be modified 
much from the above to take care of the short participation of 
Italy during the period covered. The costs have been steadily 
rising, however, until the latest estimates for Great Britain — by 
Premier Asquith, September 15, 1915 — figure out a net war ex- 
penditure, exclusive of loans to allies and certain other items, of 
about $16,800,000 a day, or at the rate of $6,132,000,000 a year, 
and a gross war expenditure, including loans to her aUies, of about 
$20,160,000 a day, or say $7,358,400,000 a year; * the monthly war 
costs of France, according to the French Budget Commission, have 
been running at the rate of about $397,440,000 a month, or say 
$4,769,280,000 a year, and the vote of credit, asked by M. Ribot 
September 16 for the last quarter of 1915, was substantially on this 
basis; ^ the average monthly cost to Russia is given by M. Ribot, 
speaking on the same date, as about $345,600,000, or at the 
rate of $4,147,200,000 a year;' the monthly war expenditures 

^ Journal of the Royal Statistical Society (London), vol. Lxxvni (May, 1915), 
pp. 361-413. 

' Vol. Lxxxiv, p. 664. For later figures, see vol. rxxxv, p. 99 (about $3,600,000,000). 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle (New York), June 26, 1915, p. 2117. See also 
statement of M. Ribot as siunmarized in the Statist (London), June s, iQiS, vol. 

LXXXIV, p. S7I. 

* Statist (London), September 18, 1915, vol. Lxxxv, p. 447. 

s Commercial and Financial Chronicle (New York), September 2$, 1915, vol. loz, 
p. 969 and Ibid., September 18, 1915, p. 877. 

• Commercial and Financial Chronicle (New York), vol. loi, p. 877. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 79 

of Germany, according to Herr Helfferich, Secretary of the Im- 
perial Treasury, in his speech introducing the third war loan 
August 20, 1915, amoimt to about $472,coo,cxx), or at the rate of 
say $5,664,000,000 a year.^ The same authority estimates the 
costs to all the nations involved at nearly $70,800,000 daily, over 
$1,888,000,000 monthly, and about $23,600,000,000 yearly.^ Allow- 
ing for the participation of Bulgaria — which occurred after Herr 
Helfferich 's estimate — and possibly other nations, the cost of the 
second year of war to aU the nations involved is likely to be in the 
neighborhood of $25,000,000,000. 

These figures compare with the estimated cost of previous wars 
somewhat as shown in the table on page 80.* 

To this we may add about $16,500,000,000 as the cost of the first 
year of the present war and perhaps $25,000,000,000 as the cost of 
a second year. 

In addition to the direct cost of maintaining armies and carrying 
on war, there is the economic loss through cessation of production. 
This has been estimated by M. Guyot and the London "Econo- 
mist " for the first six months of the war as about $10,272,000,000,* 
or at the rate of $20,544,000,000 a year. Adding this to the direct 
cost, we get a figure for the first year of the war of about $37,000,- 
000,000. If we allow for the value of lost lives, on the 

,.,___ ,- ,, Jk,, . Total losses of 

basis of M. Guyot s figures (about $4,646,400,000 for the war to 
six months), we find total losses for a year of over 
$46,000,000,000. This is "without allowing for the devastation and 
widespread destruction of fixed capital." * The total losses to July 
31, 1915, as estimated by Mr. Crammond, are as follows: — 

Great Britain $6,038,400,000 

Germany 13,320,000,000 

Belgium, including destruction of property. . . 2,527,200,000 
France, including destruction of property. . . 8,094,720,000 
Austria-Hungary, iacluding destruction of 

property 7,622,400,000 

Russia, including destruction of property . . . 7,219,200,000 

A total for the six nations of about $44,821,920,000* 

» Economist (London), September 4, 1915, vol. lxxxi, p. 358. ' Ibid., p. 360. 
' World Almanac (1915), p. 488. See also Mulliall (1899), p. 586, and Whitaker's 
Almanack (1915), p. 800. All such figures should be thought of as approximations only. 

* Economist (London), vol. lxxx, p. 51- ' Ibid., p. 51. 

• Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, May, 1915, pp. 361-413. For another est!- 



8o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The "Economist" estimated the direct costs to all the nations 
involved as about 43% and the total costs as about 96% of the 
national income or earnings. Strictly speaking, total loss occa- 
sioned by a war like the present one is incalculable. Such things 
cannot properly be measured in figures. It should be borne in 
mind that a very large part of the cost of war is represented by 
expenditures of the entire nation through the Government; and 

GROSS COST OF PAST WARS FROM 1 793-1913 — PUBLIC 

FIGURES ' 



Dates 


Countries engaged 


Cost 


1793-1815.... 

1812-181S 

1828 


England and France 

France and Russia 

Russia and Turkey 

Spain and Portugal (dvil) 

France and Algeria 

Revolts in Europe 

England 

France 

Sardinia and Turkey 

Austria 

Russia 

France 

Austria 

Italy 

United States (dvil war) 

Denmark, Prussia and Austria 

Prussia and Austria 

Brazil, Argentina and Paiagtiay 

France and Mexico 

France 

Germany 

Russia 

Turkey 

Spain and United States 

England and Transvaal 

Russia and Japan 

Italy and Turkey 

Balkan Wars 


$6,250,000,000 
450,625,000 
100,000,000 
250,000,000 
190,000,000 


1830-1840 

1830-1847 

1848 


1854-1856 

tRco 


371,000,000 
332,000,000 
128,000,000 

68,600,000 
800,000,000 

75,000,000 
127,000,000 

51,000,000 
5,000,000,000 

36,000,000 


1861-1865.... 
1864 


1866 


.^^0,000,000 


1864-1870 

1865-1866.... 

1870-1871 

1876-1877.... 
1898 


240,000,000 

65,000,000 

1,580,000,000 

954,000,000 

806,547,489 

403,273,74s 
1,165,000,000 


1900-1901 

1904-1905.... 
1911 


1,000,100,000 

2,500,000,000 

700,000,000 


1912-1913 — 


1,192,130,000 



Expense of wars, 1790-1860 $9,243,225,000 

Expense of wars, 1861-1913 15,972,051,234 

Total ^ $25,215,276,234 



mate of the direct costs and total losses, see Charles F. Speare, "What the War is 
Costing Europe," American Revienu of Reviews, April, 1915, p. 452. 

* In the case of the Balkan Wars, estimates are from bankers' statements. (See 
World Almanac, p. 488.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 8l 

that a great portion of this would be incurred in times of peace by 
the nation as individuals.^ In other words, a large part of the cost 
of war, instead of being a true addition to expenditure, is merely a 
transference of expenditure from individuals to the Government. 
On the other hand, the activities of individuals in war are destruc- 
tive, whereas in peace they are or should be constructive. Again, 
during and after a great war the people are induced to practice 
economies which in ordinary times they would be likely to neglect. 
Taking a still larger view, there is often a physical and moral regen- 
eration brought about by the occurrence of a terrible war. So it 
will not do to assume that war is all waste — that the " cost" is all 
loss. The population of Germany in the Thirty Years' War was 
reduced from about 16,000,000 to about 4,000,000.^ Before the 
present war it was probably 70,000,000. The greatest prosperity 
of England developed after the Napoleonic wars. So also it was 
with our own American Civil War. There is a regeneration that 
nature provides. Wounds heal — as a rule they can hardly be 
prevented from healing. The grass that is burned in the early 
spring is replaced with new grass greener and more lovely. So 
economists have figured out how the great losses of the present 
war ultimately may be replaced. They will constitute a serious 
burden and a serious problem, however, for many years to 
come. 

The direct costs of the war have been financed largely through 
borrowings. Undoubtedly a large amount of paper 
money has been issued — the convertibility of some of 
which remains to be proved. The war debts,' according to the 

1 For an interesting article on these phases of the cost of the war, see Roland 
G. Usher, " The Cost of the War," in the Atlantic Monthly, June, 1915, p. 847. 
' Price Collier, Germany and the Germans, p. 30. 

' The Boston Evening News Bureau, September 20, 1915, has given the war debts, 
exclusive of bank loans, as follows:* 

ALLIED LOANS 
Great Britain — 

3i per cents at 95 on 3-97% basis $1,750,000,000 

4i per cents on 4-SS% basis (new loan) 2,925,000,000 

Treasury bills, ij% io 3j% 70o,ooo,ooot 

Five-year Exchequer 3 per cents 239,000,000 

Canadian ten-year 4^ per cents in London 25,000,000 

Canadian one- and two-year s i)er cents in New York 45,000,000 

Indian Government 4% domestic loan 15,000,000 

Anglo-French loan in the United States 250,000,000 

Total $5,949,000,000 

* This list of loans has been corrected from other sources to October 23, 19x5. 
t Estimated. 



82 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

London "Statist" of October 23, 1915 (vol. lxxxvi, pp. 182-86), 
up to about that time, were as follows: — 

WAR DEBT* 

Great Britain — 

November, 1914, s\% war loan $1,680,000,000 

March, 1915, 3% exchequer bonds, net 161,280,000 

July, 191S, 4^% war loan 2,808,000,000 

October, 1915, S% American loan 250,000,000 

Treasury bills 1,027,200,000 

Total war debt $5,926,480,000 

Prance — 

NsLtional defense bonds $i,230,ooo,c»o 

Treasury bonds 450,000,000 

One-year 5 % notes in London 50,000,000 

One-year 5% notes in New York 30,ooo,ooot 

Collateral loan in New York 43,000,000 

Credit in New York (1914) 10,000,000 

Credit in New York (igis) so,ooo,ooo 

Anglo-French loan in the United States 250,000,000 

Total $2,083,000/300 

Russia — 

S per cents at g4 on 5.35% basis $257,500,000 

Second internal loan 257,500,000 

Third internal loan five-year si per cents 515,000,000 

Four percent bonds - 309,000,000 

Treasury bilk 979.500,000 

Issues in England and France 277,000,000 

Total $2,595,500,000 

/W51 — 

Twenty-five-year 4} per cents $200,000,000 

Twenty-five-year 4! per cents at 05 190,000,000 

(tee-yeai notes (United States) 6% 25,000,000 

Total $415,000,000 

Grand total Allied loans $11,042,500,000 

GERMAN AND AUSTRIAN U)ANS 

Germany — 

First war loan, s per cents at 97) on 5.32% basis $1,115,000,000 

Second loan, s per cents at 98^ 2,265.000,000 

Third loan at 99 ^ 3,000,000,000 

Nine months' notes in United States ro,ooo,ooo 

Total $6,390,000,000 

Auslria-Bungary — 

Austrian si per cents at 97i on 6.10% baas $433,000,000 

Hungarian 6 per cents at g7i on 6.70% basis 237,000,000 

Second war loan to June 25 900,000,000 

Loan from German bankers 76,000,000 

Second loan in Germany 125,000,000 

Credit in Germany 60.000,000 

Total $1,831,000,000 

Tttrkey — 
Loan in Germany $250,000,000 

Total of German loans $8,471,000,000 

Grand total of all belligerent loans $19,513,500,000 

* Reduced at the rate of $4.80 to the pound sterling, 
t Estimated. 

(For third German loan, see Commercial and Financial Chronicle [New York], vol. loi, p. 1055, 
and for Italian 6% loan, see ibid.f p. 1327.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 83 

Trance — 

Advances from the Bank of France $1,344,000,000 

French treasury bonds discounted by Bank of France in order to 

make advances to foreign Governments 101,760,000 

3i% loan of July, 1914 96,000,000 

Bon de la Defense Nationale 1,511,232,000 

Obligation de la Defense Nationale 430,272,000 

Loan from England 240,000,000 

Loan from America 250,000,000 

Total sum borrowed by France for the war $3,973,264,000 

Russia — 

5% short-term treasury bonds placed with State Bank $1,294,363,000 

S% long-term loans 1,013,200,000 

Short-term bonds placed in England 253,300,000 

Short-term bonds placed in France 316,625,000 

Treasury bills, etc 668,712,000 

Total $3,546,200,000 

Italy — 

December, 1914, 4^% loan $192,000,000 

July, 1915, 5% loan 192,000,000 

Loan from Bank of Italy 233>S93,2oo 

Total war debt $617,539,200 

Germany — 

September, 1914, 5% war stock $824,112,000 

September, 1914, 5% treasury bonds 236,000,000 

February, 1915, 5% war stock 2,148,308,000 

September, 1915, 5% war loan 2,855,836,000 

Treasury bills (approximate) 1,015,744,000 

Total war credit obtained $7,080,000,000 

Austria^Bungary — 

November, 1914, 1st Austrian sWo war loan $459,998,400 

Valuta loan from Germany 72,000,000 

November, 1914, Hungarian 6% war loan 234,000,000 

May, 1915, 2d Austrian war loan 555,998,400 

June, 1915, 2d Hungarian war loan 224,798,400 

June, 1915, 2d loan from German bankers 73,200,000 

Total publicly issued debt $1,619,995,200 

Estimated floating debt 1,022400,000 

Estimated total to September 30 $2,642,395,200 

These figures show total war loans for the Allies of $14,063,- 
483,200 and for Germany and Austria-Hungary of $9,722,395,200, 
or a total of $23,785,878,400, The figures include advances by the 



84 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

great central banks to the Governments for war purposes. France 
and Russia particularly have financed their war costs to a great 
extent through the central banks. As in the war of 1870, France 
has leaned heavily on the Bank of France.* 

It is hardly worth while to attempt to make any definite state- 
ments as to the total present debts of the leading nations engaged in 
this war. When the war is ended, it will be possible to figure with 
some accuracy the net additions to the various national debts, to 
figure the debts per capita, and to estimate the proportion between 
total debts and wealth and between debt charges and national 
income. Sufl&ce it to say, that already, in October, 1915, the na- 
tional debts of the principal belligerents as a whole probably have 
doubled.* The debts of some of the nations at war have more than 
doubled. Chancellor of the Exchequer McKenna in introducing 
the budget estimated the dead-weight debt of the United Kingdom 
March 31, 1916, as likely to be £2,200,000,000 ($10,560,000,000).' 
This would be an increase of over two hundred per cent above the 
debt in 191 2. The debt of Germany akeady has received an addi- 
tion of 30,000,000,000 marks* (October, 1915), or say $7,080,000,- 
000 — a war increase alone over our figures for 1912 of about one 
hundred and forty-five per cent. All these great increases in debt, 
of course, are for what have been called unproductive purposes 
— that is, for war. The war loans constitute a staggering addition 
to the dead-weight debts of the nations concerned.^ 

How heavy will be the burdens of these huge debts after the war 
will depend in large measure on the terms of peace and on the 
Possible basis course the indebted nations pursue after the war. 
of peace ^g .^^jy jjq^ jjgjg discuss the various suggested terms 

' For figures of bank-note expansion, gold-holdings, and assets and liabilities of the 
banks, see the Statist, October 23, 1915, vol. Lxxxvi, pp. 182-86. In France, Germany, 
and Russia the convertibility of the paper currency has been suspended. {Economist 
[London], July 10, 1915, vol. Lxxxi, p. 47.) 

' The loans of the nations at war from the beginning of the Balkan wars, October 8, 
1912, up to the outbreak of the European war, July 30, 1914, were, according to the 
Boston News Bureau, $830,000,000. Of this Germany and Austria borrowed $489,- 
000,000 and France, Servia, and Belgiimi $341,000,000. {Boston News Bureau, 
October 9, 1914.) 

' Economist (London), vol. Lxxxt, p. 463. • Ihid., p. 358. 

' The net debt of the United States August 31, 1915, was $1,119,376,669 — or 
$92,690,643 more than in 1912. {Commercial and Financial Chronicle [New York], 
vol. loi, p. 989.) 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 85 

of peace — such as the restoration of Alsace-Lorraine, the creation 
of an autonomous Poland and other matters of this kind. What- 
ever indemnities are paid will add just so much to the burden of the 
nation or nations paying them and take away just so much from 
the burdens of the nations receiving them. So also will any losses 
or acquisitions of territory increase or lessen the burdens of the 
debts. From a financial point of view, what is essential, however, is 
that the peace shall be, as far as possible, lasting, — that it shall 
make impossible a recurrence in the near future of any such catas- 
trophe as we are witnessing. Otherwise discussion of national 
solvency is a waste of time. In order to make a lasting peace, it 
would seem that boundaries should be rectified on the basis of 
nationalities or, perhaps we may say, of races. In this connection 
there are many questions to be settled involving the present do- 
minions of Austria-Hungary. Let us hope that there will be no 
effort to crush any nation or people — even though that nation 
temporarily may have offended against all the laws of civilization. 
Yet no peace will be a peace unless so-called militarism is done 
away with. Expenses for military preparation must be reduced 
largely and the energies of mankind devoted to productive pur- 
poses. All sorts of programmes have been suggested — including 
that of a United States of Europe with an international military 
and naval force to maintain order and enforce peace. ^ Undoubt- 
edly, with the backing of the laboring classes and the Sociahsts 
in many countries, a tremendous effort will be made to bring about 
the settlement of as many disputes as possible through arbitration. 
There will be also — it is evident already — a tremendous move- 
ment toward democracy and liberal institutions.^ Some such solu- 
tion would seem to be essential to continued national solvency and 
national good faith. 

If Baxter in 1874 was alarmed at the rate at which nations were 
borrowing and feared then for the solvency of some of them,' what 

* Dr. Nicholas Murray Butler in the Boston Sunday Herald, October 18, 1914, and 
meeting of the League of Peace in Independence Hall, Friday, June 17, 1915. {Boston 
Evening Transcript, ]\xa.eiy, igis-) See also Society to Eliminate Economic Causes 
of War. (Commercial and Financial Chronicle [New York], vol. 100, p. 2134.) 

2 The immunity of private property at sea in time of war, or even the neutralization 
of all conmierce, are subjects of great interest and importance. (See the Evening Post, 
New York, August 10, ipiS-) 

• Journal oj the Royal Statistical Society, vol. xxxvn, pp. 11-13. 



86 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

shall we say in 1915 with debts piling up at unheard-of rates and 

(juced e ^^^ ^^^ ^^'^ ^°^ ^^^ ^^ Sight? ^ It is hard to escape 

penditures the couclusion that after the war most of the nations 
for national engaged will be forced either (i) to reduce their ex- 
so venqy penses f or armaments materially in order to pay inter- 

est on their debts or (2) to compromise or repudiate at least a portion 
of their obligations. The debt histories which we have given show 
that such things are not unheard of. There has been during the past 
one hundred years, of course, an enormous increase in the wealth 
of the leading nations at war. For instance, the burden of the Brit- 
ish debt, on the basis of debt to wealth, even with the great addi- 
tions to date for war, is less than one third as great as in 1816. 
Great Britain could fight between three and four years more with- 
out making her debt bear a larger proportion to her resources than 
it did after the Napoleonic wars.^ At the same time there is a limit. 
There is less reason to think that her resources will increase at the 
rate they did in the earlier period. We can apply the same sort of 
tests to the other nations at war. Then there is another considera- 
tion. Whenever there is a crushing burden of debt or of taxation, — 
especially if those burdens have failed to produce any correspond- 
ing benefit, — the temptation to compromise is very strong. It is 
then that the stuff of which nations are made is revealed. Con- 
tinued expenditures for military purposes at the rate which has 
prevailed during the past thirty years,' however, added to the 
charges on the debts created through this war, are likely to lead to 
bankruptcy. It is a grave question, of course, whether in the cases 
of some nations bankruptcy can be avoided under any drcum- 
stances. 

We will not undertake to estimate the relative credit and stand- 
ing of the various nations after the war. Such a task is impossible 
until one sees more clearly what the outcome of the war is to be. 

' Some decisive military action, inability to borrow, inability to pay interest on 
existing debts, or general economic exhaustion may bring the war to an end. 

* For an interesting article on this phase of the subject, see " Will the War Bankrupt 
Europe?" in the North American Review, August, 1915, p. 174. 

' Between 1881 and 1911, the combined annual expenditure for army and navy 
of the five great European nations — Great Britain, France, Germany, Austria- 
Hungary, and Russia — much more than doubled, showing a far higher rate of in- 
crease than the respective national incomes. {Economist [London], vol. lxxdc, pp. 
SS6 and 914.) 



. UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 87 

It would seem, however, that the United States, Russia, and Japan 
would emerge from the war relatively less weakened 
than any other nations. The United States and Rus- nations after 
sia, on account of the continental nature of their *^" 
territory, the size and character of their population, and the im- 
mensity of their resources, developed and undeveloped, are in an 
enviable position. Japan has not been placed under the burdens 
that some of the other nations have been; and it may succeed in 
developing its material interests in Korea and China on a scale 
which will greatly enhance its credit. It is a law of nature never 
violated that the leadership of nations goes to the strongest — that 
is, the strongest in a broad sense. Is it too much to expect that the 
United States after the war will be in a position to assume the 
leadership which has been held for a hundred years by Great 
Britain? 

Until the effect of the present war on the debts and financial 
condition of the nations engaged becomes clearer, American inves- 
tors should exercise great care in the purchase of Proper attitude 
foreign government bonds. Mr. Mortimer L. Schiff, °^ American in- 

Ti 1 -KT tr 1 1 1 • 1 • vestors toward 

a well-known New York banker, is quoted as sa3ang foreign govem- 
in substance: that an investor should be assured that 
a borrowing country is administered economically; that in its 
annual budget, income and expenditures balance, and that the 
proceeds of any loan applied for are to be used for productive pur- 
poses; that from the point of view of the investor dreadnoughts 
and rifles are not good security; that a country should provide 
out of its own budget, through taxation of its own people or from 
internal loans, for everything that may be called its non-produc- 
tive expenditures, and that it should restrict its foreign borrow- 
ing to such productive purposes as railroads, irrigation schemes, 
and such others as may be self-supporting; that in financing 
productive enterprises in foreign countries, the most acceptable 
form of security would be a bond having a direct lien or mortgage 
on the enterprise itself and guaranteed by endorsement by the 
Government, rather than a simple government obligation; that a 
definite pledge for the service of the loan of all or a portion of some 
definite form of governmental revenue would be of advantage; that 
foreign loans placed in this country should bear, if possible, a defi- 



88 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

nite relation to trade with this country; that, as a general rule, 
short-term securities should be avoided, but a redemption provision 
should be embodied in every long-time bond; that a sinking fund, 
if possible, should be provided; and that in general the obligation 
should be of such a character as to be not too great a burden on the 
borrower — lest defaults become necessary.^ These suggestions 
have much of value. Until the Governments involved in this war 
have shown their ability to maintain solvency, Americans should 
exercise the greatest care in the purchase of their securities. 

Illustrating not only certain principles stated by Mr. Schiff, but 
in a broad way everything discussed in this chapter, is the $500,000- 
Angio-French ooo Auglo-French loan brought out in September and 
doUar loan Qctober, 1915. This loan was in the form of a joint 

and several obligation of the United Kingdom of Great Britain and 
Ireland and the French Republic. It bore 5% interest and matured 
in five years, but was convertible at any time up to maturity into 
joint 4|% bonds due in 1940, but redeemable at the option of the 
borrowing nations after 1930. The loan was made payable in 
American gold dollars, and was brought out at a price and under 
conditions calculated to insure its wide distribution among the 
American investing public. 

In several respects, this loan was unique. It was the largest bond 
issue of any kind ever brought out at one time in the United States. 
It was the first large loan made by the people of the United States 
to foreign nations. It was, moreover, the first external issue ever 
put out by Great Britain. And it was, so far as we know, the first 
joint and several obligation of two great powers. 

Yet fundamentally this loan was an ordinary transaction and 
grew out of conditions which we have discussed at length in this 
chapter. In its origin the loan was part of a commercial transac- 
tion. Great Britain and France under war conditions had been 
and were importing from this country such a large excess of mer- 
chandise 2 that they were unable to pay for it conveniently with 
American securities or with gold. In spite of holdings, by the Eng- 
Hsh and French people, of American securities many times the 

* Annalist (New York), May 31, 191S, p. SS^i smd Commercial and Financial 
Chronicle (New York), May 29, 1915, p. 1801. 

^ Their income from expenditures by Americans abroad also had been reduced 
greatly. 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 89 

axQOunt of the loan sought, these securities were not available 
immediately to pay for goods. Moderate amounts of such securities 
had been shipped to this side, to be sure, almost every week. But 
English and French investors ever since the begimiing of the war 
had shown a reluctance to part with their American securities. 
Earlier in this chapter we called attention to the fact that during 
a whole year of war all Europe had sold back to us only between 
$300,000,000 and $500,000,000 of our securities. This explains in- 
cidentally why the deposit of American securities as collateral for 
such a large loan was out of the question.^ As for shipments of gold 
by Great Britain and France to pay for their huge debit balance to 
this country, this method — even if we allow that it were possible 
— would have been a climisy, an unnecessary, and an undesirable 
way. Considerable amounts of gold, as well as American securities, 
had been and were being shipped to this country. But the English 
and the French needed the gold badly to support their banking 
structures in time of war and to make purchases which they could 
not pay for otherwise. It happened that we did not need the gold 
at all. We had already what might be called "an uncomfortable 
excess." So the English and the French arranged to buy of us and 
we to sell to them the goods they needed on credit. The loan was 
caUed and was a "credit" loan — "credit" meaning here a "com- 
mercial credit." It established a convenient method for Great 
Britain and France to pay for wheat, cotton, manufactures, and 
other goods ^ imported from the United States; and from an Ameri- 
can point of view, it made possible the marketing with two of our 
best regular customers of an unusually large amoimt of the prod- 
ucts of our farms and factories. In other words, it did for us what 
the loans of Great Britain to other countries for the past hundred 
years had done — it financed our trade. 

From the investor's point of view, the loan was safe and at- 
tractive. The yield — S^ % to s| % — was high and the security 

> The English and French might have been taxed or otherwise forced out of holding 
their American securities, but measures like this would have been harsh and unde- 
^able. 

" Probably only a small part, if any, of the loan was used to purchase so-called 
"munitions." Such use of the specific proceeds of the loan was uimecessary. Only a 
relatively small part of our exports to the Allies were " munitions of war. ' ' In the minds 
of American investors, complete separation of "munitions" from the loan would have 
had a beneficial effect. 



90 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

ample; for — to speak only of one part of the wealth of Great 
Britain and France — the four to five billion of American securi- 
ties held by the two nations were an asset for the pa3maent of their 
debt, whether they sold them back to us or not. Then, again, the 
loan was especially safe because it was part of the external or for- 
eign debt of the two countries and bore a small proportion to their 
domestic debt. For while there is no such thing as a " first mortgage 
on the British Empire," or even a first lien in any legal sense, yet it 
is a fact that all nations — even nations with records for repeated 
scaling of their domestic debts, such as Austria and Russia — have 
been careful about the payment of their foreign debts. Morally and 
practically they have regarded such debts as having precedence 
over their domestic obligations. 

In a broad way, this Anglo-French loan marks, we hope and 
believe, the entrance of the United States into the family of the 
"lending nations." Sooner or later this country would have 
reached that position anyway. But the great war has dried up in 
Europe the wells of capital available for the development of other 
parts of the world. For some time to come, Europe wiU need all her 
own capital at home — and probably considerable from this covm- 
try beside. She will not be in a position to lend freely to the Argen- 
tine, to Brazil, to Mexico, and the other food and raw material 
producing countries. Probably she will withdraw gradually a large 
part of the huge investment she has in the United States. This is 
our opportunity. Not only can we reduce gradually our large capi- 
tal indebtedness to Europe, but we can — if we put our house in 
order — take Europe's place in lending capital for the development 
of the rest of the world, taking in exchange other people's securities 
and extending with those people the markets for our own mer- 
chandise. The change will not take place all at once. This war, to 
be sure, has given us a chance for a colossal stride. Already we have 
repurchased (October, 1915) our own securities held abroad or have 
loaned to foreign nations to the extent of between say $1,100,000,- 
000 and $1,300,000,000. By so much have we reduced our debt to 
Europe and by just so much has Europe lost her creditor position. 
In proportion to the reduction of the debt, in a broad way, will be 
the reduction in interest payments abroad. But it will take some 
time (unless the war is unduly prolonged) — perhaps twenty-five 



UNITED STATES AND FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 9I 

years — to change from being a "debtor" to a "creditor" nation. 
Not until then will New York in any permanent sense become the 
financial center of the world: for to become the great international 
banker we must establish broad trade relations with aU the rest of 
the world, and we must be in a position to finance our foreign trade 
by lending freely. We must not be provincial or narrow. To lend 
freely we must save. We must, moreover, establish an adequate 
merchant marine and satisfactory banking facilities in foreign 
coimtries. All these things we must do to seize to the full the 
present opportunity and to place the credit of the United States. 
indisputably and for a long time to come at the head of the. 
Iist.i 

It remains only to give an idea of the prices of some of the leading 
government bonds under the stress of war on a colossal and unpre- 
cedented scale. In February and March, lois, after „, 

, . , Warpnces 

the war had been m progress about six months, some of government: 
of the leading securities of the allied nations were 
quoted approximately as follows: ^ 

British consols, 2^% (Flat) ^ 68185 (February 5)^ 

French rentes, 3% 681 (March 12) 

Italian rentes, 3^% 79i (February 5), 

Russian, second series 4% 75 (February 5) 

Russian, 1906, 5% 9Si (February 5) 

Japanese, sterling, 1910, 4% 71^ (February 5)' 

Japanese, sterling, 1905, second series, 

4i% 8sfi (February 5) 

The London "Economist" * has given highest andlowest prices,, 
highest price in July, 1914, and prices on February i6> 1915, of 
some leading "enemy" securities — including German imperial 
3% bonds, Prussian 3!% consols, Austrian 45% treasury notes, 

1 For information in regard to this loan, see Commercial and Financial Chronicle 
(New York), vol. loi, p. 1053; Statist (London), vol. 86, p. 14; and Economist (Lon- 
don), vol. 81, p. 499. 

* Statist (London), vol. Lxxxm, pp. 19s and 406. For later prices of government 
bonds of all the nations at war, see Economist (London), July 3, 1915, vol. lxxxi, p. 8. 
The latest prices for British consols, one issue of Japanese bonds, and one issue of 
Russian bonds, given in this number of the Economist, are "minimum" or "pegged" 
prices. 

' Prices include accrued interest. 

' Economist (London), February 20, 1915, p. 313. 



gz AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

and Hungarian 4% and 4!% rentes. These prices are hardly worth 
quoting. The low prices given represent prices which Englishmen 
or, at any rate, traders on the London Stock Exchange would pay 
for the government bonds of their enemies, and cannot be taken 
as representing the credit of the nations concerned. Furthermore, 
interest on " enemy" securities is not being paid to British holders.^ 
The prices given in our list of loans put out during the war give a 
fairer idea of the credit of the various nations. The huge domestic 
loan of Great Britain — about $3,000,000,000 — has been put out 
in the form of 4I per cents at par, which price includes several 
months' accrued interest; and the loan raised in the United States 
has been sold to investors at 965 to 98 and interest. The French 
national defense bonds have been put out at par ^ for short-term 
5% bonds; Russia has put out 5 per cents at 94 and 5-year 5 J per 
cents; Italy has borrowed with 25-year 4J per cents and one year 
convertible 6 per cents; Germany has put out 5 per cents at from 
972 to 99 > Austria has put out 5I per cents at 97I; and Hungary 
6 per cents at 97J. The credit of Great Britain remauis highest 
of all the nations at war, with France next,' and Germany third. 
A decisive outcome of the war one way or the other would have the 
effect, of course, of enhancing the market value of the securities of 
the victorious nations and of depressing the market value of the 
securities of the defeated nations. How radical has been the change 
in the credit of all the nations concerned, however, may be seen 
by comparing the prices of 1915 with those in our table for 1913.* 

^ Economist (London), July 3, 1915, vol. ixxxi, p. 8. 

' Advices received from the Boston News Bureau. 

' The issue price — 88 — of the 5% perpetual rentes brought out in November, 
1915, would seem to show the ciedit of Germany to be higher than that of France. 
(See the Statist, vol. lxxxvi, p. 592.) 

♦ The following prices of leading government bonds before and during the Franco- 
Prussian War may be of interest {Economist [London], September s, 1914, p. 416): — 



British, 3% consols 
French, 3% rentes. 
United SUtes, 6%. 

Russian, 4% 

Italian, 5% 



Oosing 
frict 


Fluctuations in 1870 


Closing 
price 






1S69 


Eishat 


Ltmesl 


1870 


91 


94 

75 


88i 


91} 




51 




86 


91 


78 


89 


11 


^ 


60 

43 


S6 



UNITED STATES AKD FOREIGN GOVERNMENT BONDS 93 

On February 11, 1915, the United States Panama 3 per cents were 
quoted at ioi§ and interest, bid, or only f of 1% less than the 
price in January, 1913.^ 

We have traced the rise and development of the so-called great 
powers, whose government bonds are the leading national securi- 
ties; we have considered the relation which the debts Summary of 
of these nations bore to their resources before the [^"n^ "hf' 
present great war; we have taken up briefly the debt prfces'oTgov- 
history or record of good or bad faith of the nations emment bonds 
issuing these obligations; we have discussed in a general way the 
financial, economic, and political status of these nations as bearing 
on their credit; and we have tried to indicate as far as possible at 
this time the effect of the great war on their condition. All discus- 
sions of government bonds involve in a certain way every factor 
relating to national existence. Fluctuations in prices of govern- 
ment bonds represent in a broad way fluctuations in the resources, 
debt, income, expenditure, progress, power, and prestige of the 
nations issuing the bonds, as well as fluctuations in the general 
economic and financial conditions prevailing throughout the 
world. We must remember that government bonds, as we said at 
the beginning of this chapter, usually are simply promises to pay 
and promises not enforceable by any legal process. We must try 
to make up our minds, from all the data available, how good in 
each case the promise is. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle (New York), February 13, 1915, p. S4o- 



CHAPTER III 

STATE BONDS 

State bonds, like government bonds, usually are simply promises 
to pay. At times some of our States have issued bonds to railroads, 
State bonds canals, or other private corporations and have taken 
simp?y pro- ^.s securfty mortgage bonds or stocks of the companies. 
mises to pay There have been cases also of railroad or other cor- 
poration bonds guaranteed by States. As a rule, however, sound 
financing requires that state bonds shall be issued only for strictly 
pubHc purposes, and that the interest shall be payable out of taxes 
levied on all the taxable property within the State. 

In view of the fact that no bondholder — unless the bondholder 
happens to be another State — can sue a State without its consent,^ 
No legal remedy the character or quality of the promise to pay is of 
ddadted'stete great importance. The case may be stated even more 
bonds strongly by saying that in the last resort there is no 

legal remedy whatever for collecting defaulted state bonds. Even 
if a verdict is secured in the courts, the Legislature may refuse to 
make any appropriation to pay interest ^ or principal. This is for 
the reason that in the matter of paying debts a State, like a na- 
tion, is a sovereign power. 

With allowance for the difference in the character of the unit, 

Other factors the f actors determining the safety of state bonds are 

the^sSety^^ much the Same as in the case of government bonds. 

of state bonds They may be grouped about these headings: — 

(i) The debt statement of a State or the proportion of net debt to 

property and to population. 

(2) The debt history of a State or its record of good or bad faith. 

(3) The present constitutional provisions governing the creation 
and payment of debt. 

' Constitution of the United States, Eleventh Amendment. 

* See io8 U.S. 76, New Hampshire vs. State of Louisiana and New York vs. State 
of Louisiana, and 192 U.S. 286 (1904), South Dakota vs. North Carolina. The latter 
case resulted finally in the settlement of a small amount of defaulted bonds by 
North Carolina. (See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 80, p. 1382.} 



STATE BONDS 95 

(4) The amount and character of the population. 

(s) General considerations bearing on the present and future 
prosperity of the State, such as size and location of territory, 
natural resources, and water and rail facilities. 

We will take up first the debt statements of the various States. 
We give on pages 96 and 97 a table for aU the States 
of the Union, showing: (i) bonds, special debt to mentsofthe 
trust funds, and floating debt; (2) cash, securities, 
and sinking-fund assets offsetting same; (3) debts less sinking- 
fund assets; and (4) same per capita} 

As may be seen from the accompanjdng table (Table I), the 
States of Vermont, New Jersey, Delaware, Florida, Iowa, North 
Dakota, South Dakota, Nebraska, Kansas, Wyoming, Nevada, and 
Oregon have debts less sinking-fund assets of less than $1,000,000 
each. The State of Pennsylvania has no net debt at all, and the 
State of West Virginia has no debt which it has recognized.^ The 
States having debts less sinking-fund assets in excess of $5,000,000 
are Massachusetts, Rhode Island, Connecticut, New York, Mary- 
land, Ohio, Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, Ala- 
bama, Tennessee, Louisiana, Michigan, Oklahoma, and California. 

As far as per-capita net debts go, the States having the smallest 
— in addition to Pennsylvania and West Virginia which have none 
at all — are: Oregon, $.04; Kansas, $.14; Iowa, $.16; „ „ 

.IK -Kx 1 1 fl. -riT • iiK 1 Smallest and 

New Jersey, f.24; Nebraska, $.31; Imnois, $.39; and largest debts 
Indiana, $.49. The States having the largest net debts '^"' 
per capita are: Massachusetts, $22.78; Arizona, $13.28; Virginia, 
$10.46; New York, $9.05; Rhode Island, $9.02; and Louisiana, 
$7.89. In the cases of both Massachusetts and Arizona, the debt 
figures include local debts for which the States have made them- 
selves responsible. 

These figures as to the size of the debts and the net debts per 
capita in the various States, while important, must The net debt 
not be taken as conclusive in the matter of the rela- fS^ ro^""^ 
tive safety of the various state bonds. There must <i^sive 
be considered in addition not only what the States have to show for 

' Table from Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Wealth, Debt, and 
Taxation, ipij (Washington, 1915), vol. i, p. 37. 

' The State of West Virginia has been held liable for a portion of the debt of the 
old State of Virginia. This subject will be discussed later in this chapter. 



96 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 









<3 



6*a 



■■ill 



I 



•c 
8 



a 



•3 

i5 



« M « w^M 

Oi o o o> ^ 



M e« « CI 

oo>o<o> 



« M « tO*4 

H H H H M 

0> Oi Oi o> Ot 



c4n « CI n 

M M H M l-t 
O 0> Ol Ol Ol 



f^M C< Ct C« 

0>0>0>0>0t 






»O00>O t*3 O 
Otc« i>-aq c^ 



0~ m" m' o" 
C) (O "i *'! 



aao.a q 

U V 0} p 3 



J-e ti « : 






^^^^ 



mOdOO Mi-Hmo 



« O C« H (O 



1000*0 ^ Oi 

t^ H VO ^ Tj- 

(ooq O t^ O; 
« ^10 cT (o 

M o c« « M 
»*j CO w o <o 



M C4 Ot M 

10 M CT O 

■* H_ M_ « 

O PO O ■^ 

HVO M to 
M t^\0 0» 



•*0 10 O M 
M « O t^ e< 
«0*0 fO»0 M 



t^ oco «o o 
>o to Ot M O 
00 iH Oi q> O 
Hi\o ^ »o i-T 
^ ^10 to>o 

^»0 N C0»0 

^*0 M t^ » 



w O CTOO ^ 
O « »0 M 00 

oio cT M « 

CO •*« t^ M 

0*0 ^*o 10 

tC m" It "f M 



to-* 't 

10 « M 

I di^OO I 

C< MO 
I WJ 00 ' 



Oi »^ e^ I- 



o>o 

O (O 

*o q 



l^ll l\ Is S||SK |||?S 



Oi«0 0'»0 ^ 

"*00 Th W M 

H o (4 Oi q 

C> ■* w" ■* O 

■^ rO >0 »OiO 

OO O O O M 



OfOMO> -^OOtOio 

>ooo o M 00 o ■* ■^ c5 

tJ- m t^vO O to 000 00 

^MniH lot^tir^M 



M ^ 0> «>.*». 
(O to t^OOO 

O M to 10 M 



« (O M o> n 



<0 OvoO 
IT} u r«>O00 
q^*q« to 
to to to 10 O 

\00 Oi o to 
ei_ c«^to ^ ^ 

^O O eft^io 

M to 



8 to 00 
I- fO 
1000 M 

to Oi o 
M 00 ci" 



00 r^ t- M >0 O to -^OO 

'OO'OO MMOOr*^ 

o tj oi o 0. w o q^ 

M ■<? t^OO to o ^ o ^ 

(4 t^iO ^ M -tj- to o> to 

qtoj^to o; qo ■* (^ 

e* w M toc^wtoo 



r*. o>cO Oi M 
e* (* CToo O 
M M M to N 
^ to cS IH 'o 

to« ^o^o 0> 
to'O C^^ *<0 H 



N 11 ^ ai^ 
H t* r* to ^ 
N'O'OOO *» 

\0 M T? fOOO 

CO M to "<t q 

^0 «^ ci" ^ ^ 



« to o- o« 
toco ^ ^r* 

q o f; qoo 

M ■<? M 00 to 

to to o to ■* 
e« OOQ o O 



:^»Otot* ooOtoOit^ 

DiHtOM cOMO^r^ 

:i^(Otoio *1'^'*T". 

*coiHfO rfO'CT'Oto 

^^Omm OOOfOOtO 

!f O M M ^ fO'O t^ 



^iOM00>O c*OiOiOm 

O c* 00 0>*0 « M O to ^ 

^ ^ ^ *^ q; *; *^ q^^'q 

O 10 tooo o »o o >ooo O 

Tooo ^00 to »o q N ^ Tt 



CI M 



IOMOOOOi MlOOlN 

t^ t* O to ■* 1000 O O 

lOtotoOtt ^r^HCi^ 

cT if d w (O ©"^O O ■^ 

tO&toOit~ M«MtO 



to O to o o 
O Noo r* g 
t--\0 t»->o o 

d" « d"*© d" 

10 r« to to r^ 
^ d to to to 

« Ct M 



■*O00 o » 

f-lO OitO ( 

ei''0 r? ti? t 
to tj- w» n ( 
^10 e^ qo 
^(O w toe^ 



w O Oit-O 

Q> Oi M ti M 

q « to to q 

dito d w (^ 

CO ftiO t*-* 
O to -^i^t- 



000 CO Oi 
C« O 00 to 



to Q O t 

to Oi W r 
■* ro« t 



It*. Q O M 6 to 1 
-8 "?^Sl 



O OOOO o 
00 Oi iJ-00 m 

00 M q^q q 
cTtooo w tC 
»"* o o*-* 

H ■^>0 to 



? ;: 



t«, MOQ 

ctOO Ot 

»q M cj^ 
d"q^ I I 



•*o. 
t^ to 

NO 00 

' torn ' 



§^900 QQl»0 OQto O ^00 O O C« O 0< O O 

1^000 00>00 toOM O 0>dO to>0 O Ot 6 O 

ciioto^ mQioio « to'O O to O t^ r»*0 O QO O O 



«^00 000 Tt 
ip e« to a T' 
O to c« O ^ 
d> •O M O M «^ «' 



*10 H « 

10^ 9 to 
O vva to 



to '* 

fO*0 



8*0 to c 
_ 000 f 

Oto c« ( 



3; 



a g! 



2:1 sir 

g I'd c9 d .::i.s.a.s o 



8 



i 1 

t % 

S a 

S 9 

it a 



ra 9 

■I 1 






§ 5 • 

I .-§1 

•S 2'5 

■S -S* 

i !•& 

s ^ s 

E? '%^ 

■r o^ 

ss-sr 



a s rt - 

n.S'.aa 



•I 






STATE BONDS 



97 






3'S. 
<3 



,?^'S'S 



lit 



I 



1 



pq 



a 



I 



•s 






nnnMn einnein MMCtciO 



O" H M M O 

!z;Q<Oiz; 



0> O Ov O Oi 
H W M H H 

o O - »o o 



o ot o> oi a 

H H H H M 

o 2! H " o 



et t% ft tfitt 

o o ^ a Oi 



« « ton 






3«o ■^00 oi to 



m "<t & 10 Tf ^ CtCOOO 

6^^ dicod 



■* 10 w <? pi 
co'S'vo q^ « 
^tCio woo 

•* M M 



«poo o p£ o 



) 10 ■<f VO 0> H O Or 



B0_ CO O^ ( 

o C^io" d" 6" w *o bi oi w 

wH^tO oo\0^ioc 

»OVO M ^ M C" 



>£>00 

00 <o 



H (9 Ol 
H Ol **J 
lO'^OO I 



•8 



I ro »n I 00 ci I vo op I |i^!?sl IMh III 

'■Ovo'm io'm»o' 'OOt'^M' *''m III 



CO 00 00 00 \o 







OJM Tt M_ 


«? 


Tf 00 W 









tq.t^q 


* 



O -^00 o^o 



p> ^ OiOO to 
000 M CM>. 

toca_ q 'if M 
to Hoo « di 
00 »^ t^vO r~ 

N ■^OO 10 CO 

MO-* woo 



a too H 
00 M 1010 
to t; Oj « 

\o di>o (o 
MOO t*.*- 

H 10 to CO 



f?il 



Oo>e« M O 

0*I0 t«.»«.QO 

^00' 00 d> di 
«00 Irt t^^o 

*2o q>N o 



H H W 0> Ct 
0»tO« 0« 
^OlC^HOO 

*o M'd" 



to O.\0 00c 

O t^ H ^ C 
■*0 « N C 



H Q 10 « 

"* 0« H 

d' to m" ■^ 

r* c- >o\o 
*0 Oi'O 10 



OoO t».»oiO 
i-t M tooo r- 
tO 000 H ro 
(O cSco ^»o 
*^ 1^0 00 10 
>Ol/3 10 00 



Oi^O «0 O tv 
>O00<O l-l H 



(O M w*o >o 

000 M^O « 



OO M H to O \0 Tj-00 

^- Oho w t* ^ M N H 
CO tO"© <0 to -^vo OiOO 



^ Ol 1-( Ol N 
O »0 i-HO CO 

Tj- d O (io 
b» r~ (^ t(- CO 
tO^O H VO M 



« O O O (o 
to ^ O ^'* 

t^ "^ CO ■^N_ 

t'-oo t^ Q O 
»o m CO O to 
"* O Ol to q; 
woo lo*©" 



CI OcQ 10 Q 
«ovo O r> 
00 w t^oo o 
©■ Ol Q w" d" 
(O »o O M t^ 
■OoO M to 



*0 0> TfO H 

n Ol a o to 

t^ TfvO cSioo 
w "d" di o t 

00 \0 TflO'O 



^ Ol « Ol « 
Ol^o^»^0 to 
to t>-00 O^O 
'tfo OOCO 
i'-io '♦woo 
to l/J 



00 
O V) 



^to 
Ol-* 



00 M 5 

, to to C 



O Oi^ VIM CO 

^0 Ol 01 f- O 00 

q qi\o ts^ to q; 

00 00" o to w "^ I 

M r« M ci Ol w 

<0 W W M 



I o" T? ^o I 00 I I ■<? I I «^ I d" I 

IooomI 00' 'ml IhIio' 



M«0 Q 

I I 1 ll I I a I 

to ■* « 



§§ i 



188 3 



« M r~ M t 

O to CO t 

r- to O ( 



g"- 



r« qi M I o to I ' 



.9 




•SSESE SSSiga ag-SlI g 83 8.3" iM^ 
iSlSisigg! :zigg;o3 o(£S(i3<2 S^D;>;> ^^^^ 



98 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

their debts/ but also the proportion between the debts and the 
value of taxable property. 

Percentaee of ^ ^^^ table OH page 99, we givc asscsscd valuation, 
net debt to same per capita, debt less sinking-fund assets, same 
uation in the per Capita, and per cent of debt less sinking-f imd assets 

erent tates ^ assessed Valuation in all the States in 1912-13.* 

This table (Table II) shows that the States of Massachu- 
setts, Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, Alabama, Missis- 
sippi, Tennessee, Louisiana, New Mexico, Arizona, and Idaho have 
net debts of 1% or over of their assessed valuations. The largest 
percentage of net debt is that of Virginia with 2.55% of its assessed 
valuation. States having net debts of less than one tenth of 1% of 
their assessed valuations, in addition to Pennsylvania and West 
Virginia, are: New Jersey, Ohio, Indiana, Wisconsin, Minnesota, 
Iowa, Nebraska, Kansas, Wyoming, and Oregon. 

Like the figures for the debts themselves, these figiures showing 
the proportion of net debts to assessed valuations are only part of 
Relation be- the story. In every State the question arises as to 
aS?&u?ra.iufi what part of the actual or true value of property the 
of property assesscd Valuation represents.^ In New York State, 
for instance, the assessed valuation for 191 2 represents only about 
44.51% of the estimated true value of property as given by the 
census, and in Pennsylvania the assessed valuation represents only 
about 32.79% of the estimated true value. In Ohio the proportion 
of assessed valuation to true value of property is about 72.75%, 
whereas in Illinois it is only about 15.14%. In Massachusetts the 
proportion is 76.20% and in California 34.51%. In any given 
State the relation of the assessed value to the true value of the 
property, as far as can be ascertained, should be borne in mind in 
estimating the burden of debt on the State. 

On the whole, it may fairly be said that the debts of our States 
are small. This has not always been true to the same extent that it 

1 For value of public properties of States, see Abstract of Special Bulletins, 
Wealth, Debt and Taxation, 1(113 (Washington, 1915), vol. I, p. 58. The total value 
of public properties of all the States in 1913 is given as $695,499,187, compared 
with total debts less sinking-fund assets of $34S,942>3oS- 

2 Wealth, Debt and Taxation, igij (Washington, 1915), vol. I, pp. 37, 747, 749. 

» For estimated true value of all property, 1850-1912, and same per capita by 
States, see Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, igis, vol. i, pp. 23-26. 



STATE BONDS 



99 



TA 


lBle n 








Assessed 

taluaUm * 


Assessed 
valuation 
per capita 


Debt less 

sinking fund 

assets 


Deht pet 
captia 


Pereentaee 
of net debt 
to assessed 


$566,807,488 


$253.00 


$13,132,375 


$5.95 


2.32% 


140,338,191 


608.00 


3.064,818 


13.28 


2.18 


427,473,108 


258.00 


1,236,066 


0.76 


■29 


2,921,277,451 


1,09500 


10,322,744 


3.83 


.35 


422,330,199 


478.00 


3,173,949 


3-70 


•75 


1,041,334.019 


881.00 


7.110.4S1 


«.I2 


.68 


93,814,011 


451-00 


763.122 


3.70 


.81 


212,887,518 


258.00 


619,199 


0.77 


■29 


842,358,342 


308.00 


6,934,302 


2.57 


.83 


167,512,157 


442 .00 


3,143,314 


5.92 


1.28 


2,343,673,232 


397.00 


3,272,620 


0.39 


.10 


1,898,307,218 


688.00 


1,350,305 


0.49 


•07 


902,092,597 


406.00 


356,670 


0.16 


■°^„ 


3,746,900,291 


1,630.00 


243.121 


0.14 


.008 


1,031,174,033 


441.00 


4.441.867 


1.90 


'43 


550,517,808 


315.00 


13.546.150 


7.89 


3.4fi 


416,891,264 


SSO.oo 


1.254,998 


1.67 


■30 


1.235,457,607 


929.00 


7.333,913 


5.56 


•59 


4,803,078,625 


1.353.00 


79.551.090 


22.78 


1.66 


2,317,561,634 


789.00 


7,089,092 


3.41 


•31 


1,474.585.315 


676.00 


1,345,290 


0.63 


.09 


i,86o!o87[956 


319.00 


4,460,519 


3.41 


1.08 


555-00 


4,671,218 


1.40 


-35 


346,550,585 


827.00 


1,512,874 


3.73 


•44 


463,371,889 


376.00 


374.394 


0.31 


.08 


101,087,082 


1,067.00 


607,695 


6.70 


.60 


, 439,683,132 


1,007.00 


1.955,611 


4.50 


■44 


2,490,490,534 


906.00 


642,069 


0.34 


.03 


72,457,454 


196,00 


1,218,209 


3.41 


1.68 


11,131,778,917 


1,146.00 


86,205,347 


9.05 


.77 


747,500,632 


324.00 


8,058,430 


3.54 


1.08 


293,048,119 


443.00 


830,424 


1.29 


.31 


6,481,059,158 


1.30500 


5,142,042 


I. OS 


.08 


1,193,655,846 


616.00 


6,930,243 


3.74 


•58 


905,011,679 


1,196.00 


30,853 


0.04 


.003 


5,068,802,988 


625.00 




— 




619,010,208 


1,068.00 


5,136,815 


9.02 


.83 


291,531.003 


185.00 


6,190,036 


3.98 


3.13 


354.278^413 


551.00 


370,000 


0.58 


.10 


625,686,793 


280.00 


11,811,640 


S.32 


1.89 


2,532,710,050 


607.00 


4,656,499 


1.14 


.18 


200,399,207 


49S.OO 


1,429,694 


3.62 


•71 


221,530,142 


615.00 


569,906 


1.58 


.36 


864,962,621 


406.00 


33,043,145 


10.46 


3.55 


1,005,086,251 


747.00 


1,556,012 


1.21 


•IS 


1,168,012,658 


894.00 




— 




2,466,636,793 


1,019.00 


3,251,000 


0.93 


.09 


180,750,630 


1,107.00 


123,375 


0.77 


•07 



State 



Alabama 

•Arizona 

Arkansas 

California 

Colorado , 

Connecticut 

Delaware , 

Florida 

Georgia , 

Idaho 

Illinois , 

iT^diana 

Iowa 

Kansas 

Kentucky , 

Louisiana 

Maine 

Maryland . . . . , 
Massachusetts . . 

Michigan , 

Minnesota 

Mississippi 

Missouri 

Montana 

Nebraska , 

Nevada 

New Hampshire 
New Jersey . . . . 
New Mexico . . . , 

New York 

North Carolina . 
North Dakota . . 

Ohio 

Oklahoma 

Oregon 

Pennsylvania . . . 
Rhode Island. . . 
South Carolina , 
South Dakota . . 

Tennessee 

Texas , 

Utah 

Vermont , 

Virginia 

Washin^on 

West Virginia . , 

Wisconsin 

Wyoming 



* Assessed valuation of all property subject to ad valorem taxation. There was in many States a large 
increase in assessed valuation m igz3. .Among these States may be mentioned Alabama, Colorado, Idaho, 
Kentudiy, and South Dakota. (See Slate and City Supplement of the Commercial and Financial Chronichf 
May 39, 191S-) 



is to-day. In 1790/ the National Government arranged to as- 
sume state debts incurred largely for the Revolution- changes in 
ary War, and did actually assume $18,271,786.47 s^tl^bts 
of these debts. Between 1790 and 1820, the States 1790-1913 

' Act approved August 4, 1790, ist Cong., 2d Sess. (i Stat. L. chap, xxxiv, 
P- 139.) 



lOO AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

incurred only a small amount of debt. From 1820 to 1830, they 
issued bonds amounting to $26,470,417, and from 1830 to 1838, 
$147,836,577.1 The Civil War brought a large increase in the debts 
of many of our States.^ For the years from 1870 to 1913 inclusive, 
the table ' on page loi shows the total debts, net debts, and net 
debts per capita of aU the States. 

As may be seen from the table, the total debt less sinking- 
fund assets of aU our States in 1913 actually was less than in 1870. 
The lowest point was reached in 1895, after which there was a grad- 
ual increase until 1913, when an unusual increase took place. This 
was due probably to the exceptional demand for securities of the 
class of state bonds and to the tendency of certain States in recent 
years to issue large amounts of bonds for roads, canals, and other 
improvements. Owing to the rapid increase in population, the 
per capita increase has not always followed closely the absolute 
increase. The lowest net debt per capita for the period covered by 
the table was reached in 1909 and the highest in many years in 
1913. On the whole, as stated above, the aggregate debt of our 
States may be spoken of as moderate. 

This comparative freedom of our States from debt has been the 

result, in most cases, of long and sometimes bitter experience. At 

Comparative some time in their history, twenty of oiu: States, in- 

beedomfrom eluding some of our bcst Northern States, have de- 
debt due to ° , ' 
bitter ex- faulted the mterest on their bonds or compromised 

nence ^^ repudiated the principal. 

When we remember that it is impossible in the present condition 
Importance of of the law to force a State to pay its bonds, the record 
debt history ^f ^j^g different States in the payment of their obliga- 
tions becomes of commanding importance. 

There were three periods of default, compromise, or repudiation: 
(i) From 1840-42, when Pennsylvania, Maryland, Indiana, Uli- 
Three periods nois, and Michigan, as well as Florida, Mississippi, 
wmpro"^or ^nd Arkansas defaulted; (2) from 1848-60, when 
repudiation Minnesota, Texas, and California began certain ad- 
justments of their debts; and (3) from the beginning of the Civil 
War down to the early nineties, when Virginia, North Carolina, 

> tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 523. » Ibid., pp. 530, 537, 554. 

» National and Stale Indebtedness, iSjo-igzs, p. 18. 



STATE BONDS 



lOI 



South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama, Tennessee, Louisiana, 
Arkansas, and Missouri defaulted on or compromised their bonds. 
In this period also arose the difficulties between Virginia and West 
Virginia. 



TOTAL AND NET DEBT AND NET DEBT PER CAPITA OF 
ALL THE STATES, 1870-1913 



Year 



1870. 

1880, 

1891. 
1892. 
1893. 
1894. 
189s 

1896 
1897, 
1898 
1899 
1900 

1901 
1902 
1903 
1904 
190S 

1906 
1907 
1908 
1909 

1910 
1911 
1912 
1913 



Total Debt 



$352,866,698 

306,016,561 

258,195,056 
249,266,723 
240,175,83s 
233,146,225 
225,488,146 

226,702,714 
237.043.590 
253.957,941 
261,118,967 
265,133,041 

262,247,074 
274,148,756 
266,926,910 
272.493.578 
278,135.397 

281,411,192 

279.768,751 
290,029,63s 
300,494,024 

322,948,868 
347,041,981 
376,114,098 
422,796,525 



Sinkmg-Funi 
Assets 



$31,270,789 

46,984,569 
43,518,777 
38,124,440 
37,429,077 
31,271,660 

28,123,908 
28,358,779 
30,049,746 
32,602,117 
29,821,060 

33,856,273 
34,859,467 
34,791,189 
36,846,091 
39,264,804 

42,952.929 

44,501,415 
50,655,306 

59,355,095 

66,813,710 
71,177,988 
76,451,848 
76,980,571 



Debt less Sinking- 
Fund Assets 



Amount 



Per 

Capita 



$352,866,698 
274,745.772 

211,210,487 
205,747,946 
202,051,395 
196,194,298 ' 
194,216,486 

198,578.806 
208,684,811 
223,908,195 
228,571,048 » 
23S.453.594 ' 

228,478,997 ' 
239.369,271 ' 
232,135.721 
23S.647.487 
238,870,593 

238,458,263 
235,267,336 
239,374,329 
241,138,929 

256,143,276 ' 
275,919,983 ' 
299.763.423 ' 
345,942,305 " 



B9.1S 
5-48 

3-3r 
314 
3-03 

2.88 
2.80. 

2.81 
2.90. 
3 06, 
.3-07 
3.10. 

2.9s 
3-03 
2.88 
2.86 
2.8s 



2.79. 
2.70. 
2.70, 
2.67 

2.78 
2-95 
3 IS 
3-57 



> Not reported. ' Sinking fund exceeds debt $477.iSo — Rhode Island. 
' Sinking fund exceeds debt $54,198 — New Jersey. 
< Sinking fund exceeds debt $141,613 — New Jersey. 
» Sinking fund exceeds debt $88,196 — New Jersey. 
• Sinking fund exceeds debt $79,982 — New Jers^. 
' Sinking fund exceeds debt $8,118 — Pennsylvania, 
s Sinking fund exceeds debt $S5,990 — Pennsylvania. 
» Sinking fund exceeds debt $101,173 — Pennsylvania. 
10 Sinking fund exceeds debt $126,351 — Pennsylvania. 



I02 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The earliest period of default followed the financial crisis of 
1837-39. At the beginning of 1830, the debts of the States were 
only about $13,000,000. In 1834, the last installment 
of the United States debt was paid — an act which 
firmly established our credit abroad. In view of the fact that the 
States did a large part of their borrowing in London, the impor- 
tance of this becomes apparent. Provision was made in 1836 for 
distribution of the surplus revenues of the United States among the 
several States.^ Furthermore, the period was a prosperous one all 
over the world. There had been in our country a real and substan- 
tial growth, although the population and resources of the Western 
States were small. These favorable factors were magnified by other 
influences of a more doubtful character. The fight between the 
United States Government and the United States Bank caused the 
chartering of large numbers of state banks all over the country. 
Paper money became abundant, and a spirit of speculation per- 
meated the whole country. "Men acted as if a short and secure 
road to wealth had been discovered, on which all might travel, and 
he who went the fastest would be the first to reach the desired 
end." ^ The States borrowed money generously and spent it lav- 
ishly. Internal improvements were undertaken on a huge scale. 
Rashness became "epidemic." Before the crash came, high prices 
for practically everything prevailed. Then, more or less suddenly, 
the Bank of England stopped the credit of several American bank- 
ing houses in London. Suspension of specie payments soon fol- 
lowed, then a short renewal, and then a second suspension. Not 
only the Bank of the United States in Pennsylvania, but every 
bank south of Philadelphia, stopped payment. By 1840 many of 
our States were in financial difficulties.^ 

In the following pages we shall attempt to give a short debt his- 
Compiete short tory of all the defaulting States. So far as we know, 
drfaiUtiiS^'^ °' this is the only collected history, written from sources 
States a,nd brought up to date, which includes all the States 

1 Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 529. 

' North American Review, Janiiary, 1844, p. 114. 

• Ibid., pp. 110-22. See also Bankers' Magazine and Statistical Register, Novem- 
ber, 1849, pp. 341-43. For a short discussion of the origin and^development of the 
internal improvement Idea, see Dewey, Financial History of the United States (New 
York, 1915), pp. 212-16. 



STATE BONDS I03 

at one time or another defaulting on their bonds. In view of the fact 
that the experiences of many of these States have been more or 
less similar, some readers may prefer to follow the histories only of 
such States as interest them. The very similarity, however, of so 
many of the debt histories makes all the clearer the lessons to be 
learned. Not only the reasons for default are established, but the 
way in which the bondholders fared in final settlement. 

August I, 1842, Pennsylvania defaulted interest on its bonds. ^ 
In 1 82 5 , the State had entered upon an important sys- 
tem of internal improvements. Under the impulse of 
an act ^ passed in 1836 to charter the United States Bank, — 
which act also repealed the state tax on real and personal property, 
— a new series of improvements was begun. Bonds were issued, 
largely in aid of railroads and canals, until in 1842 the state debt 
had reached $37,319,395- After the panic of 1837, work on the 
state improvements ceased, and many of the properties passed into 
private hands. For a large part of its debt, the State obtained 
nothing whatever. Furthermore, it was obliged to receive in pay- 
ment of revenues its own "relief notes" or depreciated currency. 
Under this combination of unfavorable circumstances, the State 
was unable to pay interest in cash. 

It issued for interest, however, 6% certificates or scrip.' At one 
time something over $3,000,000 of principal was overdue. Im- 
proved methods of assessment and a revision of the tax laws en- 
abled the State to resume interest payments in February, 1845. 
At first, these payments were made to a considerable extent in 
"relief notes." In 1848, only a small amount of these notes re- 
mained outstanding.^ In 1857 and 1858, provision was made for 
retirement of a considerable portion of the principal of the debt 
through sale of raDroad and canal property.^ 

In January, 1842, Maryland failed to pay interest on its debt. 
Like Peimsylvaiua, Maryland had breathed in the , . 

, , , , ... 1 . -1 M 1 • Maryland 

spirit of unbounded optimism which prevailed in 

the ten or a dozen years preceding 1837. It had subscribed to the 

1 North American Review, January, 1844, p. 122. 

^ Laws of Pennsylvania (1835-36), no. 22. 

' See Laws of Pennsylvania (1842), no. 127. 

< For above account, see Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, March, 1849, pp. 257-68. 

" See Tenth Census, vol. vii, p. 544. 



I04 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

stocks of various railroads, including the Baltimore and Ohio, and 
had loaned money to and purchased the stock of the Chesapeake 
and Ohio Canal. At the time when the State was using thus its 
credit, it had no system of taxation whatever. It depended solely 
on the income of the public works, or else on the sale of additional 
bonds, to meet the interest on its debt. The general insolvency 
following the panic of 1837 caused a suspension of the canal works 
for some years. The income from all the improvements was far less 
than the amount necessary to pay interest on the state debt, and 
the State was unable to negotiate further bonds abroad. 

To meet this situation, laws were passed in 1841 and 1842 ^ pro- 
viding for a direct tax. The lack of a proper system for collecting 
the taxes, however, together with the difficulty of the times, made 
this measure ineffective. When the State found itself imable to pay 
interest, it received coupons in payment of taxes. From 1844 to 
1846, it made partial payments on interest current and accrued. 
Later, it funded arrears of interest with 6% bonds. On January i, 
1848, it resumed current interest on its public debt in fuU. Al- 
though at one time some people in the State had shown a leaning 
toward repudiation,^ the record of Maryland as it was written was 
such as to inspire confidence in its good faith.* 

Indiana suspended interest payments after January, 1840. In 

keeping with the spirit and practice of the times, the State had 

issued bonds in aid of the Wabash and Erie Canal, the 

Indiana ^ _^,-^,, ,_ , , 

State Bank of Indiana, and other pnvate enterpnses. 
The negotiation of the bonds had been a source of "fearful jobbing " 
and had resulted in serious losses to the State. When in 1839 it 
became impossible to borrow more money, the public works were 
suspended and many of them were surrendered or abandoned. It 
was impossible to collect from the small farmers, who made up most 
of the population at this time, sufficient taxes to meet the interest 
on the heavy debt. At the time of default there was also a consider- 

• Laws of Maryland, vol. 20 (1841), chap. 23; ibid., vol. xxi (1842), chap. 116; 
ibid., chap. 328. 

2 For above account, see North American Review, January, 1844, pp. 125-27, and 
Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, May, 1849, pp. 483-89. 

' In 1837, when banks had suspended specie pajrments, Maryland paid its inter- 
est in gold or silver or its equivalent. (Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, May, 1849, 
p. 487.) 



STATE BONDS I05 

able amount of State paper outstanding receivable for taxes. The 
tender of this prevented, of course, the receipt of money available 
for interest. 

To settle the interest, state bonds bearing 7% interest and re- 
deemable in five years were offered, but of these only a trifling 
amount were accepted. The principal and back interest of the debt 
finally were settled by an act passed January 19, 1846, and 
amended January 27, 1847.^ These acts provided that one half the 
old debt and interest should be taken care of with new bonds pay- 
able from taxation and the other half with certificates payable from 
the property and tolls of the Wabash and Erie Canal.^ Cash inter- 
est pajonents on state bonds were resumed at the rate of 4% July 
1, 1847.' 

July, 1841, Illinois stopped payment of interest on its debt. An 
act* for an immense system of internal improvements had been 
passed in 1837. Bonds had been issued for railroads, . 

bank-stocks, and the Illinois and Michigan Canal. 
When "the great revulsion overtook the commercial world," all 
work on the public improvements stopped. Many banks which 
had bought state bonds failed, "and the State never got any- 
thing." Banks to whose capital the State had subscribed finally 
were wound up "with total loss of capital." The State was 
obliged, moreover, to receive its own depreciated paper for public 
dues. In 1844, the total debt, including interest, was given by 
the Governor as $14,440,381.^ Like Indiana, Illinois at this time 
simply was unable to pay." 

Within a few years, however, the Illinois and Michigan Canal 
was completed, interest on that part of the state debt was paid to 
date, and the process of discharging the principal was begun.^ To 

1 General Laws of Indiana (1845-46), chap, i; ibid. (1847), chap. i. 

' The canal was completed and for a time paid promptly interest on the certi- 
ficates. Later, however, it proved a failure. (See Tenth Census, vol. vii, pp. 621-22, 
and Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 19, p. 493.) 

• For above account, see Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, August, 1849, pp. 150-60. 

* Public Laws of Illinois (1836-37), pp. 121-52 Supplemental Act. Ibid., pp. 
152-53- (Both approved March 4, 1837.) 

» Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, December, 1852, pp. 661-64; ibid., March, 1858, 
p. 278. 

» North American Review, January, 1844, p. 127. 
' Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, March, 1858, p. 279. 



Io6 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

take care of the state debt other than the canal debt, annual taxes 
were provided.^ January i, 1857, the Governor of the State de- 
clared that during the past four years $4,564,800.40 had been paid 
in liquidation of the public debt as well as interest on the principal 
during that time. "There is now no doubt about the State being 
prepared to pay the interest upon her whole debt as it matures in 
future.^ The record of Elinois is one of delayed payments, but of 
payments in full. 

Michigan defaulted in its interest payments July i, 1841.' The 
Constitution of the State adopted at the time of the 
admission of the State to the Union urged the con- 
struction of a system of internal improvements.* In 1837, the 
Legislature projected a system of improvements, including rail- 
roads, canals, and river improvements, exceeding both the means 
and the needs of the people. A loan of $5,000,000 was authorized 
for these objects.^ The State was to sell its bonds through an 
" agent" — the Morris Canal and Banking Company of New York 
— and to receive payment in installments. Under this arrange- 
ment, the State marketed $1,362,000 of its bonds at par less a 
commission of 2|%. The agent was unable to settle for the re- 
maining $3,638,000 bonds. These bonds, with $200,000 railroad- 
aid bonds, were then sold to the United States Bank at Philadelphia 
and the Morris Canal and Banking Company on time. Both 
concerns failed and the State received only $998,000. The State 
was unable to meet its interest, and work on the public im- 
provements was stopped. 

In settlement, Michigan agreed to acknowledge as much of its 
debt as it had received payment for in tuH. For interest on this 
from July i, 1841, to July i, 1845, it issued new 6% bonds.' Bonds 
for which the State had received no payment were to be canceled. 

' Const. III. (1848) , art. XV. This part of the debt had been funded to a large extent 
under an act passed in 1847. (See Public Laws of Illinois [1846-47], pp. 161-65.) 

' Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, May, 1857, p. S4S- 

» North American Review, January, 1844, p. 134. 

* Constitution of Michigan (1835), art. xn, sec. 3. 

' Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, February, 1850, pp. 133-34. Act approved 
March 21, 1837, as amended by act approved November 15, 1837. {Laws of Michi- 
gan [1837], no. 77; ibid. [1837-38], no. i.) 

° Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, February, 1850, pp. 136-37. Act approved March 
8, 1843. (Laws of Michigan [1843], no- 73-) 



STATE BONDS I07 

In settlement of bonds for which the State had received only partial 
pa3rments, it arranged to issue new bonds for the amount received 
by the State, together with interest, but less damages for non- 
pajnnent.^ The amount actually received on part-paid bonds was 
ascertained to be $s°2^-^ per $1000. Later, the State sold certain 
railroads and accepted pajrment in state bonds on the basis of the 
above settlement.^ The weak point in Michigan's record arises 
from the fact that part-paid bonds had been pledged by the 
United States Bank in Pennsylvania to secure loans from various 
banking houses in Europe, and appeared to be in the hands of 
innocent purchasers.' 

After January i, 1840, the then Territory of Florida paid no 
interest on an issue of bonds of the Bank of Pensacola endorsed 
by the Territory. In addition to this endorsement, 
Florida had issued bonds to supply the capital of the 
Union Bank of Florida, and later, bonds in behalf of the Southern 
Life Insurance and Trust Company.* In 1837, the banks suspended 
specie payments and soon after were found to be hopelessly insol- 
vent. The population of Florida in 1840 was only about 50,000, and 
the liabilities of the Territory fairly heavy. ^ The bonds referred to 
the Territorial Legislature later repudiated.' The Constitution of 
the State, adopted before the admission of Florida to the Union, 
denied to the Legislature the power of laying any tax for the 
purpose of paying the bonds which were issued by the Terri- 
tory.'' 

Again, in 1873, the Legislature refused to make provision for 
certain state bonds in default — notably $4,000,000 bonds issued 
to the Jacksonville, Pensacola, and Mobile Railroad Company.' 
At this time Florida had a funded and floating debt of nearly 
twenty per cent of its total assessed valuation. The taxes collected 

» See Laws of Michigan (1842), no. 60, and ibid., p. 172 (Joint Resolution no. 38). 

' Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, February, 1850, pp. 138-39. See Laws of Michi- 
gan (1842), no. 60. 

» North American Review, January, 1844, pp. 136-37. 

* Bankers' Magazine, December, 1857, pp. 449-50. 

« Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 587- 

« Bankers' Magazine, December, 1857, p. 430. 

' Constitution of Florida (1838; effective March 3, 1845), art. vm, sec. 2. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 16, p. 387. Tenth Census, vol. vn, 
pp. 588-89. Fart of these bonds were for the benefit of the Florida Central Railroad. 



I08 AMERICAN AI^ FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

had proved insufficient for the requirements of the State. ^ Further- 
more, a good deal of railroad property had been destroyed during 
the Civil War.!* 

Yet the method of escape chosen and the excuse given were char- 
acteristic. The Attorney-General of the State declared that there 
was no provision by law for assessing a tax to pay either principal 
or interest on state bonds issued to the Jacksonville, Pensacola, and 
Mobile Railroad. He alleged fraud and illegality, and declared that 
the Legislature never would authorize a tax to pay the bonds.' 
The Supreme Court of Florida sustained the Attorney-General and 
the Legislature in the repudiation.* In 1912, the Council of the 
Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, London, listed $7,000,000 old 
bonds of Florida in default.^ 

After July i, 1840, Mississippi paid no interest on $2,000,000 
bonds put out to subscribe to the stock of the Planters' Bank,* and 

.... in 1842, repudiated, on the ground of illegality and 
alleged fraud, a $5,000,000 issue put out to promote 
the Union Bank.^ Both the Planters' Bank and the Union Bank 
failed.* It was for this reason rather than from inability to pay that 
Mississippi refused to recognize its bonds. The resources of the 
State were ample.' Furthermore, in the case of the Union Bank 
bonds, the Legislature of 1839 had resolved "that the sale of the 
bonds was highly advantageous to the State and the bank." ^" 
There were no substantial grounds of illegality in either case. The 
State Court of Errors and Appeals had held the Union Bank bonds 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 16, p. 187, and vol. 17, p. 19. 

' International Review, November, i88o, p. S79- 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 17, p. 323. 

" Holland v. The State of Florida et al., 15 Florida, 455 (1876). 

' Thirty-ninth Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 

P-36S- 

' Bankers' Magazine, January, 1853, p. 497, and November, 1849, p. 342. 
December 2, 1852, the people voted against paying these bonds. {Bankers' Mag- 
azine, January, 1853, p. 499.) 

' North American Review, January, 1844, p. 132. Thirty-eighth Annual Report, 
Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, p. 388. 

* Bankers' Magazine, December, 1846, p. 339. Thirty-eighth Annual Report, 
Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, pp. 39-40. North American 
Review, January, 1844, p. 130. 

• Bankers' Magazine, December, 1850, pp. 454-56, and ibid., November, 1849, 

P- 349- 
" North American Review, January, 1844, p. 132. 



STATE BONDS I09 

valid obligations of the State, and the legality of the Planters' 
Bank bonds was not seriously questioned.^ 

The Constitution of Mississippi, as amended in 1876, prohibited 
the State from ever pajing the Union Bank bonds or the Planters' 
Bank bonds." Judge Curtis long ago wrote laconically that, in the 
payment of debts, there was a great difference between " the people 
of Mississippi and the people of Massachusetts." ' Mississippi can 
claim the honor of inventing the word "repudiation" in the sense 
in which it is now used.^ 

Arkansas was in default in 1841.^ The State had issued bonds 
in aid of the State Bank of Arkansas and the Real Estate Bank 
of Arkansas.' Later, the banks were placed in liqui- 
dation by an act of the Legislature.'' For many 
years, no interest was paid on the public debt. This was not due 
to lack of resources nor was it owing to any well-groimded claims 
of fraud. In 1845, the impaid interest on the state debt amoimted 
at least to as much as the principal. A moderate tax would have 
sufficed to take care of the accruing interest, yet such a tax the 
Legislature refused to levy.^ 

In 1869, an act ' was passed for fimding a portion of the state 
debt with new 6% bonds. By the close of 1870, Arkansas again 
had increased its debt by issuing bonds for building levees and 
over $5,000,000 bonds in aid of railroads.^" Some of the levee bonds 
issued to contractors were sold by them as low as twenty-six to 
twenty-seven cents on the dollar.^^ In 1873, all the aided railroads 
defaulted in interest, and the State did likewise.^" On January i, 
1878, the total debt of Arkansas had reached a figure of nearly 
twenty per cent of the assessed valuation of the State.^' 

1 Bankers' Magazine, November, 1853, p. 432. Thirty-eighth Annual Report, 
Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, pp. 386 and 388. 

2 Constitution of Mississippi, art. xii, sec. s, as amended January 18, 1876. See 
Constitution of i8go, art. xiv, sec. 258. 

5 North American Review, January, 1844, p. 133. 

* See Bankers' Magazine, December, 1846, p. 339. 

» Bankers' Magazine, December, 1854, p. 488. 

' Hunt's Merchants' Magazine, May, 1857, p. 542. 

' Tenth Census, vol. 7, p. 603. ' Bankers' Magazine, December, 1854, p. 488. 

» Acts of Arkansas (1868-69), no. 55. 

w Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 27, p. 15, and vol. 36, p. 706. 

" Ihid., vol. 14, p. 85. '* Ibid., vol. 36, p. 706, and vol. 40, p. 119. 

" Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 25, p. 161. 



no AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

In the sam6 year, the Supreme Court of the State, on technical 
grounds, held the levee bonds unconstitutional and void.^ The 
state legislature repudiated aU the railroad bonds because "au- 
thorized by alien adventurers"^ — the so-called "carpet-bag- 
gers" from the North. This action was confirmed by the Supreme 
Court of the State.' Against certain bonds included in the fimding 
of 1869, and known as "Holford" bonds, the people of Arkansas 
later charged fraud.* In 1885, an amendment to the Constitution 
of the State prohibited levying a tax or making an appropriation 
to pay interest or principal of the Holford bonds, the railroad-aid 
bonds, and certain of the levee bonds.' In March, 1887, the Legis- 
lature passed an act* providing for the "undisputed" debt, in- 
terest on which had been in default since 1872. Under an act 
passed in 1899, provision was made for refimding the recognized 
debt with an issue of 3% thirty-year bonds.^ The principal of 
the debt of Arkansas unprovided for in 191 2 has been given as 
$8,706,773.8 

The second period during which there broke out difficulties with 
state bonds — between 1848 and i860 — was of minor impor- 
Second period tauce. The troubles of Texas began before it was 
comprise annexed to the United States, and the difficulties of 
or repudiation California proved to be largely a question of legality 
and not of inability or unwillingness to pay. The case of Minne- 
sota was the only one resembling many of the earlier and many 
of the later defaults. 

An amendment ^ to the constitution of Minnesota adopted No- 
vember 6, i860, provided that no law for the payment of prin- 

* Smithee v. Garth, 33 Ark. 17. 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 31, p. 303. 

» State of Arkansas v. Little Rock, Mississippi River, and Texas Railway Com- 
pany, 31 Ark. 701. 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 33, p. 328. For history of "Holfords," 
see Tenth Census, vol. 7, p. 603. 

' Constitution of Arkansas (1874), Amendment no. i, adopted January 14, 1885. 
' Acts of Arkansas (1887), p. 269, Act cxxvi. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 
vol. 44, p. 421, and vol. 40, p. 119. 

' Acts of Arkansas (1899), p. 269, Act cxLvni. 

' Thirty-Ninth Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 

P- i(>S- 

* Constitution of Minnesota (i860), art. DC, sec. 2, as amended November 6, i860. 
See General Statutes of Minnesota (1866), p. 37. 



STATE BONDS III 

cipal or interest of $2,275,000 state bonds issued in aid of rail- 
roads should take effect until ratified by popular vote. , ,. 
The railroads, which had turned over first-mortgage 
bonds to the State, had become insolvent. When partially com- 
pleted, they had foimd themselves unable either to negotiate their 
own securities except at "ruinous rates" or to sell any considerable 
amount of state bonds issued for their benefit..^ In 1862, the 
State granted to the railroad companies title to lands and other 
property free and clear.^ Some of the state bonds had gotten into 
the hands of contractors and other innocent holders.* For many 
years, the State refused to recognize any of this debt. At one time 
the "Grangers" and later the national "Greenback-Labor" party 
were prominent among the repudiators. One "Granger" not only 
wanted elected judges pledged to "wipe out the bonds," but was 
ready to "wipe out the Supreme Court" of the United States if 
that court should by any chance declare the bonds an obligation 
of the State. According to good opinion, the State was able to pay 
its entire railroad debt without serious inconvenience.* 

In 1 88 1, the Supreme Court of the State held invalid the con- 
stitutional amendment repudiating the bonds,^ and thereby left 
to the legislature authority to settle the debt. At a special session 
of the legislature called September 19, 1881, an act * was passed 
providing for the settlement of the old debt on the basis of fifty 
cents on the dollar of cash or new 5% bonds for old 7% bonds and 
interest. On January 14, 1882, all but $108,000 of the $2,275,000 
state railroad bonds had been paid at this rate in new bonds or 
cash.'' 

The state legislature of Texas in 1848 passed an act * to provide 
for ascertaining and auditing the debt of the late 
Republic of Texas — interest on which was in de- 
fault. When Texas seceded from Mexico in 1835, it had a popula- 

1 Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 633-34. 

' Special Laws of Minnesota (1862), chaps, xvn and XX, pp. 226 and 247. 
' Scott, The Repudiation of State Debts (New York and Boston, 1893), p. 155. 
* Lalor's Cyclopcedia of Political Science (Chicago, 1884), vol. m, p. 608. 
' State V. Young, 29 Mmn. 474. 
' Laws of Minnesota (1881, extra session), chap. i. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 634. For interesting data bearing especially on the 
legality of the Minnesota railroad debt, see Minnesota State Bonds (New York, 1871). 
' Laws of Texas (1848), vol. n, chap. 143. 



112 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

tion of less than 140,000, of whom only about one third were white 
— the balance being principally Indians. The Republic had its 
independence to maintain, Indian marauders to keep off, and the 
other expenses of government to meet.^ For a large part of its 
debt, it was claimed, Texas had not received an3rwhere near face 
value. The state authorities divided the debt into three classes 
on the basis of the estimated value of the claims. The entire 
amovmt, including interest, was given as $9,647,253.14, to which 
was assigned a value of $4,807,764.37. 

On this basis it was proposed to settle the debt. When Texas 
had become a State, the United States had possessed itself of 
certain customs resources which had been pledged to secure the 
debt of the Republic." In the Texas "boundary biU," ' the United 
States, for the sake of including in New Mexico certain territory 
claimed by Texas, agreed to pay Texas $10,000,000 in 5% bonds, 
provided that only $5,000,000 should be issued until creditors of 
Texas had released the United States from all claims on accoxmt 
of customs pledged. The second five million never was received 
because the State could not comply with the conditions.^ Febru- 
ary 28, 1855, the United States appropriated $7,750,000 in cash 
and apportioned it among those creditors of Texas claiming against 
the United States.* At the close of 1856, the State was declared 
to be out of debt.* 

California was in default in interest in January, 1854.'' The 
. early debt had been incurred largely for State ex- 

penses.* In 1856, the Supreme Court of the State de- 
clared all the surplusage of indebtedness above the $300,000 limit 

' State and City Supplement of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, April 29, 
1893, p. 175. 

2 Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 600-01. 

' Acts of 31st Congress, ist Sess., chap. XLix, approved September 9, 1850 (9 U.S. 
Stat, at Large, p. 446). Tenth Censtis, vol. vn, p. 601. 

* State and City Supplement of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, April 29, 
1893, p. 176. 

' Acts of 33d Congress, 2d Sess., chap, cxxix, approved February 28, 1855 (10 
U.S. Stats, at Large, p. 617.) See Laws of Texas (1855-56), chap. l. For laws of Texas 
passed to settle debt, see Laws of Texas (1849-50), chap. CLVu; ibid. (1851-52), 
chaps. L, xcvm, cv. Various subsequent provisions were made for the same purpose. 

° Tenth Censtts, vol. vn, p. 601. 

' Bankers' Magazine and Statistical Register, December, 1854, p. 488. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 644. 



STATE BONDS II3 

fixed by the Constitution of 1849 null and void.^ In April, 1857, 
the legislature passed an act ^ calling in the various illegal issues 
and authorizing $3,900,00x3 new bonds to be exchanged for the 
old. In April, i860, another act * was passed authorizing $200,000 
additional bonds to adjust an error in the original refunding. 

The third period of difficulties with state bonds — from the 
time of the Civil War down to the early nineties — may be called 
the true period of repudiation. It is concerned only Third period 
with the Southern States.* The causes of the de- °omprom'ise 
faults and repudiations of most of the Southern or repudiation 
States during this period were in part the same and in part differ- 
ent from the causes of the earliest defaults discussed above. There 
was the same lack of understanding of the proper purposes for 
which state debts should be created and the same inadequate idea 
of the proper management of state finances. There was in addition 
the weakening of the South by the Civil War. Before the war, 
the Southern States, as a whole, were wealthy and prosperous. 
In i860, the total assessed valuation of Virginia, North Carolina, 
South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama, Mississippi, Louisiana, 
Arkansas, Tennessee, and Missouri was $4,332,901,458, and in 
1880 the total assessed valuation of the same States, with the 
addition of West Virginia, was $2,232,790,584.^ This was partly 
owing to the removal of slaves from the list of taxable property 
and partly owing to a general undervaluation of property.^ There 
was, however, a real loss from the point of view of raising taxes. 

In addition to the economic weakening of the South on account 
of the war, there was in most of the States so-called "carpet-bag" 
government with all its incompetency and dishonesty. As far as 

* Nougues V. Douglass et al., 7 Cal. 65. Constitution of California (1849), art. 
vni. 

* Statutes of California (1857), chap, ccxuv, approved April 28, 1857. 
" Ibid, (i860), chap, cccixm, approved April 30, i860. 

* The Fourteenth Amendment, section 4, of the Constitution of the United States, 
ratified by three fourths of the States before the close of 1868, reads: "But neither 
the United States, nor any State shall assume or pay any debt or obligation incurred 
in aid of insurrection or rebellion against the United States, or any claim for the loss 
or emancipation of any slave; but all such debts, obligations, and claims shall be held 
illegal and void." 

" Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 4 and 16. 

' See the Tenth Census, vol. vn, for estimated true values of property in the given 
States in i860 and 1880. 



114 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

misappropriations go, these have been referred to as not exceed- 
ing $20,000,000.^ The irregularities in the handling of state debts 
were so numerous and so complicated, however, that it is impos- 
sible to estimate with any accuracy the losses from this source. In 
this period Virginia, North Carolina, South Carolina, Georgia, 
Florida, Alabama, Tennessee, Louisiana, Arkansas, and Missouri 
defaulted in interest or compromised or repudiated the principal 
of their bonds, and Virginia and West Virginia began the dispute 
about West Virgioia's share of the ante-Civil War debt of Virginia. 
Some of the States for many years were in a condition of chronic 
default. 

Virginia defaulted in interest July i, 1861.* Previous to the 
Civil War, the State had met every liability for principal and 

interest "faithfully and promptly." The debt, con- 

tracted chiefly for railroads, canals, turnpikes, and 
public buildings, was described later as "free from the taint of 
extravagance, fraud, or doubt." ' On July i, 1867, after settling 
for the back interest with new bonds, the State resumed cash 
interest payments at the rate of 4% and issued coupons or cred- 
ited registered holders for the remainder of interest due. 

January i, 1869, the State again defaulted.* The property of 
the people was much reduced, and the task of raising revenue 
under the conditions left by the war was not an easy one.® By 
January i, 1871, the debt, through accimaulations of interest, 
had mounted to $47,390,839.96.® To meet the situation, the legis- 
lature passed the Funding Bill of 1871.^ This provided that for 
one third of the old debt and interest, except the 5% dollar bonds 
and the sterling bonds,* a certificate should be issued payable in 
accordance with the settlement made between Virginia and West 
Virginia and that for the other two thirds there should be issued 

' North American Remew, August, 1884, p. 141. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 13, p. 139. 

' North American Review, February, 1882, p. 150. Commercial and Financial 
Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 360; vol. 14, p. 175. 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 13, p. 139. 

' North American Remew, February, 1882, p. 151. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 360. 

' Acts of Virginia (1870-71), chap. 282. 

' The s% dollar bonds were funded in the same way, but with new s% bonds in- 
stead of 6%; and the sterling bonds were treated, with certain adjustments, on the 
same basis. 



STATE BONDS IIS 

new 6% bonds payable in thirty-four years. The coupons on the 
new or "consolidated" bonds were to be receivable for taxes and 
other dues. Under this act there was exchanged something Kke 
two thirds of the old debt.^ 

Then a new spirit came over Virginia's dreams. The so-called 
"Readjusters" appeared upon the scene.'' In December, 1871, 
they put through the legislature a resolution for discontinuing 
the funding of the state debt.' The State failed to pay interest 
due in January, 1872, although there were sufficient funds in the 
Treasury.* The claim was made that the people were too poor to 
take care of the debt — a claim hardly borne out by facts.^ March 
7, 1872, the legislature passed over the governor's veto an act * 
repealing the receivability of coupons for taxes and other public 
dues. The legislature also agreed to pay 4% interest to holders 
of the "consolidated" bonds who acquiesced in the repeal of the 
tax-receivable feature of the coupons.^ This was the origin of the 
class of bonds known as "pealers." * The Supreme Court of Ap- 
peals of Virginia, however, held that the State must receive the 
coupons for taxes.® 

The panic of 1873 prostrated business and diminished the reve- 
nues of the State. ^^ In 1874, Governor Kemper in a message to the 
General Assembly declared the State imable to fulfill all the con- 
ditions of the Fimding Act of 1871.^^ Default was made in interest 
January, 1874.^^ In 1879, the legislature passed an act known as 
the McCulloch Bill,^* which provided for refunding a part of the 
debt with new bonds bearing 3% interest for ten years, 4% for 
twenty years, and 5% for ten years. The coupons from these 
bonds were to be receivable for taxes. This act was acceptable to 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 14, p. 151. Up to December i, 1871, 
$21,610,691 consols were issued. (Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 557.) 

* North American Review, February, 1882, p. i$i. 

• Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 13, p. 839. 

• Ibid., vol. 14, pp. SI and 175. ° lUd., vol. 14, p. 175. 
' Acts of Assembly (1871-72), chap. 148. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 14, p. 323. 

' See American Law Review, vol. xxm, p. 927. 

' Antoni v. Wright, 22 Gratt., 833. 

'" North American Review, February, 1882, p. 152. 

'1 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 18, p. 350. 

" Ibid., vol. 18, p. 598. 

" Acts af Virginia, (1878-79, Special Session), chap. 24. 



no AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

creditors, and under it a portion of the debt was exchanged for 
new " ten-forty dollar bonds." ^ 

Later, the political complexion of the Government changed, 
refimding ceased, and interest on the "ten-forties" was defaulted.* 
In 1880, the Supreme Court of Appeals of the State held the Mc- 
Culloch law constitutional and the coupons receivable in full for 
taxes.' The "Readjusters" triumphed, however, in 1882 with the 
enactment of two laws known as the "Coupon-Eallers"* — the 
effect of which as interpreted was to prevent the receipt of any 
large amount of coupons for taxes — and a law known as the 
Riddleberger Act ' for the settlement of the debt. This act, after 
leaving to West Virginia provision for one third of the old debt 
(1861) or its equivalent, provided for scaling various classes of 
the remainder from 20% to 47%. 

For many years, the bonds issued under this act were the only 
bonds of the State receiving interest in cash. The "consols" re- 
ceived no interest in cash and the "pealers" no interest at all from 
1874, and the "ten-forties" received no cash interest after July, 
1880.^ The bondholders made various unsuccessful attempts to 
obtain satisfactory terms.^ Finally, in 1891, after several months 
of negotiations, the bondholders and the representatives of the 
State arrived at a basis of settlement.* After certain adjustments, 
the principal and interest of the state debt July i, 1891, was de- 
termined to be $28,616,972.98. The "Olcott Plan," allowing for 
a certain amount of bonds as probably lost, assumed the debt to 
be in round numbers $28,000,000.® In exchange for this, it pro- 
posed to issue $19,000,000 new bonds payable in one hundred 
years and bearing 2% interest for ten years and 3% for ninety 
years. The coupons were not to be receivable for taxes. The 
different classes of bonds fxmded were to receive new "century" 

' Up to October i, 1879, there were issued of these $8,049^4.50. {Tenth Census, 
vol. vn, p. 559.) 

' Seventh Annual Report, Council of the Coiporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
p. 66. 

' Williamson !i. Massey, 33 Gratt. 237. 

* Acts of Assembly (1881-82), chaps. 7 and 41. See Parsons v. Maiye and others, 
23 Fed. Rep. 113 (Circuit Court, E. D. Virginia, Feb. 11, 1885). 

^ Acts of Assembly (1881-82), chap. 84, approved February 14, 1882. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 56, p. 636. 

' See ibid., vol. 44, p. 627. ' Ibid., vol. S7, p. S^S- ' tti^-t vol. 56, p. 636. 



STATE BONDS II7 

bonds in proportions varying from 60% to 75% of principal 
with similar adjustments for interest. This plan was embodied 
in an act approved February 20, 1892.^ In December, 1893, Gov- 
ernor McEonney stated that $24,547,358 old bonds had been re- 
ceived in exchange for new bonds and canceled. Four semiaimual 
interest payments had been met promptly.^ Later, the reduction 
of the debt was begun through purchases of bonds for the sinking 
fund.* The debt history of Virginia since the Civil War has been 
a checkered one. 

The constitution of West Virginia, adopted in 1863, provided 
that West Virginia should assume an "equitable portion" of the 
public debt of Virginia as it was before January i, v- • • 

1861.* Later negotiations for an adjustment of the 
debt were begim between the two States.^ March 30, 187 1, the 
legislature of Virginia passed a fimding bill® which provided, 
among other things, that one third of the old Virginia debt should 
be fimded with certificates payable in accordance with the settle- 
ment thereafter made between the two States. Virginia claimed 
that $15,239,370.74 properly was chargeable to West Virginia on 
the grovmd that the new State contained one third of the terri- 
tory and population of the old State.^ West Virginia, on the 
other hand, claimed that her share was not over $953,360.23 on 
the basis of the net amounts expended and invested in her terri- 
tory up to January i, 186 1.* The negotiations dragged on for 
years.* 

In March, 191 1, however, the United States Supreme Court 
held West Virginia liable for a principal debt of $7,182,507.46 and 

1 Acts of Assembly (1891-92), chap. 325, as amended by Acts of Assembly (1893- 
94), chap, no, and by Acts of Assembly (1897-98), chaps. 113 and 287. See Com- 
mercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 56, p. 802; vol. S7, p. 1053. The time for accept- 
ing the Olcott settlement was extended from time to time until December 31, 19 14, 
with authority given to the sinking-fund commissioners to extend one year more. 
(State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, November 21, 1914, 
p. 169.) 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. S7, p. 1053. ' Ibid., vol. 58, p. 357. 

* Constitution of West Virginia (1863), ayt. vnc, sec. 8. 
' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 564. 

' Acts of Virginia (1870-71), chap. 282. 

' International Review, November, 1880, p. 568. Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 564-65. 

• Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 565. 

' See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 56, p. 637; vol. 58, pp. 51 and 444. 



Il8 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

left the question of interest for adjustment between the parties.^ 
The commissioners of the two States again failed to agree.^ In 
June, 1914, the United States Supreme Court ordered a special 
master to take additional testimony.* On June 14, 1915, the court 
sustained in practically every particular the findings of the mas- 
ter. Allowing for a net credit to West Virginia as of January i, 
1861, of $2,966,885.18 and adding to the principal of the debt 
$8,178,307.22 for interest up to July i, 1915, the court held the 
total amoimt due by West Virginia as $12,393,929.50. The court 
ordered a charge of 5% interest on the total amoimt awarded by 
the decree from the date of entry vmtil the debt be paid. It 
ordered costs divided evenly between the two States. Whether 
the legislature of West Virginia settles in accordance with the 
decision of the Supreme Court remains to be seen.* 

In 1868, North Carolina settled the back interest on all but its 
Civil War debt with new 6% bonds.* The debt had been contracted 
„ , „ ,. largely for railroads.® Some of the efforts to give aid 

North Carolina i i i. , , . t ■. 

resulted dis£istrously, and m other cases the agents 
of the State wasted the fimds.^ Governor Caldwell in 187 1 de- 
clared that for many of the "special tax" bonds, issued in exchange 
for railroad and canal stock, the State received only from ten to 
thirty cents in currency on the dollar, and for certain raibroad-aid 
bonds, less than fifty cents in specie.® October i, 1876, the total 
debt of the State was given as $41,846,930.45. Of this, over 
$13,000,000 was impaid interest.^ 

Governor Vance, in a message to the general assembly in 1879, 
claimed that the State was under no moral obligation to pay the 
debt at face value. He said: "Quite one haK of our property upon 
which our bonds were based, was wantonly destroyed by consent 
of a large majority of those who held them. . . ." He declared 
that practically all the special tax bonds were "not binding either 

* Virginia v. West Virginia, 220 U.S. 1; 31 S.C. 330; SS L-E. 353. 

' See Virginia j?. West Virginia, 231 U.S. 89; 34 S.C. 29; 58 L.E. 135. 

* Virginia v. West Virginia, 234 U.S. 117. For suromary of report of Master, see 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. loo, p. 414. 

* See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 100, p. 2099. 

5 Ibid., vol. 6, p. 748. " Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 567. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 263. 
' Ibid., vol. 13, pp. 740-41; vol. 17, p. 803. 
' Ilrid., vol. 23, p. S99- 



STATE BONDS II9 

in law or good morals." ^ An amendment to the State Constitu- 
tion ^ was adopted and ratified later by popular vote forbidding 
payment of the following bonds unless the proposal to pay them 
shaU have been ratified by a majority of aU the voters of the 
State: special tax bonds, $11,366,000; Chatham Railroad bonds, 
$1,030,000; Williamston and Tarboro Railroad bonds, $150,000; 
penitentiary bonds of 1868, $44,000. These bonds still are un- 
paid.^ 

In 1879, the legislature also passed fimding laws ^ providing 
substantially as follows: (i) for the issue of 4% bonds due in 1910 
to fimd ante-war bonds at 40% of face value, railroad bonds 
recognized as vaUd at 25% of face value, and funding bonds of 
1866 and 1868 at 15% of face value, nothing being given for over- 
due coupons; (2) for the issue of 6% bonds due in 1919 in exchange 
for North Carolina railroad construction bonds at par, holders 
of construction bonds abating $240 of overdue interest on each 
$1000 bond. Various attempts have been made since to enforce 
payment of the special tax bonds.^ In 1905, as the result of a de- 
cision by the United States Supreme Court,* settlement was made 
for a smaU amount of bonds secured by stock of the North Caro- 
lina Railroad.^ In 1913, the legislature passed an act ^ authoriz- 
ing the payment of a small amount of unfunded bonds in cash at 
fifteen, twenty-five, and forty cents on the dollar of principal on 
the basis of the Fxmding Act of 1879. The debt history of North 
Carolina shows the unfortunate results of a heavy debt incurred 
to a considerable extent without value received. 

During the CivU War, South Carolina became in arrears in in- 
terest.' March 23, 1869, an act ^^ was passed to pro- „ , ^ ,. 

, , , 1 ,1 ■ r . . 1) A^i • South Carolina 

Vide for the conversion of state securities. Ihis 

1 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 69. 
'' Constitution of North Carolina (1868, as amended 1879), art i, sec. 6. 
' Thirty^inth Annual Report, Council o£ the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
p. 366. 

* Laws of North Carolina (1879), chaps. 98 and 138. 

' See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 85, p. 1100; vol. 86, p. 121; vol. 90, 
p. 249; vol. 92, pp. 477 and 610. 
' South Dakota v. North Carolina, 192 U.S. 286 (1904). 
' See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 80, p. 1382. 
8 PMic Laws of North Carolina (1913), chap. 131. Cf. ibid. (1879), chap. 98. 

• Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 13, p. 622, 
'I" Acts of South Carolina (1868-69), no. 159. 



I20 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

act provided for funding the old debt and interest with new securi- 
ties bearing the same rates of interest as the old. The state debt 
history of South Carolina goes back to 1794 and includes the issue 
of bonds in aid of banks and railroads.^ After the Civil War, the 
State suffered xmder an extreme example of "carpet-bag" gov- 
ermnent.^ Much of the State's money was stolen or wasted.* 
Apparently bonds were issued largely in excess of the amoimts 
authorized by law, and railroad securities were endorsed on a 
wholesale scale. According to a report of a committee of the legis- 
lature during the session of 1871-72, there had been created 
direct and contingent UabiUties amoimting to $28,977,608.20 for 
the existence of a large part of which no adequate reason could be 
given. The State was declared to be virtually bankrupt.* In 
January, 1872, the State again defaulted ia interest.® 

In 1873,* the legislature passed an "act to reduce the voliune 
of the public debt and to provide for the payment of the same." ^ 
This act declared void $5,965,000 bonds issued for the conversion 
of the State debt, on the ground that these were put on the mar- 
ket without authority of law. It provided further that the re- 
mainder of the debt should be funded at fifty per cent of its face 
value and interest from 1872 into new 6% "green consols." Up 
to October 31, 1875, there had been funded, under the Act of 
1873, $7,220,512.65 of the old debt.* 

At various times, up to 1877, interest on all or a part of the 
debt was ia default.' Legislative investigating committees ia 
1877 reported $3,608,707 treasury vouchers issued without proper 

• Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 297. 

' Ibid., vol. 13, pp. 622-23. International Review, November, 1880, pp. 576-77. 

' The liberality of the I^islature to itself and its friends extended at one time to 
having fitted up a room in the State House wherein to serve "wines, liquors, eatables, 
and cigars to state officials, senators, members of the House and their friends, at all 
hours of the day and night." (Report of the Joint Investigating Committee on Public 
Frauds, etc., 1877-78, quoted in Scott, The Repudiation of State Debts [New York 
and Boston, 1893], Appendix vi, p. 314.) 

* Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 572. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 18, p. 317. 

' The governor in a message referred to the debt of the State, October 31, 1873, 
as $15,851,627.35. Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 574. 

' Ads of South Carolina (Special Session, 1873), no. 427. 

' Tenth Cemus, vol. vn, p. 575. 

» See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 21, pp. 224, 231, 535, 614; vol. 33, 
p. 57; vol. 24, p. 445. 



STATE BONDS 121 

legal authority and the overissue of $1,000,000 of a loan for the 
payment of interest on the public debt. March 22, 1878, there 
was established by joint resolution a court of claims, with the 
idea of trying to straighten out the state finances.^ In 1879, the 
Supreme Court of the State declared illegal certain bonds in- 
cluded in the refunding under the Act of 1873.'' Invalidity was 
discovered to a considerable extent among the "green consols."^ 

The final adjustment took place imder an act approved Decem- 
ber 24, 1879, and amended February 20, 1880.^ All valid "green 
consols" and valid portions were exchangeable at par with in- 
terest to July I, 1878, for new "brown bonds" printed from the 
same plates.^ A writer in the "International Review" in 1880 
held that South Carolina had the best excuse for repudiation of 
aU of the States.* 

An act ^ was passed in 1871 "to protect the people of the State 
of Georgia against the illegal and fraudulent issues of bonds. ..." 
Under authority of the state constitution of 1868, 
endorsements of railroad bonds were permitted for 
not over one half the cost of the road and provided that the State 
should have a first lien on the property.* Accordingly, up to March 
16, 187 1, the State had endorsed $5,923,000 railroad bonds.® Fur- 
thermore, imder the rule of the "carpet-baggers," Georgia was 
plunged into debt for all sorts of alleged public improvements. 
Later, claims were made of the issue of bonds in excess of the 
amount provided by law, of fraud, and of other irregularities.^" 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. S7&-77. Acts of South Carolina (1877-78), Joint Reso- 
lution no. 99, p. 669. 

2 Walker v. State of Soutli Carolina, 12 S.C. 200 (1879). 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 18. 

* Acts of South Carolina (1879), no. 186. Ibid. (1880, Extra Session), no. 224. 

6 December 19, 1904, the United States Supreme Court aflSrmed the decision of 
the United States Circuit Court in the case of Lee v. Robinson and declared the 
revenue bond scrip of this State to be void. (196 U.S. 64.) Under Act of March 2, 
1872, $1,800,000 of this scrip had been issued. (Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 
vol. 80, p. 725.) The act was passed over the veto of the governor, March 2, 1872. 
(Acts of South Carolina [1871-72], no. 65.) 

' International Review, November, 1880, p. 576. 

' Georgia Laws (1871-72), no. s- 

8 Constitution of Georgia (1868), art. in, sec. vi, sub-sec. $. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 360. 

" Lalor's Cyclopiedia of Political Science (Chicago, 1884), vol. m, p. 606. See Pre- 
amble of Georgia Laws (1871-72), no. $. 



122 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The legislature in 1872 declared void $3,982,000 state bonds 
and state endorsements of $4,475,000 railroad bonds.^ An amend- 
ment ^ to the constitution in 1877 provided that numerous issues 
of bonds never should be paid. The principal of the defaulted debt 
of Georgia in 1912, according to the Coimcil of the Corporation of 
Foreign Bondholders, was $12,757,000.^ In justice to Georgia, it 
must be said that, while her resources probably were sufEident 
to take care of her entire debt,^ she suffered in common with other 
Southern States through incompetent and dishonest government 
in the Reconstruction period.^ 

Beginning in 1823, Alabama issued its bonds in aid of banks and 
other private enterprises. In the early forties, interest on the 
state debt was met promptly, though with difficulty. 
After November, 1861, interest payable in New 
York was defaulted, but interest due in London was paid regu- 
larly to January, 1865. Later, the unpaid interest on bonds issued 
both in London and in New York was settled with new bonds. A 
similar settlement was made for the principal of bonds which 
matured in 1863, 1865, and 1866.® 

In 1867 and 1868, the legislature passed acts ^ providing for 
state endorsement of railroad bonds under certain conditions. 
Under this general authority, endorsements were made for $19,- 
006,000. The State also issued $2,300,000 direct bonds for rail- 
roads.* July, 1872, the State defaulted in interest on bonds and 
endorsements in aid of the Alabama and Chattanooga Railroad.' 
The road had become bankrupt." In 1873, an act ^^ was approved 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 15, p. 411. Georgia Laws (1872), 
nos. I, 2, 3, 4, 5. 

* Georgia Constitution (1868), art. 3, sec. 6, as amended May i, 1877. 

' Thirty-ninth Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
p. 366. 

' Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 31, 1875, p. iv. 
International Review, November, 1880, p. 578. 

' See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 19, p. 375. Lalor's Cydopcedia of 
Political Science, vol. in, p. 606. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 590-92. 

' 4cto o//4/a6omo (1866-67), no. 641, as amended by iJii. (1868), p. i7;fW(i. (1868), 
no. 3. See also ibid. (1869-70), no. 142. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 593. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 15, p. 14. 

" Ibid., vol. 13, p. 739. 

" Acts of Alabama (1872-73), no. 21, approved April 21, 1873. 



STATE BONDS 1 23 

providing for the issue of state bonds in place of state endorse- 
ments in the ratio of one to four. The new bonds were to mature 
in thirty years and bear 7% interest. The State settled with some 
of the railroad companies on this basis.^ 

In Jvme, 1875, the debt of Alabama was estimated as $31,952,- 
000.30, of which $9,691,000 was contingent railroad debt, $4,- 
696,407 past-due interest, and $2,500,000 estimated floating 
debt.^ The taxable property of the State at this time was about 
$159,000,000.' The State was described as in a condition of 
"practical insolvency." This was held to be due to the bad effects, 
of the war, loss of crops, and loose state and coimty administra- 
tions. A Southern newspaper blamed the bondholders for sup- 
porting Congress in fastening on the people "that thieving crew'" 
who voted away the State's credit "by the cart-load." * 

By an act ^ passed in 1876, the debt was "adjusted" to not 
over $9,668,423.® There were authorized $7,000,000 new bonds, 
bearing interest at 2% for the first five years, 3% for the next five,, 
4% for the next ten, and 5% for the final ten years; $1,000,000. 
bearing interest at 2% for the first five years and 4% for the next 
twenty-five; and $596,000 bearing 5% from the beginning. For 
the old general direct debt bearing 5%, 6%, and 8% interest, the- 
new 2%, 3%, 4%, and 5% bonds were given dollar for dollar with- 
out any allowance for interest; for the 7% state bonds issued in 
the ratio of one to four for endorsed railroad bonds, the new 
5% bonds were given at the rate of fifty cents on the dollar of 
principal, together with a waiver of certain impaid taxes. In ex- 
change for the endorsed bonds of the Alabama and Chattanooga 
Railroad, amounting to $5,300,000, there were given the $1,000,000. 
bonds bearing 2% for five years and 4% for twenty-five years; 
for the $2,000,000 state bonds issued direct to the railroad, the 
State released its hen on the road and transferred 500,000 acres 
of land.' There are at present defaulted loans of the State of 

* Tenth Censits, vol. vn, p. 593. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 20, p. 582. ' IhU., vol. 21, p. 276. 

* Ibid., vol. 20, p. 582. ' Acts of Alabama (1875-76), no. 38. 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. S9S- See also Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 
23, p. 622. 

' See Third Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
pp. 21-22; Fourth Report, pp. 12-17, and Fifth Report, pp. lo-ii. Tenth Census, vol. 
vn, pp. S94-9S- 



124 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Alabama, but there are no available records of their amount and 
character.^ 

Tennessee issued bonds in aid of banks as early as 1832. The 
State also issued bonds, from time to time, in aid of railroad and 
turnpike companies. In April, 1865, the total state 
liabiUties, including endorsements but not including 
war debt, were given as nearly $20,000,000. Small portions of the 
principal of the state debt had matured from 186 1 to 1864 and had 
not been paid. The revenues of the State in 1865 were insufficient 
to pay current expenses and interest on the debt. A large portion 
of the railroad companies to whom bonds were issued did not pay 
the interest. From time to time these roads were sold and the 
proceeds applied to pajnnent of the bonds.^ In 1865, provision 
was made for paying all past-due bonds and interest.' 

In 1866, $5,958,000 additional state bonds were authorized in 
aid of railroads. The July, 1868, interest on the debt was not met. 
In 1868, interest was fxmded. July i, 1869, the total liabilities of 
the State were $39,896,504.55. Of this debt a considerable portion 
was taken care of through sale of state interests in railroads.* 
March 17, 1873, an act^ was approved to fimd the legally issued 
bonds and coupons of the State with new 6% bonds. 

The July, 1875, interest was not paid.* The State had difficulty 
in collecting taxes.^ In 1879, the governor of the State said that 
it had been able to pay only three installments of interest in ten 
years. He reported the debt, including interest, as $24,274,017.* 
An act, approved March 28, 1879, for funding the debt at fifty 
cents on the dollar with new 4% bonds, was rejected by popular 
vote.^ In 1881, an act was passed funding the debt at par with 
new 3% bonds, but this act was declared imconstitutional by the 
Supreme Court of the State.^" In 1882, an act was passed funding 
the debt at 60% of the principal and interest with new bonds 

' Thirtyninth Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
P- 365- 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 604-05. ' Acts of Tennessee (1865-66), chap. K. 

* Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 605-06. ' Acts of Tennessee (1873), diap. xxiv. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 21, p. 87. 

' Ibid., vol. 21, p. 614. ' Ibid., vol. 28, p. 44. 

' Seventh Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
p. 60. 

" Acts of Tennessee (i88i), chap, cixxm. Lynn tr. Polk, 76 Tenn. 121 (1881). 



STATE BONDS 125 

bearing 3% interest for two years, 4% for two years, 5% for two 
years, and 6% for twenty-four years.^ In 1883, the state treasurer 
absconded leaving a large deficit. The legislature thereupon re- 
pudiated the settlement and stopped the payment of the January 
coupons.^ 

In the same year the legislature passed an act ' scaling certain 
portions of the debt 24%, 21%, and 20%, and funding these por- 
tions with bonds bearing 6%, $}{%, and 5% respectively, and 
scaHng practically all the rest of the debt 50% and funding it at 
3% interest. Under an act of 1905,* all unfunded bonds, except 
$335)666.66 held by the United States Government, were elimi- 
nated from the state debt as of January, 1907. 

In the case of Teimessee, there was no reasonable doubt about 
the validity of most of its bonds.^ Like many others, the State 
incurred a large debt — sometimes for purposes of doubtful value. 
The State had a good many misfortimes, including war]and yellow 
fever. The condition of the Southern States at one time, according 
to the " Conunercial and Financial Chronicle," * called for forbear- 
ance. At the same time the treatment of their debts was not such 
as to inspire the confidence of investors. 

Since the Civil War, Louisiana has had a debt history somewhat 
similar to the debt histories of other Southern States. The early 
debt of the State included bonds issued for railroads . . 
and liabilities incurred in aid of banks and munici- 
palities.'' In 1866, the state auditor referred to the great decrease 
in taxable property since the Civil War, to the difiiculty of col- 
lecting taxes, and to the fact that state currency was receivable 
for public dues.^ The legislature of 1866 authorized $997,300 
bonds to pay certain bonds and coupons past due. 

* Ads of Tennessee (1881-83, 3d Extra Session, 426 General Assembly), chap. 

4. P- 6- 

' Tenth Annual Report, Councfl of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, p. 92. 
See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 36, p. 170. Acts of Tennessee (1883), 
chaps, n, iv. 

' Acts of Tennessee (1883), chap. Lxxxiv, p. 76. • Ibid. (1905), chap. 393. 

' International Remew, November, 1880, p. 585. See Lalor's Cyclopcedia of Political 
Science, vol. in, p. 610. 

« See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 27, and vol. 29, p. 82. 

' See Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 597. For certain interesting phases of early his- 
tory, see North American Review, January, 1844, pp. 137-40. 

8 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 4, p. 233. 



126 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

From 1867 to 1871, large amounts of bonds were issued for levees 
and in aid of railroads and canals.^ In 1871, certain taxpayers 
issued a warning that the legislature was exceeding its powers.^ 
The total liabilities of the State January i, 1872, amoimted to 
$41,733,752.' A considerable amoimt of overdue interest was 
paid in 1873. Later, a committee of seven citizens appointed by 
the governor reported against the validity of a large part of the 
debt, and claimed that for a portion of the remainder the State 
had received only from thirty to fifty cents on the dollar.^ In 
September, 1874, owing to misgovermnent and impending bank- 
ruptcy, the Federal authorities placed General Emory tempo- 
rarily in charge of the State Government and property.' 

January 24, 1874, a fimding act * had been passed providing for 
an issue of "consolidated bonds of the State of Louisiana," pay- 
able forty years from January i, 1874, and to bear 7% interest. 
These bonds were to be exchanged for all valid bonds at the rate of 
sixty cents on the dollar. Under the same date, another act ' was 
passed proposing a constitutional amendment to declare the new 
consolidated bonds a valid contract between the State and the 
holders of the bonds. May 17, 1875, Governor Kellogg, who had 
returned to power, signed an act * supplemental to the fxmding 
act. The new law declared $14,320,000 bonds, issued mostly for 
levees and railroads, "questioned and doubtful." The bonds were 
to be passed upon by the courts. Under these acts, there were 
funded up to the close of 1878 old bonds amounting to $19,874,666.' 

January i, 1879, the State again defaulted in interest.^" The debt 
ordinance " of the new constitution of the State, adopted July 

' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 598. 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 12, p. 403. 
' Tenth Census, vol. vn, p. 598. 

* ComTnercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 18, p. 62. ' Ibid., vol. 19, p. 283. 

" Laws of Louisiana (1874, 3d Leg., 2d Sess.), no. 3. ' Ibid., no. 4. 

' Ibid, (187s, Extra Sess.), no. 11. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 20, 
p. S2I. 

' Sixth Annual Report, Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, p. 34. 
On a portion of the new bonds, the State was in default July i, 1874, July i, 1875, 
and July i, 1876. 

"> Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 42. Defaults also in 1877 and 
1878. (Scott, p. 115.) 

" Constitution of Louisiana (1879), art. 1 of debt ordinance. See Laws of Louisi- 
ana (1884), pp. 74 and 77. 



STATE BONDS IVJ 

23, 1879, reduced the interest on the consoKdated bonds to 2% 
for five years from January i, 1880, 3% for fifteen years, and 4% 
thereafter. Holders of the consolidated bonds were given the 
option of exchanging them at the rate of seventy-five cents on the 
dollar for new bonds bearing interest at the rate of 4%. This 
action, together with the repudiation of various issues of bonds, 
was Justified by those who carried it out on the grounds that at 
one time the State House had been seized by United States sol- 
diers, that the body of men that passed the funding act of 1874 
was not a constitutional legislature, and that the bondholders 
were mainly Northern capitalists.^ In June, 1882, an amendment 
was passed, and later ratified by the people, fixing interest on the 
consolidated bonds at 2% for five years from January i, 1880, 
and 4% thereafter.^ The Supreme Court of the United States in 
March, 1883, held that whether or not the debt ordinance violated 
the contract of 1874 and therefore was tmconstitutional, there was 
no remedy.' The Council of the Corporation of Foreign Bond- 
holders in 1912 listed $5,627,160 Louisiana bonds the principal of 
which was in default.'* 

The only other State to be discussed in connection with defaults 
is Missouri. This State was in default in interest on its railroad 
debt from 1861 to 1867. In the early fifties, Missouri 
had loaned its credit on a liberal scale for the con- 
struction of railroads. In 1859, i860, and 1861, nearly all the 
railroads which had debts guaranteed by the State defaulted. 
The State became directly responsible for obligations amounting 
to $23,701,000, in addition to its previous debt of about $1,000,000. 
Later, much of the railroad property was destroyed. Furthermore, 
during the Civil War, the State was obliged to incur large addi- 
tional indebtedness for military purposes. The state debt proper 
and the new military debt were taken care of promptly as regards 
interest; and by the end of the war, the principal of the military 
debt had been considerably reduced. On January i, 1865, the 

' Lalor's Cyclopcedia of Political Science, vol. in, p. 606. 

^ Amendment ratified April 22, 1884. See Laws of Louisiana (1882), no. 76, and 
ibid. (1884), p. 77. 

' Louisiana v. jumel, 107 U.S. 711. New Hampshire v. Louisiana, 108 U.S. 76. 

* Thirty-ninth Annttal Report, Coimdl of the Corporation of Foreign Bondholders, 
p. 366. 



128 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

aggregate state debt was $36,094,908, of which $24,754,000 repre- 
sented railroad bonds which the State had guaranteed and old 
state bonds issued prior to the Civil War.^ 

In 1867, the legislature passed an act ^ authorizing a tax of four 
mills to be applied to the credit of the state interest fund, and 
providing that certain sums received from the United States be 
applied to the payment of overdue coupons. The act also provided 
for the issue of six per cent funding bonds for the remaining over- 
due coupons. In 1874, a further fimding act ' provided for $1,000,- 
000 six per cent twenty-year funding bonds to be used from time 
to time to pay maturing bonds. So vigorously did Missouri go 
about the work of paying its debt that by January i, 1869, the 
total debt had been reduced to $21,675,000 and by January i, 
1885, to $15,243,000. The debt history of Missoiui is a troubled 
but an honorable one. 

In the matter of debt histories, mention may be made of three 

other States. In 1840 to 1842, the solvency of New York State 

was "in great jeopardy." The State had made loans 

Summary of a J f J 

state debt to raihoads and incurred a large debt for canals. In 

"^" ' 1841, Ohio had great difficulty in borrowing money 

to continue work on its system of internal improvements. Both 
these States, however, always managed to pay promptly interest 
and principal of their debts. Massachusetts, during the Civil War, 
when gold was at a premium, agreed to pay interest and principal 
of all scrip and bonds in gold or silver coin.* AH the other States 
of the Union, according to our information, have clear records 
for the payment of their debts. The States with longer histo- 
ries have had more chances to get into trouble than the yoimger 
States, and also have not always had others' mistakes to guide 
them. Repudiation has not been confined to the Southern States; 
though it must be said that the people of those States have shown, 
on the whole, much less responsibility in debt matters than 
the people of the North and West. This may be accounted 

' See Report, State Auditor of Missouri (1883-84), part n, pp. 40, 74 and 116, 
and Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. 636-37. 

' Act approved March 12, 1867 {Laws of Missouri I1867], p. 168), as amended by 
act approved March 25, 1868 {ibid. [i868, Adj. Sess.] p. 174). 

' Act approved March 30, 1874 {Laws of Missouri [1874], p. 169). 

* Tenth Census, vol. vn, pp. S37, 539, 614. 



STATE BONDS 129 

for partly by the large percentage of negro population in the 
South. 

Our study of the debt history of the States leads us to the con- 
clusion that debts too large compared with the property available 
for taxation or debts incurred for purposes not strictly 
public^ are dangerous. The people of a State are orVrdoubSff 
likely to refuse to pay when they feel unwilling to jangerour^ 
stand the burden of taxation necessary or when they 
feel that they have not had their money's worth for their bonds- 
The situation is greatly aggravated by the fact that there is no 
adequate legal remedy for bondholders. As long as the Eleventh 
Amendment stands, "a sovereign State possesses the royal right of 
snapping its fingers in its creditor's face." ^ However, people, even 
the most Ught-hearted in debt matters, are willing to pay their 
debts and maintain their credit when the debts have been justly 
incurred and when they have plenty of resources with which to pay. 

The experiences of our States in the creation and payment of 
debts have had the salutary effect of causing practically aU the 
States of the Union to place in their constitutions EjEperfence has 
debt provisions which are, on the whole, extremely caused practi- 
conservative. Just as our form of government, fed- states to Umit 
eral, state, and municipal, is largely the outgrowth stitutions state 
of our colonial experience in government, so the lim- ^ ^''^^ '^ 
itations in our state constitutions on the creation of debt by the 
States are the outgrowth of our early experience in debt-making. 

Four States, however (New Hampshire, Vermont, Massachu- 
setts, and Connecticut), have no constitutional hmitations what- 
ever on the creation of debt. These States have such „ 

, , Four States 

splendid financial records that the necessity of im- have no 
posing constitutional restrictions on the debt-making Umitations" 
power of the legislatures never has been strongly felt. 

The present constitutional provisions in regard to the debt- 

' There is developing at the present time in Canada an interesting situation and 
one which bears a striking resemblance to the situation in the United States before 
1840. The Dominion Government has guaranteed bonds of the Canadian Northern 
and Grand Trunk Pacific Railways. The situation of the companies is such that the 
Government may be called on to make good its guarantee and the economic and 
financial condition of Canada makes this problem full of interest. (See Boston Even* 
ing Transcript, January 11, 1915.) 

* Lalor's Cyclopcedia of Political Science, vol. m, p. 613. 



I30 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

creating power of the remaining States of the Union are grouped 
, ,. about five principal considerations: — 

Leading consti- ... . , ,. . . , 

tutionai provi- (i) Pemussion to Dorrow Without limit for the pur- 

sions governing ^ „. . . . • .. 

creation of posc of repelling mvasion, suppressmg insurrection, 
state debts ^^ defending the State in time of war. 

(2) Permission to borrow, usually limited to a small amount, 
for the purpose of meeting casual deficiencies in revenue. 

(3) Permission to borrow for some special purpose definitely 
stated in the act authorizing the loan, provided that arrange- 
ments are made in the act for paying the interest and prin- 
cipal of the bonds and provided in many cases that the act 
authorizing the loan is ratified by a vote of the people. 

(4) Permission to issue bonds or notes to refimd existing debt. 

(5) Prohibition against loaning the credit of the State to private 
enterprises, engaging in works of internal improvement, or 
loaning credit to political subdivisions. 

The above provisions may be said to be the standard constitu- 
tional arrangements about the creation of debts by States.^ 

The provision permitting unlimited borrowing in case of in- 
vasion, insurrection, or war obviously is necessary and advan- 
tageous. If a State cannot protect itself against 

Invasion, . » . ^ • ^ • 1 j j 

insurrection, mvasion, Or Cannot mamtam law and order, or even 
is imable to assist the National Government in time 
of need, its very existence is threatened. 

The provision allowing a State to issue bonds or notes up to a 
small amoimt to take care of casual deficiencies in revenue or 
defid n ^^^^ imcxpccted emergencies is simply precaution- 
cies and other ary. The amount which a State may borrow on this 
emergencies |ja,sis should be and usually is limited very strictly. 
These loans are in their very nature temporary and are paid 
usually out of revenues as received.^ 

' For examples of fairly representative constitutional debt provisions, see Constitu- 
tion of New York (1894), as amended, art. vn, sees. 1-4, as amended in November, 
1909, and art. vn, sec. 12; Constitution of Ohio (1851), as amended September, 1912, 
art. vm, sees. 1-5, and art. xn, sec. 6; Constitution of Virginia (1902), art. xin, sees. 
184, 185, and 187; Constitution of Utah (1895), as amended, art. xiv, sees, i, 2, and 
6; Constitution of California (1879), as amended, art. rv, sees. 22, 31; art. xn, see. 13; 
art. XVI, sec. i. 

* The constitution of Missouri (1875) provides that such loans shall be paid with- 
in two years. (Art. iv, sec. 44.) 



STATE BONDS 13 1 

The provision allowing a State to borrow for some definite piece 
of work, provided arrangements are made in the act for the pay- 
ment of the loan and provided the people approve „ ^^.^ j^^ 
the creation of the debt, is not foimd in all the state definite purpose 

..^ ,. -r. • 1 /■ • 1 when authorized 

constitutions. It is, however, a fairly common pro- by vote of the 
vision. It is imder this authority granted by its con- ^°^ * 
stitution that the State of New York has borrowed large sums on 
long-term bonds for highways and canals. It is a provision which 
in the case of any people not naturally careful about the creation 
of debt may be Uable to a good deal of abuse. 

Prohibition against using the credit of the State in aid of private 
enterprises, which is found in almost all the consti- „ , ., . . 

.,.,,. , r 1 1 • Prohibition 

tutions/ is the direct result of the early experience against loan- 
of the States in debt-making. "^ "^ 

In the constitutions of some of the States there are fovmd special 
provisions about the proportion of debt to assessed valuation, 
about the form of votes for authorizing debt, about ^ . , 

Special con- 

the length of time which bonds shall have to run, stitutionai 
and various other matters. Sometimes special pro- p'""^'""^ 
vision is made for specific issues of bonds, as in the case of Cali- 
fornia ^ for the Panama Pacific Exposition. 

The constitution of North Dakota * provides for the certifica- 
tion by the auditor and secretary of state on all state bonds that 
the same are issued pursuant to law and within the LegaUty 
debt limit. In view of the fact that a State may °f'^'"* 
refuse to pay its debt, whether legally issued or not, the question 
of legality is not as important in state bonds as in mimicipal 
bonds. It should, however, always be taken into consideration. 
This is attended to usually by obtaining the opinion of competent 
lawyers. 

A careful study of the constitutional provisions of all the 
States in regard to the creation and payment of debts Substantial 
shows a substantial agreement on what is sound creation and 
and wise. The provisions have almost a monotonous ^ta^^leto 
imiformity. 

> Contra, see Constitution of Rhode Island (1842), art. iv, sec. 13. 

' Constitution of California (1879), art. iv, sec. 22, as amended November 8, 1910. 

» Constitiaion of North Dakota (1889), art. xn, sec. 187. 



132 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

On the whole, the States of our Union, since the early days of 

the rage for so-called internal improvements and since the Civil 

War and carpet-bag periods in the South, have been 

Financial sta- ,. , r , , . , 

biiity depends exceedingly careful about creating and very consaen- 
e peop e ^-Jqus about paying debts. The frequent amendments 
to the constitutions of some of our Western and Southern States, 
however, show that in the last resort the only reliable safeguard 
against the creation of excessive debts is the disposition of the 
people themselves. 

Another important class of considerations in estimating the 
credit of our States is concerned with population. The amoimt of 
population and the increase of population in a State, 
thfstatef and ^s showing its size and growth, are important. Table 
£*same°"^^^ ^ (°^ pa^gc 133) gives the population in 1900 and in 
1910 and the percentage of increase from 1900 to 
1910 of all our States.^ 

Table A shows the greatest percentage of increase in population 
in the States of North Dakota, Oklahoma, Idaho, Nevada, and 
Washington and the smallest percentage of increase in New Hamp- 
shire, Vermont, Iowa, and Missouri. The credit of the respective 
States mentioned, however, shows how dangerous is the taking of 
any one factor by itself as decisive in determining the credit of 
a State. 

The character of the population is a far better test of credit. 
Population Table B (on page 134) shows the percentage of white, 
by color uegro, and all other races to total population in all 

our States in 1900 and 1910.* 

Table B shows the States of Maine, New Hampshire, Vermont, 
Michigan, Wisconsin, Mionesota, Iowa, and Nebraska all with a 
population 99% or over white. On the other hand, it shows the 
States of South Carolina and Mississippi with a white population 
of less than 45% of the whole; the States of Georgia, Florida, Ala- 
bama, and Louisiana with a white population of only between 
50% and 60%; and the States of Virginia and North Carolina 
with a white population between 60% and 70%. These figures 
are interesting when taken in connection with the debt histories 
of the various States. 

» Thirteenth Census, Population, vol. i, pp. 30, 3*. • Ibid., vol. i, pp. 147-53. 



STATE BONDS 
TABLE A 



133 



State 



Population 



igoo 



igio 



Per cent 
of increase 
•igoo-io 



Alabama 

Arizona 

Arkansas 

California 

Colorado 

Connecticut. . . . 

Delaware 

Florida 

Georgia 

Idaho 

Illinois 

Indiana 

Iowa 

Kansas 

Kentucky 

Louisiana 

Maine 

Maryland 

Massachusetts. , 

Michigan 

Minnesota 

Mississippi 

Missouri 

Montana 

Nebraska 

Nevada 

New Hampshire . 

New Jersey 

New Mexico. . .. 

New York 

North Carolina. . 
North Dakota. . , 

Ohio 

Oklahoma 

Oregon 

Pennsylvania. . . 
Rhode Island . . . 
South Carolina.. 
South Dakota. . . 

Tennessee 

Texas 

Utah 

Vermont 

Virginia 

Washington 

West Virginia. . . 

Wisconsin 

Wyoming 



1,828,697 

122,931 

1.311.S64 

1,485,053 

539,700 

908420 

184,735 

528,542 

2,216,331 

161,772 

4,821,550 

2,516,462 

2,231,853 

1,470,49s 

2,147,174 

1,381,625 

694,466 

1,188,044 

2,805,346 

2,420,982 

1,751,394 
1,551,270 
3,106,665 
243,329 
1,066,300 

42,335 
411,588 

1,883,669 
195,310 

7,268,894 

1,893,810 
319,146 

4,157,545 
790,391 
413,536 

6,302,115 
428,556 

1,340,316 
401,570 

2,020,616 

3,048,710 
276,749 
343,641 

1,854,184 
518,103 
958,800 

2,069,042 
92,531 



2,138,093 

204,354 

1,574,449 

2,377,549 

799,024 

1,114,756 
202,322 

752,619 
2,609,121 

325,594 
5,638,591 
2,700,876 
2,224,771 
1,690,949 
2,289,905 
1,656,388 

742,371 
1,295.346 
3,366,416 
2,810,173 
2,075,708 
1,797,114 
3,293,33s 

376,053 

1,192,214 

81,87s 

430,572 
2,537,167 

327,301 
9,113,614 
2,206,287 

577,056 
4,767,121 

1,657,15s 
672,765 

7,665,111 
542,610 

1,515,400 
583,888 

2,184,789 
3,896,542 

373,351 
355,956 
2,061,612 
1,141,990 
1,221,119 
2,333,860 
145,965 



16.9 
66.2 
20.0 
60.1 
48.0 
22.7 

95 
42.4 

17-7 
101.3 

16.9 
7-3 
03 

ISO, 
6.6 

19- ft 
6.g 
9.0. 

2Q.0 
16. I 

i8.s 

15.8 

6.0, 

54- S 
II. 8. 

93-4 
4.6 

34-7 
67.6 
25-4. 
»6.S, 
80.8 
14.7 
109.7 
62.7 
21.6 
26.6 
13- 1 
45-4 
8.1 
27.8 

34-9 
3-6 
II. 2 
120.4 
27.4 
12.8 
S7.7 



134 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

TABLE B 



State 



Alabama 

Arizona 

Arkansas 

California 

Colorado 

Connecticut 

Delaware 

Florida 

Georgia 

Idaho 

Illinois 

Indiana 

Iowa 

Kansas 

Kentucky 

Louisiana 

Maine 

Maryland 

Massachusetts . . . . 

Michigan 

Minnesota 

Mississippi 

Missouri 

Montana 

Nebraska 

Nevada 

New Hampshire. . . 

New Jersey 

New Mexico 

New York 

North Carolina. . . 

North Dakota 

Ohio 

Oklahoma* 

Oregon 

Pennsylvania 

Rhode Island 

South Carolina 

South Dakota 

Tennessee 

Texas 

Utah 

Vermont 

Virginia 

Washington 

West Virginia 

Wisconsin 

Wyoming 



White 


Negro 


Indian, Chinese, 
Japanese and others 


jgoo 


xgio 


jgoo 


igio 


igoo 


igio 


S4-7 


57- S 


4S-2 


42. s 


(1) 


(i) 


7S-6 


83.9 


i-S 


1.0 


22.9 


IS. I 


72.0 


71.8 


28.0 


28.1 


(I) 


(I) 


94S 


9SO 


0.7 


0.9 


4.8 


4.0 


98.0 


98.0 


1.6 


1-4 


0.4 


O-S 


g8.2 


98.6 


1-7 


1-4 


0.1 


0.1 


83.4 


84.6 


16.6 


iS-4 


(i) 


(i) 


S6.3 


S8.9 


43-7 


41.0 


0.1 


(i) 


S3-3 


54-9 


46.7 


4S1 


(i) 


(r) 


9SS 


98.0 


0.2 


0.2 


4-3 


1.8 


g8.2 


98.0 


1.8 


1.9 


(i 


(i) 


97-7 


97-7 


2-3 


2.2 


¥\ 


(r) 


99-4 


99-3 


0.6 


0.7 


(i) 


(i) 


963 


96.7 


35 


3-2 


0.1 


0.2 


86.7 


88.6 


13-3 


11.4 


(i) 


(i) 


S2.8 


S6.8 


47-1 


43- 1 


0.1 


0.1 


99-7 


99-7 


0.2 


0.2 


0.1 


0.1 


80.2 


82.0 


19.8 


17.9 


(i) 


(i) 


98.7 


98.8 


I.I 


I.I 


0. 1 


0.1 


99.1 


99.1 


0.7 


0.6 


0-3 


0.3 


99.2 


99.2 


0.3 


03 


O-S 


o.S 


41-3 


43-7 


S8.S 


56.2 


0.2 


0.1 


94-8 


95- 2 


S-2 


4-8 


(i) 


(i) 


93- 


9S-9 


0.6 


OS 


6.4 


3.6 


99.1 


■99.0 


0.6 


0.6 


0.3 


0.4 


83.6 


90.7 


0.3 


0.6 


16. 1 


8.7 


99.8 


99.8 


0.2 


0.1 


(i) 


(1) 


96.2 


96.4 


3-7 


3-5 


0.1 


0.1 


923 


93- 1 


0.8 


O-S 


6.9 


6.4 


98. S 


98.4 


1-4 


r S 


0.2 


0.1 


66.7 


68.0 


33- 


31.6 


03 


0.4 


97-7 


98.8 


0.1 


0.1 


2.2 


I.I 


97-7 


97.6 


2-3 


2-3 


(i) 


(i) 


84.8 


87.2 


7.0 


8.3 


8.2 


4.S 


9S-4 


97-4 


03 


0.2 


4-3 


2.4 


97- S 


97-4 


2.S 


2.S 


0.1 


(1) 


97.8 


98.1 


2.1 


1.8 


0.1 


0.1 


41.6 


44.8 


S8.4 


SS-2 


(i) 


(1) 


94.8 


96.6 


O.I 


O.I 


S-i 


3-3 


76.2 


78.3 


23.8 


21.7 


(1) 


(i) 


79.6 


82.2 


20.4 


17.7 


(i) 


(i) 


98. S 


98.2 


0.2 


0.3 


V3 


I-5 


99-7 


99- S 


0.2 


O-S 


(i) 


(i) 


64-3 


67.4 


3S.6 


32.6 


(i) 


(I) 


95. 8 


97.1 


o.S 


o.S 


3-7 


2.3 


9S-S 


94-7 


45 


S-3 


(i) 


(i) 


99- S 


99.4 


0.1 


0.1 


0.4 


0.4 


96.2 


96.1 


I.O 


^•S 


2.7 


2.3 



(i) Less than one-tenth oi 1%. 



* Includes Indian Tenitoiy for igoo. 



STATE BONDS 
TABLE C 



135 



State 



Percentage of 

illiterates lo years 

and over 



igoo 



igio 



Class 



Percentage of 

persons from 

6 to 20 years 

attending school 



ipzo 



Alabama 34.0 

Arizona 29.0 

Arkansas 20. 4 

California 4.8 

Colorado 4.2 

Connecticut s- Q 

Delaware 12.0 

Florida 21.9 

Georgia 30.5 

Idaho 4.6 

Illinois 4.2 

Indiana 4.6 

Iowa 2.3 

Kansas 2.9 

Kentucky 16. 

Louisiana 38. 

Maine 5. 

Maryland 11. 

Massachusetts.... 5. 

Michigan 4. 

Minnesota 4. 

Mississippi 32. 

Missouri 6.4 

Montana 6.1 

Nebraska 2.3 

Nevada 13.3 

New Hampshire. . . 6.2 

New Jersey S- 9 

New Mexico 33. 2 

New York 5.5 

North Carolina ... 28. 7 

North Dakota S-6 

Ohio 4.0 

Oklahoma' 12. i 

Oregon 3.3 

Pennsylvania 6. i 

Rhode Island 8.4 

South Carolina. ... 35 . 9 
South Dakota. .. . S-o 

Tennessee 20.7 

Texas 14. S 

Utah 31 

Vermont S-S 

Virginia 22.9 

Washington 3.1 

West Virginia 11.4 

Wisconsin 4.7 

Wyoming 4.0 



22.9 
20.9 

12.6 

3-7 

3-7 

6.0 

8.1 

13-8 

20.7 

2.2 

3-7 

31 

1-7 

2.2 

12. 1 

29.0 

4-i 

7-^ 

S- 

3- 

3- 

22. 

4- 

4- 

1.9 

6.7 

4.6 

S-6 

20.2 
SS 

18. s 

31 

3-2 
5-6 
1.9 

S-9 

7-7 

2S-7 

2.9 

13-6 
9.9 

2S 

3-7 

IS-2 

2.0 
8.3 
3.2 
3-3 



Negro 


Si-4 


Indian 


S3-4 


Negro 


58. 7 


Foreign-bom white 


65.0 


Foreign-bom white 


68.4 


Foreign-bom white 


64- S 


Negro 


60.9 


Negro 


S2.7 


Negro 


Si-Q 


Foreign-bom white 


69.0 


Foreign-bom white 


634 


Native white 


66.0 


Foreign-bom white 


69.6 


Foreign-bom white 


70.6 


Native white 


61.0 


Negro 


43- 1 


Foreign-bom white 


67.7 


Negro 


S8-4 


Foreign-bom white 


66.7 


Foreign-bom white 


67-7 


Foreign-born white 


68.4 


Negro 


60.2 


Native white 


65.1 


Foreign-bom white 


64.7 


Foreign-bom white 


69.9 


Indian 


62.9 


Foreign-bom white 


65.8 


Foreign-bom white 


62.2 


Native white 


61.0 


Foieign-bom white 


63-7 


Negro 


61.3 


Foreign-bom white 


64.1 


Foreign-bom white 


66.1 


Native white 


67.8 


Foreign-bom white 


66.8 


Foreign-bom white 


62.3 


Foreign-bom white 


61.0 


Negro 


51.6 


Incian 


66.7 


Native white 


S9-4 


Negro 


S8.o 


Foreign-bom white 


70.2 


Foreign-bom white 


70.6 


Negro 


56. 3 


Foreign-bom white 


66. s 


Native white 


65.5 


Foreign-bom white 


66.2 


Foreign-bom white 


64.3 



> Includes population of Indian Teiritoiy for igoo. 



136 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Another question to be considered is the intelligence or ignorance 
of the population. Table C (on page 135) shows the percentage of 
statistics as illiterates of ten years of age or over for 1900 and 
to uteracy 1910, the class of population from which a majority 

of the illiterates is drawn, and the percentage of persons between 
the ages of six and twenty attending school in 1910.^ 

Table C shows the States of Iowa, Nebraska, and Oregon 
with less than 2% of illiterates and the States of South Dakota, 
Kansas, Utah, Idaho, and Washington with only between 2% 
and 3% illiterates, whereas it shows the States of South Carolina 
and Louisiana with over 25% illiterates and the States of Georgia, 
Alabama, Mississippi, New Mexico, and Arizona with over 20% 
iUiterates. Table C shows further that the largest class of illiter- 
ates in the States where illiteracy is greatest, with the exception 
of New Mexico and Arizona, is negro. The table further shows 
a school attendance of over 70% in the States of Vermont, 
Kansas, and Utah and of less than 60% in the States of Mary- 
land, Virginia, South Carolina, Georgia, Florida, Alabama, Ten- 
nessee, Louisiana, Arkansas, Texas, and Arizona. All these figures 
throw light on the debt histories of many of our States. It is a fact 
to be noted that in every State but Connecticut and New York, 
where the illiteracy is very smaU an3rway, the percentage of iUite- 
rates in 1910 is less than in 1900. 

There remains in discussing state bonds only one other broad 
class of considerations. These are what we will call general con- 
General con- siderations — such as the size of the State in territory, 
lS^''s°i5et|°''" t^s amoimt of developed and undeveloped resources, 
of state bonds the locatiou of the State as regards water and rail 
facilities, and other similar considerations. Any intelligent person 
can arrive at a fairly soimd conclusion along these lines by observ- 
ing the geographic positions of the various States, by looking up 
the reports of their manufacttires, by examining the statistics of 
bank clearings and postal receipts, and by obtaining other general 
information of a similar character. 

As illustrations of what we mean by general considerations 
Examples of favorably affecting the credit of States, we may 
^^^ say that the State of New York, for instance, with 

• Thirteenth Census, Population, vol. i, pp. 1108, 1214-18, 1230. 



STATE BONDS 137 

its large and fertUe territory settled with an unusual number of 
important cities, its great harbor on the Atlantic Ocean at New 
York City, its access to the Great Lakes and its splendid railroad 
connections with the West, is unusually fortunate; that likewise 
the State of Illinois, bordering on Lake Michigan and located 
almost in the center of the great Mississippi watershed, with its 
immense annual production of wealth from the soil, is fortunate; 
that so is Texas, with an area large enough and resources large 
and varied enough to enable it, perhaps, to support the entire 
population of the United States within its borders; that likewise 
California is fortimate, with its great area, fine harbors, and ad- 
vantageous position with regard to the Panama Canal. 

Li summing up the factors bearing on the credit of States, we 
wish again to lay emphasis on the following: (i) The proportion 
of net debt to the assessed valuation and to the true 
value of property and also the proportion of the debt factors bearing 
to the population; (2) the debt history of the State or °° "'^'^ "^""^ 
its record of good or bad faith; (3) the present constitutional provi- 
sions regulating the creation and payment of debt; (4) theamoimt 
and character of the population; and (5) general considerations 
bearing on the present prosperity and future growth of the State. 

On the whole, it is probably fair to say that to-day the legally 
issued obligations of our best States rank next in safety to the 
obligations of our National Government. The States, obligations of 
broadly speaking, have reserved, and, as far as pos- ""L*'^' ^ '*'''' 
sible, should reserve, for emergencies the high credit safety to ob- 
which they have built up through years of successful the National 
administration of state finances and through lessons ^o^^™"^"* 
of still earlier years learned at great cost. 

One thing more remains to be said. The prices of our state bonds 
over a long course of years have reflected not only the individual 
credit of the various States, but also, like aU other „ . 

. . . Prices of 

bonds, the pnce of capital at any given time, m state bonds 
1872, we find bonds of such States as Rhode Island, ^ ' ^^" 
Ohio, and Michigan quoted to yield around 6% net income.^ In 
1882, we find bonds of Rhode Island, New York State, Ohio, 
Michigan, and Missouri selling to yield roughly between 4% and 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 14, p. 17. 



138 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

4.50%.! During this period the bonds of the Southern States sold 
at all kinds of prices — from ^ of 1% for South Carolina 6 per 
cents in 1878, 1% for North Carolina special tax bonds in 1879, 
and 1% for Arkansas raiboad-aid 7 per cents in 1884, to 117% 
for Missouri 6 per cents in 188 1 and 180% for North Carolina 
railroad bonds in 1889 ^ — the price of any given issue being based 
upon whether interest was being paid on the bonds, whether the 
principal was questioned, whether there was a large amoimt of 
accrued interest provided for in some settlement and other similar 
considerations. In 1892, we find bonds of New Hampshire offered 
to yield about 3.25% and of Missouri quoted to yield 3.50%.* In 
1902, we find offerings of State of Massachusetts bonds to yield 
from 2.95% to 3.05%, of Rhode Island bonds to yield about 2.70%, 
of New York State bonds to yield from 2.55% to 2.63%, of Indiana 
bonds to jdeld about 3.10%, of Tennessee bonds to yield from 
3.20% to 3.25%, and of Mississippi bonds to yield about 3.50%.'' 
Lastly, in 1912, we find offerings of State of Massachusetts taxable 
bonds to yield from 3.80% to 3.85%, State of Connecticut bonds 
to yield about 3.82%, and State of New York bonds to yield from 
3.90% to 3.95%-^ These quotations show some of the fluctuations 
in the price of capital, as weU as the credit at different times of 
some of our States. 

The great European war has affected the prices of state bonds 
War prices vcry slightly. We give below prices of four issues of 
state bonds in July, 1914, and in July, 1915: — 



of state bonds 




July, iQisi 



Massachusetts taxable registered 3J per cents} 

New York State 4 per cents, 1961 

Virginia funded debt 2-3 per cents, 199 r 

CaUfomia 4 per cents § 



92.51, 

lOO^IOlJ 

84} sale 
97-31 



* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 4, igi4, p. 32. t Ibid., July 3, 1915, 

X Dealers'lists, July, 1914, and July, 1915. Prices 01 a twenty-year 3j% bond reduced from b 
(3-05% and 4.05%). 
§ Dealers* lists, July. 1914, and July, r9is. Prices of twenty-year 4% bonds (4.20% basis). 



p. 34- 

Lsis puces 



'■ Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 34, p. 24. 

' See the Financial Review (Annual, i9is)> PP- 96~97- 

• Dealers' lists, January, 1892. * Dealers' lists, January, 1902, 

' Dealers' lists, January, 19 12. 



STATE BONDS 



139 



These show changes during the year so small as to be unimpor- 
tant. 

State bonds, as remarked earlier in this chapter, as a rule are 
nothing more than promises to pay. These promises vvaimgness 
are not in the last resort enforceable by suit. The 
willingness, therefore, as well as the ability, of the 
people of the State to honor their obligations is of 
the first importance. 



of the people 
to pay state 
bonds is per- 
haps the most 
important 
factor in safety 



CHAPTER IV 

COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 

County bonds are the direct obligations of counties. Municipal 
bonds, strictly speaking, are bonds of cities and towns only. In- 
cluded in this term very often, however, are bonds 
dpai and dis- issued by school, park, drainage, and fire districts and 

trict bonds are .■, . . • , ,. t n at. t_ 

payable out Other quasi-mumapal corporations. In all the above 
of taxes cases, the bonds are payable out of taxes levied on all 

the property within the county, municipality, or district issuing 
the bonds.' 

Furthermore, a county, mimicipality, or district, unlike a State, 
can be sued without its own consent. In case of failure to pay inter- 
The means of ^^^ °^ principal, bondholders can bring suit asldng for 
recovery on de- a levv of taxes. In Certain States, such as Maine,* 

faulted county, i. i. <.•.«• a i r^ • k 

municipal, and New Hampshire,' Massachusetts,* and Connecticut,* 
are faW™ ^ bondholders have the legal right to seize the property 
complete ^j ^^ ^^^ inhabitants in execution of the judgment of 

a court ordering payment of defaulted municipal bonds. 

Aside from this question of legal remedy, the lead- 
goveming safety ing Considerations determining the safety of county, 
those in case of municipal, and district bonds are similar to the con- 
state bonds siderations governing the safety of state bonds. In 
other words, these factors are of first importance: — 

(i) The debt statement, or the net debt compared with the 
assessed valuation and with the true value of property. 

' There is a class of bonds known as special assessment bonds which are payable 
out of taxes levied on abutting property. These are not in any legal or true sense 
municipal bonds. 

* Revised Statutes, chap. 47, sec. 96, and chap. 86, sec. 30. Eames v. Savage, 77 
Maine, 212 (1885). 

• Public Statutes of New Hampshire, chap. 234, sec. 8. 

" Hawkes v. Kennebec County, 7 Mass. 461, 463 (1811). Chase v. Merrimack 
Bank, 19 Pick. (Mass.) 564, 569 (1837). Gaskill ». Dudley, 6 Met. (Mass.) 546 (1843). 
Hill V. Boston, 122 Mass. 344, 349 (1877). 

' Beardsley v. Smith, 16 Conn. 368 (1844). 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS I4I 

(2) The constitutional and statutory provisions in regard to the 
creation and payment of debt. 

(3) The record of good or bad faith. 

(4) The amoiint and character of the population. 

(5) The location, prosperity, and chances for growth of the 
community. 

As a matter of law and of practice, the proportion of net debt — 
which is usually taken to mean the gross debt less the general sink- 
ing fimds, the water debt, and sometimes debt created ^he proportion 
for income-producing property other than waterworks °^ °^t debt to 

'^ oir r J ^ assessed valu- 

— to the assessed valuation vanes considerably m the ation varies 
different States. If it is safe to speak of any definite fn the Cerent 
figure as the normal proportion of net debt to assessed ^^'^ 
valuation, we may take possibly 5%. The methods of figuring net 
debt for municipalities in the different States vary so much, how- 
ever, that this figure can be considered nothing more than an arbi- 
trary standard. It is safe to say that a net debt (meaning here a 
debt the real burden of which is on the taxpayers) of 1% of the 
assessed valuation is small and a net debt of 10% 

J 111 Debt less 

dangerously large. ^ sinking-fund 

We give below the total debt— including debt for J^nlargLt^ 
waterworks and other productive purposes, but less u^^^^V^! 
sinking-fund assets — of the ten largest cities in the 
United States.* 



City 


Debt, less sinking- 
fund assets, igi3 


Dd)t, less sinking-fund 
assets per capita 


New York City, New York 

Phikdelphia, Pennsylvania 


$862,743,861 
100,960,972 
81,699,819 
75,676,830 
46,326,458 
41,829,001 
36,539,920 
28,365,058 
22,854,668 
10,513,076 


$165.95 
61.87 
34.85 


Boston Massachusetts 


104.75 


Baltimore A/fa.rvlanH 


80.63 


Cleveland. Ohio 


67.17 




65.51 


Buffalo New York 


63.47 




31.60 




20.19 







* For assessed valuation of counties and of incorporated places having a popula- 
tion of 2500 and over, and for net debts of coimties and of incorporated places, see 
Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, IQ13, vol. i, pp. 348, 398, 752, 841. 

» Ibid., pp. 405, 414. 41S. 417. 420, 425, 429. 433- 



142 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

This table shows New York City with by far the largest per 
capita debt and Detroit with by far the smallest. 

Modifying in most States, to a great extent, the significance of 
the net debt of any one municipal corporation is the practice of 
The significance issuing bonds by Several different corporations cover- 
°f a miSci'^aBt ™S Substantially the same territory and levying taxes 
often is modi- for the payment of their bonds on practically the same 
tence of quasi- property. We find bond issues, by school districts in 
CT^ing ^ ' over thirty States including New Hampshire, New 
corporations york, Illinois, Utah, South Carolina, and Texas; by 
water districts in Maine and Massachusetts; by fire districts in 
New Hampshire, Massachusetts, Rhode Island, and Connecti- 
cut; by road districts in Ohio, Mississippi, Louisiana, Arkan- 
sas, and Texas; by park districts in Illinois and Missouri; by 
drainage districts in Illinois, Wisconsin, Iowa, Nebraska, Okla- 
homa, North Carolina, and Texas; by irrigation districts in Mon- 
tana, Colorado, and California; and by levee districts iu Mississippi, 
Louisiana, and Arkansas.^ The State of Missouri contains, besides 
the coxmties and cities, at least four different kinds of debt-creating 
quasi-municipal corporations — namely, school, park, road, and 
drainage districts; and the States of Mississippi, Louisiana, Ar- 
kansas, and Texas contain four kinds — namely, school, road, 
drainage, and levee or "navigation" districts. In addition to the 
above, we find in Connecticut especially and to some extent in 
New York state bond issues by two and sometimes three different 
municipal or quasi-municipal corporations covering practically the 
same territory and called cities, towns, boroughs, and villages.^ 
A s% muni- ^ vi^w of thcse facts, it is obvious that a net debt 

Stet'e lik'e '"'' °^ S% for a municipality in a State like Massachu- 
Massachusetta sctts, wherc the Issue of bonds by districts is com- 

may be less of . •ii-tt, 

a burden on paratively rare, is less of a burden on the commimity 

ity than a than a net debt say of 3% for a dty in some State 

dfbt'i^stat ^^ Illinois, where there may be also a 2% or a 3% 

like Illinois (jgbt fgj. ^ drainage district covering practically the 

' These are simply examples and do not include all the States having such dis- 
tricts. 

' State and City Section of the Commercial and Financial Chronide, May 29, 
191S, passim. In the State of Washington there is a corporation, distinct from the 
dty of Seattle, called the Port of Seattle, which has issued bonds. (See Und., p. 168.) 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS I43 

same territory as the city and possibly a 2% or a 3% debt issue 
by park districts within the city limits.' 

Consideration of the proportion of debt to property in our muni- 
cipalities leads to the question of the constitutional and statutory 
provisions of the various States in regard to the issue constitutional 
of bonds by counties, mimicipalities, and districts, and statutory 

■' ; jT ; provisions m 

Perhaps the best way to treat this phase of the subject regard to 

• t • J -Ji ^u 1 t li. local debt 

IS to summarize and compare with the laws of other 

States the recently enacted legislation of Massachusetts governing 

municipal finances.* 

The leading provisions of the Massachusetts laws xhe Massa- 
goveming the creation of local debt are as follows: — <i"isett3 laws 

1. Except when authorized by law for certain purposes, to be enumer- 
ated later, and except for the purpose of paying Debt limit 
certain demand notes or restoring trust fimds, no for cities 
city of Massachusetts shall authorize indebteiiess ^ ^""^^ 

to an amount exceeding 2^% and no town to an amount exceed- 
ing 3% of the average assessed valuation of taxable property for 
the three preceding calendar years.* Purposes of 

2. Cities and towns may incur debt within the limit of '^^"^ ^°"J ""^ 
indebtedness prescribed above for the following pur- gations within 
poses and payable within the periods stated below: '^''" ^^^ 

1 In this connection there is. an interesting provision in the constitution of South 
Carolina as follows: that "wherever there shall be several political divisions or 
municipal corporations covering or extending over the same territory or portions 
thereof, possessing a power to levy a tax or contract a debt, then each of such political 
divisions or municipal corporations shall so exercise its power to increase its debt 
under the foregoing eight per cent limitation that the aggregate debt over and upon 
any territory of tUs State shall never exceed fifteen percentum of the value of all 
taxable property in such territory as valued for taxation by the State: Provided that 
nothing herein shall prevent the issue of bonds for the purpose of paying or refunding 
any valid mimidpal debt heretofore contracted in excess of eight percentum of the 
assessed value of all the taxable property therein." {Constitution of South Carolina, 
art. X, sec. 5.) 

' Acts 1913, chap. 719, as amended by Acts 1914, chaps. 143 and 317; Acts igis, 
chap. 648; Acts jgi3, chap. 634; Acts igi3, chap. 677; Acts igz3, chap. 727, as amended 
by Acts IQ14, chap. sS't -^ci^ 1910, chap. 616, as amended by Acts igi2, chaps. 45 
and 49; Acts igi3, chap. 416; Acts igog, chap. 490, part i, sec. 5, cl. 15, as amended 
by Acts igi4, chap. 83; Acts igio, chap. 379. 

' Acts igi3, chap. 719, sec. 12; Acts igi3, chap. 634. 

Coimties in Massachusetts, except Suffolk and Nantucket, cannot borrow, except 
in anticipation of taxes, without special permission of the Legislature. (Revised Laws, 
chap. 21, sec. 39, as amended by Acts igi'4, chap. 386.) Fire, water and watch dis- 
tricts are similarly limited. (Acts igij, chap. 719, sec. 3.) 



144 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

(i) For the construction of sewers for sanitary and surface 
Sewers drainage purposes and for sewage disposal, thirty years. 

(2) For acquiring land for public parks under the provisions of 
Parks chapter 28 of the Revised Laws and amendments therepf, 

thirty years. 

(3) For acquiring land for, and the construction of, schoolhouses 
School- or buildings to be used for any municipal or departmental 
houses purpose, including the cost of original equipment and fur- 
nishing, twenty years. 

(4) For the construction of additions to schoolhouses or buildings 
to be used for any municipal purpose, including the cost of 

Additions to original equipment and furnishings, where such additions 
buUdi^s increase the floor space of said buildings to which such ad- 
ditions are made, twenty years, 
(s) For the construction of bridges of stone or concrete, or of 
Bridges iron Superstructure, twenty years. 

(6) For the original construction of streets or highways or the 
Streets extension or widening of streets or highways, including land 
damages and the cost of pavement and sidewalks laid at the 
time of said construction, ten years. 

^"' . (7) For the construction of stone, block, brick, or other per- 
manent^'' ...,,. , ' ^ 
pavements manent pavement of similar lastmg character, ten years. 

(8) For macadam pavement or other road material under specifi- 

Temporaiy cations approved by the Massachusetts Highway Commis- 

pavements sion, five years. 

Walls (g) YoT the construction of walls or dikes for the protection of 

dikes highways or property, ten years. 

(10) For the purchase of land for cemetery purposes, ten 
Cemeteries years. 

(11) For such part of the cost of additional departmental equip- 
Depart- ment as is in excess of 25 cents per $1000 of the preceding 
equipment year's valuation, five years. 

(12) For the construction of sidewalks of brick, stone, concrete, 
Sidewalks or Other material of similar lasting character, five years. 

(13) For connecting dwellings or other buildings with pubhc sewers. 

Connection when a portion of the cost is to be assessed on the abutting pro- 
wl th sewers __.. ^ 

perty owners, five years. 

Abatement (14) For the abatement of nuisances in order to conserve 
o nmsances ^j^^ pubUc health, five years. 

(15) For extreme emergency appropriations involving the 
Emergency health or safety of the people or their property, five 

appropna- , •' r- r- r c J7 

tions years.' 

' Acts igi3, chap. 719, sec. s, as amended by Acts igi4, chap. 317. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS I4S 

Debts may be authorized as above only by a two-thirds vote of all 
the members of a city council or other governing body taken by 
yeas and nays and subject to the approval of the xwo-thirds 
mayor, if such approval is required by the charter of vote is 
the city; and in the cases of towns only by a vote '""^^^^^'^ 
of two thirds of the voters present and voting.^ 
Cities and towns may incur debt outside the limit of indebtedness 
prescribed above for the following purposes and pay- Debt outside 
able within the periods stated below: — *'■"'' 

(i) For temporary loans in anticipation of revenue, or in antici- 
pation of the issue of bonds or notes, or in connection with 
altering grade crossings, or in connection with Temporary 
highway construction in anticipation of reim- '°*"^ 
bursement by the Commonwealth, one year. 

(2) For establishing or purchasing a system for supplying the 
inhabitants of a city or town with water, or for the pur- 
chase of land for the protection of a water sys- „, , , 

, , . ^ . , , . "^ Water works 

tem, or for acquirmg water rights, thirty years. 

(3) For the extension of water mains and for water equip- 
water departmental equipment, five years. ™^'^' 

(4) For establishing, purchasing, extending or enlarging a gas or 
electric lighting plant within the limits of a city or town, 
twenty years; but the indebtedness so in- Electric 
curred shall be limited to an amount not ex- ''sht plants 
ceeding in a town 5% and in a city 23% of the last pre- 
ceding assessed valuation of such town or city. 

(s) For acquiring land for the purposes of a pubUc playground, 
as specified in section 19 of chapter 28 of the Revised Laws 
and amendments thereof, thirty years; but the „. , 

indebtedness so incurred shall be limited to 
an amount not exceeding one half of 1% of the last preced- 
ing assessed valuation of the city or town.^ 
, All other debts hereafter incurred by a city or town shall be reck- 
oned in determining its limit of indebtedness, and debts authorized 
under the provisions just stated, except for tempo- y^j^g ^^^^g, 
rary loans, must be authorized by the same votes as sary outside 
in the case of debts within the debt limit. Temporary ^ ^ '""* 
loans, unless in anticipation of the proceeds of bonds or notes 
(which require no vote at all) , require a majority Certificates 
vote.' P'=«P* '" 

, ^ temporary 

. Cities and towns may sell bonds, notes, or certifi- loans must be 
cates of indebtedness as authorized above at not ^°^^ ^' ^^ 

* Ads igi3, chap. 719, sec. 5. 

' Acts igi3, chap. 719, sec. 6. See also sections 2, 3, 4, and 9. • Ibid. 



146 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

less than par at public or private sale. Temporary loans, as de- 
scribed above, to run not over one year may be sold at a dis- 
count.'- 

7. No further sinking funds for the payment of debts created by 
Payment of cities and towns shall be established, and all loans, except 
method is^"^' temporary loans to run not over one year, shall be payable 
compulsory in annual installments sufficient to extinguish at maturity 

the debt created.'' 

8. The city of Boston shall not assess for ordinary municipal purposes 
over $10.55 on every $1000 of taxable property, according to the 

Tax limits for average assessed valuation for the preceding three years.' 
municipal Other cities in Massachusetts may, after a pubUc hearing, 

purposes estabUsh by ordinance the maximum rate of taxes to be 

raised for ordinary municipal pinposes, that is, for purposes exclu- 
sive of the state tax and other amounts assessed upon the city by 
the State, the county tax and sums required by law to be raised on 
account of the city debt. Such maximum rate can be thereafter 
changed only by a two-thirds vote of the governing body, after a 
pubUc hearing.* 

9. During the year 1914 every city and town which has at the time of 
this act (1913) outstanding notes payable on demand, or which has 

Payment of expended for the general expenses of the city or town 
and restoration ^^^^ funds which have not been restored, shall provide 
of trust funds for the payment of such notes and for the restoration of 
such trust funds in the tax levy for the year 1914 where such provi- 
sion is reasonably practicable. When not practicable, debt may be 
incurred, outside the limit of indebtedness fixed by law, to the 
amount necessary to pay the demand notes or restore the trust 
funds, and serial bonds or notes may be issued payable at periods 
not later than fifteen years from their respective dates of issue.* 

A brief discussion of the propriety and wisdom of the above laws 
„ . , and a comparison with the laws of other States may 

Comparison of . ^ ^ •' 

Massachusetts be of interest. The variations are almost numberless, 
those of but certain general resemblances and differences may 

other states be pointed OUt. 

The first thing to fix in mind is the position of the legislature. 
As a rule, its action is limited by constitutional restrictions. In 
some States, however, such as New Hampshire,^ Massachu- 

' Acts 1913, chap. 719, sees. 8 and 10. ' Tbid., sees. 13 and 14. 

' Ibid., sec. 18. ' Ihid., sec. 19. ' Ibid., chap. 634. 

' Abbott, Lav/s of Public Securities, sec. 495, p. 992. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS I47 

setts,^ and Kansas,^ the limitation 'of the creation of debts by 
counties, municipalities, and other political subdi- Authority and 
visions is left to the state legislature without sub- LegiSature in 
stantial constitutional restrictions. Sometimes the certain states 
legislature in municipal charters lays down certain limits for the 
creation of debt;^ sometimes it passes more or less general leg- 
islation; and sometimes it authorizes by special acts specific 
loans. 

The limitation of the debt of cities in Massachusetts to 2^% and 
of the debt of towns to 3% of the average assessed valuation for the 
threeprecedingyears, except for temporary loans and . 

except for the acquisition of property which should indebtedness in 

.ir .. p 11* 1 1 1 Other States 

be seu-supportmg or for public playgrounds, may be 
said to be very conservative. This compares with a gross debt 
limit, with certain exceptions, of 10% in New York State; * a gross 
debt limit of 2% of the value of taxable property, except obliga- 
tions incurred for public protection or defense and except gravel 
road bonds, in Indiana;^ a limit for municipalities in Wisconsin' 
of 5% of the value of taxable property; a limit, with certain excep- 
tions, for cities and towns in Virginia ' of 18% of the assessed value 
of real estate unless further issue is authorized by a majority vote 
of the people ; and in Louisiana,* a limit for munidpahties, parishes, 
and districts, with certain exceptions, of 10% of the assessed value 
of the property. 

A practice has crept into the constitutional provisions or laws of 
some of the States making special exceptions in favor of certain 

' Abbott, Laws of Public Securities, sec. 487, p. 978. 
' Constitution of Kansas, art. xn, sec. $• 

• State and City Section of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 
X914, pp. 32 and s8. 

* Constitution of New York, art. vm, sec. 10, as amended November, 1909, in effect 
January i, 1910. Birdseye, Consolidated Laws of New York, vol. 7, p. 22. 

' Constitution of Indiana, art. xm. Bums's Annotated Indiana Statutes (Revision 
of 1914), vol. I, p. 124. 

' Constitution of Wisconsin, art. xi, sec. 3. See Wisconsin Statutes (1898), vol. 1, 
p. 122. 

' Constitution of Virginia, art. Vin, sec. 127. Pollard, Code of Virginia (1904), 
p. ccxlii. 

' Constitution of Louisiana (1913), art. 281, as amended November 3, 1914. See 
Acts of Louisiana (1914), no. 192, for amendment. Drainage districts, under the 
above article, are given powers relative to incurring indebtedness up to fifty cents 
per acre, to be secured by special taxes of like amount. 



148 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

communities, so as to allow them to issue bonds beyond the 
amovmt authorized for other commimities in the same 

£xceptions m 

favor of certain State. Examples of a reasonable use of this practice 
commum les ^^^ -^^^ York ^ and Philadelphia * for expensive per- 
manent improvements, such as subways and docks. Examples of 
what seem to us illogical and possibly dangerous exceptions are 
those found in the laws of South Carolina ' and Alabama.* In 
South Carolina, especially, the habit has grown up of excepting 
municipahties from the debt limit for almost any purpose. 

In this connection it is to be noted that Massachusetts in its 
recently enacted legislation, while carefully limiting the creation of 
Limiting debt debt, has removcd the tax limit for mimidpalities, ex- 
tex w fa°^ cept in Boston, in all municipalities in the State. This 
Massachusetts geems to US wise. Removing the tax limit and care- 
fully limiting the creation of debt certainly is more conservative 
than limiting the tax rate and allowing more or less liberal borrow- 
ing. A rise in taxes is noticed sooner and felt more directly by citi- 
zens than is an increase in the debt. Tjdng any community down 
too tight in both respects may hamper its reasonable development 
and in the long run make its bonds less safe.^ 

AH the purposes for which mimicipahties in Massachusetts may 

issue bonds, it will be noted, are of a strictly public character and 

not for the special benefit of any private individual 

Purposes of '^ -^ ^ 

issue should or corporation. Throughout the Umted States the 

be of 3. strictlv 

pubUc most common purposes for which county, municipal, 

c aracter ^^^ district bonds may be issued are as follows: 

Roads, bridges, and county buildings, such as court-houses and 
jails; parks and playgrounds, sewers, waterworks, and electric 

' Constitution of New York, art. vin, sec. 10, as amended 1909. Birdseye, Con- 
solidated Laws of New York, vol. 7; cumulative Supplement (1910-13), vol. 1, p. 
22. 

' Constitution of Pennsylvania, art. ix, sec. 8, as amended 1911. Purdon's Digest 
(13th ed.), supplement of 1912, p. 2. 

' Constitution of South Carolina (189s), art. x, sec. 6, as amended 1911. See also 
ibid., art. vin, sec. 7. See Code of Laws of South Carolina (1912), vol. n, pp. 632, 
642, 660. 

* Constitution of Alabama (1901), art. xn, sec. 226. Code of Alabama (1907; 
Criminal), vol. 3, p. 173. 

' For difficulties likely to arise in bonds payable out of taxes limited to a certain 
amoimt, see United States v. County of Clark, 96 U.S. 211, and State ex rel. Hudson 
V. Trammel, 106 Mo. 510; 17 S.W. so*. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 149 

lighting plants ^ and municipal buildings, such as school-buildings, 
city or town halls, and fire stations. 

As examples of authority given mimicipalities outside of Massa- 
chusetts to issue bonds for improper or unwise purposes, mention 
may be made of the following: Permission for towns Examples of 
in Vermont ^ to borrow for the benefit of railroads to fJiue°bonds° 
an amount not exceeding practically 8% of the as- oTuSmse^^' 
sessed valuation; permission for counties and munici- purposes 
palities in Minnesota ' to create debts in aid of railroads to an 
amoimt not exceeding 5% of the taxable property of the munici- 
pality; permission for municipalities in Nebraska * to make dona- 
tions to a railroad or for other works of internal improvement to an 
amoimt not exceeding 10% of the aggregate assessed valuation of 
the county and subdivisions, provided the proposition shall have 
been approved by the voters, with permission for an additional 
amount of 5% by a two-thirds vote; and permission for certain 
townships in South Carolina ® to issue railroad-aid bonds to an 
amount not exceeding 8% of the assessed valuation. 

In a large mmiber of the States, issuing bonds in aid of railroads 
or for private enterprises, purchasing the stock of private corpora- 
tions, or loaning the credit of the coimty or mmiicipal- ^ 

' ° "^ , , ^ In many States 

ity to such corporations specifically is forbidden.^ loaning credit 
This prohibition is the result of the experience which munidpaKties 
many counties and some municipalities have had, in '^ f°rbiddeu 

> Two interesting provisions among the laws of many States authorizing munici- 
palities to borrow for the purchase of public utilities are : those in the laws of Michigan 
authorizing villages to issue mortgage bonds to acquire public utilities without liability 
on the part of the village; and those in the laws of Mississippi providing that bonds 
issued for waterworks, gas or electric lighting plants may be secured by pledge of 
the revenue of such plants. (Public Acts of Michigan [1909], chap. 278, sec. 26. See 
Howell's Michigan Statutes [2d ed.], vol. 3, title xvi, chap. 98, sec. 6215. Laws of 
Mississippi [1914], chap. 147, sec. 6.) 

' Public Statutes of Vermont (1906), sec. 3558. 

» General Statutes of Minnesota (1913), sees. 1928 and 1951. See also Constitution 
of Minnesota, ait. rx, sec. 15. 

* Constitution of Nebraska, art. xn, sec. 2. See also Revised Statutes of Nebraska 
(1913), sec. 405. 

' Constitution of South Carolina, art. x, sec. 6. Code of Laws of South Carolina 
(1912), vol. 2, p. 642 . See also Acts of South Carolina (1911), nos. 155, 156, iS9, 162- 

' Constitution of New Hampshire, part 2, art. v. Public Statutes of New Hampshire 
(1901), p. 33. Connecticut: Amendments to the Constitution, art. xxv. Constitution of 
New York, art. vm, sec. 10. Birdseye, Consolidated Laws of New York, p. 150. 
Constitution of Illinois, art. xiv, separate section; Emsed Statutes of Illinois (1912}, 
p. Izzv. 



ISO AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

issuing bonds in aid of private enterprises, partiailarly railroads, 
of finding later that the communities did not get the benefits which 
they expected and of being obliged or being willing to default on 
the bonds. The experience of counties and mimicipalities in this 
respect has been similar to the experience of many of our States- 
Certain States permit municipalities to issue refunding bonds — 
a practice which should not, except under special circumstances. 
Refunding ^^ permitted. Among such States may be mentioned 

bonds Vermont, 1 Rhode Island," Virginia,' and Alabama.* 

In the Massachusetts laws, the length of time which bonds may 
run is based, as far as practicable, on the permanence of the work 
^ ,, , for which the money is spent. For instance, bonds is- 
setts time to sucd f or the purchase of land for parks or playgrounds 
with pCTma-° ^ give the city a permanent asset. Bonds issued even for 
nence of work school-buildings alonc give the city property with a 
life probably of at least twenty years; whereas bonds issued for 
sidewalks may give the municipality property which will have to 
be replaced or rebuilt within a short time. The limitation to ten 
years of bonds issued for cemetery purposes is based probably on 
the minimum estimate of the length of time the land will be avail- 
able for cemetery purposes. 

In the constitutions or statutes of many of the States, an arbi- 
in some States '^ary limit is placed on coimties, cities, and other po- 
the length of Utical subdivisious as to the length of time which their 

tmie bonds may , ° 

run is fixed bonds may run. For mstance, bonds m Colorado* 
to thTpurpose must nm not less than ten years and not more than 
of issue fifteen years ; bonds in New Hampshire ^ and inlllinois ^ 

' Public Statutes of Vermont (igo6), chap. 157, sees. 3567, 3572. 

' General Laws of Rhode Island (1909), title vm, chap. 46, sec. 21. (Towns only.) 

• Acts igoS, p. $3$. Pollard's Virginia Code, Annotated, vol. 3 (Supplement, 1910), 
sec. 1038 /, p. 133. See also Acts 1914, p. 256. Pollard's Code Biennial (Virginia, 
1914), sec. 834 b, p. 142. 

• Constitution of Alabama (igoi), sec. 224. See also Acts of Alabama (1907), p. 790, 
sec. 195. Political Code of Alabama (1907), art. xxvni, sec. 1436. 

' Constitution of Colorado, art. xi, sec. 8. Mills's Annotated Statutes of Colorado, 
p. c 207. See also ibid., chap. 161, sec. 7226, sub-section 6, p. 3028. 

• Municipal Bonding Act, Laws of New Hampshire (1895), chap. 43, sec. 2. 
Public Statutes of New Hampshire (1901), p. 491. 

' Constitution of Illinois, art. ix, sec. 12. Revised Statutes of Illinois (1912), p. 
tdz. See also Revised Statutes of Illinois (1912), sec. 700, p. 455; chap. 34, sec. 128, 
p. 657. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 151 

must be paid within twenty years; in Oklahoma, ^ within twenty- 
five years; in Pennsylvania,^ within thirty years; in Texas,' within 
forty years, and in California,* with certain exceptions, within 
forty years. 

In many States it is necessary to have all or practically all bond 
issues of local communities, beyond a certain amount, authorized 
by a vote of the people ; for instance, in Pennsylvania,^ j^ ^^^ 
a majority vote is necessary; in South Carolina,* a States a vote 

. . , , , . , . , .of the people is 

majonty of voters who have paid taxes for the previ- necessary to 
ous year; in Utah,^ a majority vote of the property ^'i"'""^^ ''°°<*^ 
taxpayers; in Vermont,* Kentucky,' Missouri,^" North Dakota,^^ 
and certain other States, a two-thirds vote of the people; and in 
Oklahoma ^^ and Washington,^' a three-fifths vote of the people. 
Provisions of many other States along these lines could be given. 
We have discussed above the Massachusetts laws in regard to 
the creation of local debt, and have compared them with the laws 
of some of the other States. The creation of debt is Methods of 
one thing and the payment of it is another. The paying debt 
Massachusetts laws ^* compel payment by serial method. The com- 
monest method still, however, in other States is payment through 
the estabhshment of sinking funds, created out of annual taxes and 
calculated to be suflScient with accumulations to pay the principal 
of the debt at maturity. Payment by serial method is simpler, 
more scientific, and probably more economical. 

' Constitution of Oklahoma, art. x, sec. 26. 

* Constitution of Pennsylvania, art. DC, sec. 10. Purdon's Digest (13th ed.), vol. i, 
p. igg. See Act of April 20, 1874, sec. i, Laws of Pennsylvania, p. 65. Purdon's 
Digest (13th ed.), vol. 3, p. 2721. 

» Revised Civil Statutes of Texas (1911), title xvm, art. 618. 

* Constitution of California, art. xi, sec. 18. Henning's General Laws of California 
(1914), p. 79; ibid., vol. 5, chap. 352, art. 3051, sec. 5. 

' Constitution of Pennsylvania, art. K, sec. 8. Pvirdon's Digest (13th ed.), vol. r, 
p. 197. 

* Constitution of South Carolina, art. n, sec. 13. See also art. 8, sees. 5 and 7. 
' Constitution of Utah, art. xiv, sec. 3. 

' Public Statutes of Vermont (1906), diap. 157, sec. 3556. 

' Constitution of Kentucky, sec. 157. 

'° Constitution of Missouri, art. x, sees. 12 and 12 A. Revised Statutes of Missouri, 
(1909), chap. 84, art. 2, sec. 8668. 

•' Constitution of North Dakota, art. xn, sec. 183. Compiled Laws of North Dakota 
(1913), p. ciii. 

'* Constitution of Oklahoma, art. x, sec. 26. 

" Constitution of Washington, art. vrn, sec. 6. " Acts igi3, chap. 719, sec. 14. 



152 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

On the whole, the Massachusetts laws, in our opinion, establish 
a system of creating and paying debt that seems financially somid 
Local debt ^°^ politically expedient.^ They cover in a systematic 
laws in way all the proper purposes for creating debt; and 

on the whole, ' they provide a safety-valve for the public demand for 
^°° improvements through the removal of the state limit 

on the local tax. 

In general, it may be said that constitutional or statutory provi- 
sions ia regard to the creation of local debt which are too strict or 
General laws *°° narrow are imdesirable. They are likely to lead 
j°^sard to to a long Ust of exceptions and special acts * which, in 
should not the end, will take much of the effectiveness out of the 

limitation of debt. The provisions of many States in 
regard to debt creation by municipalities seem extremely conserva- 
tive when you begin to read and extremely lax before you finish. 

Taken by and large throughout the coxmtry, the state limita- 
tions on the creation of local debts are much more liberal than the 
Laws govern- provisions governing the creation of state debt. This 
more°uhe?d''^ is, in our opinion, desirable. The credit of the State 
goveridng* should be reserved largely for emergencies. Further- 
state debt more, the citizens of a dty or town are better able to 
judge of the desirability of any given loan by the municipality than 
they are of a state loan. In the case of a municipal loan, the citizens 
get the direct benefit and they carry the immediate burden. 
Other factors Perhaps even more important than the constitu- 
tte^safetyo? tional and statutory provisions regulating the crea- 
""^.'5;. tion and payment of local debt are the following con- 

municipal and _ *^ -' ° 

district bonds siderations: 
(i) The amoimt and character of the population. 

(2) The record of good or bad faith. 

(3) The location, prosperity and probable future growth of the 
community. 

The amount of the population of a county or dty is an important 
consideration. There are Just fifty cities, according to the census 

' In the matter of public credit, all considerations having a bearing on the general 
status and well-being of the community are relevant. 

^ Some people have criticized even the new Massachusetts laws in this respect. 
The right to go to the legislature for special acts is not, of course, taken away, 
although the inducement to do so is less than under the old laws. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 1 53 

of 1910, with a population of 100,000 or over. New York City is 
the largest and Albany the smallest of these fifty The amount 
cities. The ten largest cities of the United States tfon''i7°^"'*' 
with their population are: 1 important 

New York, New York 4,766,883 

Chicago, Illinois 2,185,283 

Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 1,549,008 

St. Louis, Missouri 687,029 

Boston, Massachusetts 686,092 

Cleveland, Ohio 560,663 

Baltimore, Maryland 558,485 

Pittsburg, Pennsylvania 533)905 

Detroit, Michigan 465,776 

Buffalo, New York 423,715 

The direct obligations of the above cities, payable out of taxes 
levied on all the property within those cities, may be considered, in 
a general way, the leading municipal securities in the United States. 
If we should take a limit of 50,000 people or over, we should find a 
long Hst of cities with high credit. 

More important even than the size of the population in its effect 
on the real safety of municipal bonds is the character of the popu- 
lation. In the last resort, all debts of any kind depend The character 
on the good faith of some person or persons to do as °l^^^ P°p"" 
they have agreed and to honor their obligations. The important 
character of the people of the New England States, from the point 
of view of paying their debts, is perhaps better than that of any 
other section of the country. The people of New York State like- 
wise have been careful about the payment, if not about the crea- 
tion, of debt. 

This leads us to speak of the record of county, municipal, and 
district bonds and to discuss briefly certain typical defaults. In 
proportion to the amount of bonds put out, the record The record of 
of municipal bonds is better than that of state bonds. boTds'htl 
Perhaps this is true largely because the history of th|nthat"f 
state debts is longer and covers much more of the state bonds 
early development period in the United States, when the popula- 
tion was shifting and the relation of the people to their various 
> Thirteenth Census of the United States (1910), vol. i, Population, pp. 78-79. 



154 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

government units and to private enterprise was in a more or less 
chaotic condition. Perhaps, also, the completeness of the legal 
remedy in the case of mxmicipal bonds has had a tendency to re- 
strict the amount of defaults. At the same time, the amount of 
defaults in payment of interest or principal of coimty and munici- 
pal bonds, if we include all cases of bonds illegally issued, is con- 
siderable. A writer in the "North American Review" many years 
ago estimated the amount of defaulted county, city, township, and 
school-district bonds as over $300,000,000.1 Included in this total 
was a large amount of defaulted bonds in such States as lUinois, 
Missouri, Kansas, Nebraska, and the Dakotas, as well as in the 
Causes of South.^ As in the case of state defaults, illegality 

<»"°.'y' , usually has been the excuse rather than the reason. 

municipal ^ 

and district The prmapal causes of default m the bonds of 

coimties, municipaUties, and districts have been: — 
(i) A furor for improvements similar to that which prevailed at 
one time in many of our States and which led to financial 
difl&culties at one time or another of such cities as Pitts- 
burg, Pennsylvania,' Elizabeth, New Jersey,* and Superior, 
Wisconsin.^ 

(2) Issue of railroad-aid bonds or bonds for other doubtful or 
illegal purposes, as in the cases of Macon County, Missouri,' 
St. Clair County, Missouri,^ Green County, Kentucky,* 
Taylor Coimty, Kentucky,' and Otoe County (Nebraska 
City Precinct), Nebraska. ^^ 

(3) Issue of bonds by small, struggling or unstable communities 

where the property and taxing power proved insufficient to 

take care of the bonds, as in the cases of Syracuse, Kansas," 

Olympia, Wasliington,!^ Middlesboro, Kentucky, ^^ and 

Mobile, Alabama." 

' John F. Hume in the North American Review, August, 1884, pp. 129 and 131. 
' Ibid., p. 131, and C. M. Harger in Moody's Magazine, February, 1906, p. 358. 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 24, p. 591. * Ihid., vol. 28, p. 146- 
^ Ibid., vol. 79, p. 2107. The defaulted bonds were held by the United States 
Circuit Court of Appeals to be special assessment bonds. 

' Ibid., vol. 92, p. 1191. ' Ibid., vol. 89, p. 1293. ' Ibid., vol. 96, p. 1507. 

' Ibid., vol. 95, p. 1760. '" Ibid., vol. 72, p. 302. 

'' Information given by bankers. 

'' Information given by bankers. 

" Ibid. See also Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 84, p. 404. 

" Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 25, p. 382. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS !$$ 

(4) Special misfortunes, such as yellow fever epidemics in Mem- 
phis, Tennessee,' and Savannah, Georgia," and the disas- 
trous floods at Galveston, Texas.' 

(5) Issue of bonds by municipal irrigation districts, where the 
inherent risk of the enterprise is considerable, such as Denver- 
St. Vrain Municipal Irrigation District, Colorado,* Denver- 
Greeley Irrigation District, Colorado,* and San Arroya Irri- 
gation District, Colorado.* 

The above examples have been chosen not because they are in, 
every case the worst, but because the information is available.'' 

There have been also a few cases of plain bad faith, of which 
mention may be made of St. Joseph, Missouri,* which voted to 
compromise and refund a city bonded debt at sixty c^ses of 
cents on the dollar with reduced interest when there ^^ ^^^^^ 
was no necessity for any default, and Fort Worth, Texas,* which 
refunded a portion of its old 6% bonds with new 4% bonds without 
any necessity for such action and without any adequate reason. 

A recent attempt at bad faith, which proved little more than 
amusing, was the effort of the Mayor of Atchison, Kansas, to re- 
fimd in July, 1913, at a time when municipal bonds Attempted 
were selling to yield from 4|% to S% net income, old b^A^t^c'hhon. 
4% bonds with new 4% bonds at par and his refusal K*"sas 
to pay off the old bonds in cash. The result of this attempt was the 
ruling by the Kansas Supreme Court that it had jurisdiction to 
require levy of a tax to pay full principal of the bonds and f orbid-- 
ding any tax levy unless provision was made for them.^" 

In the matter of the settlement of the claims of bondholders on 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 31, p. 328. 

' Investor's Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, January 26, 1878, 
p. xiii. 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 71, p. 564. 

* Ibid., vol. 92, pp. 476 and 972. ' Ibid. 

' State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 1914, 

p. I4S- 

' See Appendix, "County and Munidpal Defaults,'' pp. 297-303. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 23, pp. 13s and 175; ibid., vol. 25, 
p. 408; ibid., vol. 28, p. 477. 

• Ibid., vol. 69, p. 711, and information received from bankers. 

" Levison v. Finney, no. 18,934, Supreme Court of Kansas. This case never was 
reported for the reason that it never came to a final hearing on the matter of levying 
a tax. (Letter from Clerk of Court, November 7, 19 14. See Appendix, p. 304.} 



156 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

defaulted county, municipal, and district bonds, the practice has 
varied all the way from full settlement of interest and 
made with principal, as in the case of Pittsburg, Pennsylvania,* 
on o ers ^^ ^-^q so-called Penn Avenue bonds, to a failure to 
pay anything at all, as in the cases of the railroad-aid bonds issued 
by Green Coimty, Kentucky,^ and St. Clair Coimty, Missouri.' 
Elizabeth, New Jersey,^ Memphis, Teimessee,* and New Orleans, 
Louisiana,* at one time or another compromised all or a part of 
their debt on the basis of fifty cents on the dollar. Mobile, Ala- 
bama,' issued $510 in new 6% bonds for every $1000 of old 8% 
bonds. Macon County, Missouri,* settled an aggregate claim of 
$2,200,000 with $750,000. Scaling of the principal to a greater or 
less degree has taken place in many other cases.' 

On the whole, reduction in interest rather than scaling of the 
principal has been the rule. Where the amount of bonds has been 
Bondholders Small and where the prospect has been nothing worse 
often have than a Scaling ia interest, bondholders often have 

accepted re- ° ,. , , 

duction in f ound it more advantageous to accept a slight reduc- 

than fight tion in interest rather than fight the question through 

through courts ^^^ courts with the possibility in some cases of not 
being able to collect the amoimt of the probable judgment. 

The attitude of the people toward repudiation of county or 
municipal obligations has been, perhaps, less radical than the at- 
, . , , titude of the people in the cases of certain of our 

Attitude of . '^ -^ 

the people States. With the exception of some of our counties, 

promise or the piocceds of bouds issued have not been wasted to 
repudiation ^j^^ same extent as were the proceeds of some of our 
state bonds. Illegality of issue as an excuse for compromise or 
repudiation has been used almost as frequently; but the knowledge 
of the existence of a legal remedy in the case of counties, munici- 
palities, and districts, — suit to compel levy of taxes to pay interest 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 302. 

^ Ibid., vol. 77, p. 48; vol. 84, p. 949. These bonds have been practically invali- 
dated by the United States Supreme Court. 

' Ibid., vol. 89, p. 1293. State and City Section, Commercial and Financial 
Chronicle, May 30, 1914, p. 124. 

■* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 47, p. 50. ' Ihid., vol. 37, p. 202. 

' Ihid., vol. 31, p. 606-607. ' Ibid., vol. 21, p. 302. ' Ibid., vol. 92, p. 1191. 

' For leading steps in the history of certain county and municipal defaults and 
settlements, see Appendix, pp. 297-300. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 1 57 

and principal of bonds, — and of the disposition of the courts to 
interpret legality of issue strongly in favor of maintaining good 
faith, have caused the people and their representatives to take a 
firmer attitude toward the payment of their debts. As a rule, the 
extent of the effort toward compromise or repudiation has de- 
pended on the character of the population. 

Aside from the defaults and compromises on mimicipal bonds, 
there has been in local finances, especially of recent years, a con- 
siderable amount of mismanagement which has ,,. 

, , , , Mismanage- 

threatened to lead to financial difficulties. This situa- ment of local 
tion has been met sometimes by passing careful gen- 
eral laws governing finances of municipaUties, as in Massachusetts, 
and sometimes by establishing a commission form of government,' 
which has been done in the cases of Lawrence, Massachusetts," Om- 
aha, Nebraska,' Denver, Colorado,* and New Orleans, Louisiana.^ 
In addition to the size and character of the population and the 
record of good or bad faith, the factors of location, present pros- 
perity, and probable future growth are important. 
These are questions which can be looked up fairly ent prospenty^ 
easily in the cases of most of our cities and towns. ^^J^^J^ 
In addition to the national and state censuses, the cominunities 

' are important 

growth of cities often may be mdicated by changes 

in postal receipts, bank clearings, school attendance, and other 

similar indices. 

In connection with municipal bonds, there are two factors which 
should always be borne in mind: (i) That the obligations in order 
to be legally binding must be legally issued; and (2) Legality of 
that the certificates must be genuine * and in proper cenffication as 
form. The legality of the issue of municipal bonds is '° genuineness 
taken care of usually by bankers obtaining the opinion of first-class 

1 According to the Boston News Bureau, June 12, 1914, 6g cities out of 195 having 
an estimated population of 30,000 or over have adopted the commission form of 
government. Dayton, Ohio, is given as the only city of 30,000 people or over 
having the "city manager plan." 

' State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 1914, p. 24. 

• Ibid., p. 130. 

• Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 96, p. 580; vol. 97, p. 1322. 

• Ibid., vol. 9S, p. 634. 

' See the case of forgery of town notes in Framingham, Massachusetts, Franklin 
Savings Bank v. Inhabitants of Framingham, 212 Mass. 92. 



158 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

lawyers. The genuineness of the certificates often is arranged by 
certification by some bank or trust company or, as in the case of 
town notes in Massachusetts ^ and bonds in North Dakota," Ne- 
braska,' and Texas,* by certification by some state bureau or by 
state and county ofl&cials.* 

During the past twenty-five years and especially during the past 
ten or a dozen years, there has been a large increase in the amoimt 
Increase in of county, miuucipal, and other local debt. The 
dp"af ^I'Zct accompanying table shows aggregate net debt, or 
local debt indebtedness less sinking-fund assets, and net debt 

per capita of coimties, cities, towns, villages, townships, school 
districts, and other subdivisions in the United States for 1890, 
1902, and 1913, together with percentages of increase.' 



Date 


Debt less sinking- 
fund assets 


Per cent increase 

i8go-igo2 and 

i902-igi3 


Per-capita debt 
less sinking- 
fund assets 


Per cent increase 

iSgo-igoz and 

igo2-igi3 


1890 
1902 
1913 


$925,989,603 
1,630,069,610 
3,475,954,353 


76.0 
113- 2 


5i4-79 
20.74 
35-81 


40.2 
72.6 



While practically all these increases represent the creation of 
debt for purposes which, broadly speaking, are entirely proper,^ 
and while due allowance must be made for the great growth of the 
country during this period, the amoimt of increase certainly is 

^ Acts igio, p. 616, as amended by Acts igiz, chaps. 45 and 49. See also Acts igis, 
chaps. 84 and 285. 

' Constitution of North Dakota, art. xn, sec. 187. 

' Constitution of Nebraska, art. xrr, sec. 2. 

* Acts iSgs, p. 184; Acts igoi, p. 16. Resised Civil Statutes of Texas (1911), title 
xvni, jirts. 619-625. 

^ lii Georgia, the validity of proposed bond issues is determined in advance by 
the Superior Court: and when judgment is given in the affirmative, the bonds never 
thereafter can be questioned. {Acts i5p7, p. 82; Code of the State of Georgia [1911], 
sees. 445-451.) 

^ Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Wealth, Debt, and Taxation 
(1913), vol. I, pp. 234-35. 

' For value of public properties and assets of funds, other than sinking funds, of 
counties in 1913, see Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, County Reve- 
nues, Expenditures, and Public Properties, igij (Washington, 1915), p. 29S; and for 
figures in regard to incorporated places having a population of 2500 and over, see 
Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Municipal Revenues, Expenditures, 
and Public Properties, igij (Washington, 1915), p. 336. 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS 159 

startling. During the past twelve or fifteen years, large sums have 
been expended for parks, playgrounds, and other permanent im- 
provements. It is hard to escape from the conclusion that this 
great increase in local debt is part of the general extravagance 
which characterized the period.' 

Perhaps we might say, with the likelihood of being right, that the 
increase in municipal debt in the next few, years would be propor- 
tionately less than in the past few if it were not for increasing 
the more or less general movement under way to-day lo acquire pub- 
toward the acquisition by municipalities of street rail- ^'^ utilities 
ways and of gas and electric lighting plants. We find that even in 
Massachusetts municipal ownership of electric lighting plants has 
spread to a considerable extent.'' We find in addition mimicipal 
lighting plants in Vermont, Connecticut, New York, Pennsyl- 
vania, Ohio, Michigan, Kansas, Oregon, North Carolina, and 
many other States.' ^. .^ . 

, Distnbution 

The total local debt in 1913, as given by the Umted of local 
States Census, is made up as follows: * ^ '^^^ 





Amount 


Per cent of total 


Counties 


$371,528,268 

2,985,555,484 
118,870,601 


10.7 


Cities, towns, villages, etc 


85-9 








Total 


S3y*75,954,3S3 


100. 







This shows the bulk of our local debt to be debts of cities, towns, 
and villages.* 

' For short discussion of increase in local debts of Great Britain, France, and Ger- 
many, see Hirst, Credit of Nations (Washington, 1910), pp. 39, 94, and 72. For an 
early discussion of municipal debt in the United States, see Atlantic Monthly, vol. 
xxxvm, pp. 661-73 (Charles Hale, "Mimicipal Indebtedness"). 

' See Twenty^inth Annual Report, Board of Gas and Electric Light Commissioners 
(Boston, 19 14). 

' State and City Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 1914, 
passim. The debt of local communities in Great Britain for public utilities is large. 
See Hirst, Credit of Nations (Washington, 1910), p. 45. 

* Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, igij, vol. i, p. 235. 

' The proportion which local debt bears to national and to state debt inay be 
seen from the following figures for 1913: Nation, $1,028,564,055; States, $345,942,- 
305; minor divisions, $3,475,954,353; total, $4,850,460,713. {Wealth, Debt, and Taxa- 
, turn, ipij, vol. I, p. 229.) 



l6o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Owing somewhat to the large increase in the supply of municipal 
bonds, but still more to the decline ia. the prices of all long-time, 
DecUne in high-grade bonds, municipal bonds have been selling 
apaJ^onds""' during the past two or three years at or near the low- 
1902-12 egt prices for over twenty years. The following table 

shows prices on an income basis of the bonds of some of our leading 
cities in January, 1902, and January, 191 2: — 



Cities 



Boston, Massachusetts . . . . 
New York, New York .... 
Philadelphia, Pennsylvania 

Chicago, Illinois 

Milwavikee, Wisconsin. . . . 
St. Paul, Minnesota 



Net yield 



igo2 


igiz 


3- 10% 

3 -00% 
3 -20% 

3-25% 
3 -20% 


3- 90% 
4.10% 
3 90% 
4.00% 
4- 00% 
4.00% 



If we capitalize a thirty-year 4% bond on a 3% basis, we get a 
price of 119.69 and interest; if we capitalize the same issue on a 4% 
basis, we get, of course, a price of 100 and interest. If we do the 
same thing with a twenty-year 4% bond, we get a price of 114.96 
and interest for a 3% basis and a price of 100 and interest for a 4% 
basis. These figures represent very fairly, we think, the extent of 
the decline in the prices of the leading city bonds between 1902 and 
1912.1 

The effect of the European war on the prices of municipal bonds 
has been considerable. The following prices (see table on page 
161), obtained by reducing basis prices given in dealers' 
lists to definite prices for twenty-year 4% bonds, may 
be of interest. ^ 

The prices given in the table show an average decline for the 
year of 2.43 points. 

* Prices taken from circulars of leading bond dealers for January, 1902, and Jan- 
uary, 1912. 

* The prices of New York City bonds are reduced from the New York Stock Ex- 
change prices as given in the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 99, p. 32, and 
vol. loi, p. 34. 



War prices 



COUNTY, MUNICIPAL, AND DISTRICT BONDS l6l 



Boston, Massachusetts, registered 

Providence, Rhode Island 

New York, New York 

Cleveland, Ohio 

Minneapolis, Minnesota 

Memphis, Tennessee 

Portland, Oregon 



July, 1(114 



(And interest) 

loo.oo 

100.69 

100.00 

g8.64 

99.18 

94.72 

97-31 



July, igi5 



(And interest) 
99- 32 
99-3* 
96.2s 
96.6s 
9S04 
91.59* 
9S-3S 



• Lowest oSering. 

In closing this chapter, we would give as our opinion that county, 
municipal, and district bonds are among the safest mediums of 
investment in the world. As far as the record for past performance 
goes, municipal bonds are entitled to greater con- on the whole, 
sideration than any of our state bonds except the bondfar^ ex- 
very best. To-day the laws governing the creation of ^eedingiy safe 
debt by municipal or quasi-municipal corporations are conserva- 
tive enough to make investment in the bonds of communities even 
of moderate size exceedingly safe. 



CHAPTER V 

STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 

Railroad bonds may be defined as the obligations of railroad 
Definition of Companies operating their properties usually with 
raUroad bonds steam and doing a general freight and passenger 
business. 

Such bonds may be of various kinds: that is, first mortgage, 
consolidated mortgage, general mortgage, collateral trust, deben- 

■ kinds ^^^> or income bonds. A first-mortgage bond, as its 
of raUroad name impKes, is secured by a first mortgage on all or 

a part of the property of the railroad company. A 
consoUdated-mortgage bond usually is secured by a first mortgage 
on a portion of the road and by a jimior mortgage on the rest. A 
general-mortgage bond usually is secured by a junior mortgage on 
all or most of the road. A collateral-trust bond is secured, as a rule, 
by deposit with the trustee of stocks or other bonds or both.' A 
debenture bond may be described as a long-term note without 
security other than the general credit of the company.^ An income 
bond is a bond the interest on which is payable when earned. Any 
one of the above kinds of bonds may be convertible, although the 
usual form is the convertible debenture, that is, a long-term note 
of the company convertible into stock. 

In addition to the above kinds of securities, all which may be 
Equipment Called Strictly railroad bonds, there are equipment 
bond*s*™d°hort- bonds* issucd for say 90 per cent of the cost of new 
tenn notes equipment and payable in annual or semiannual in- 

' Sometimes an entire issue of first-mortgage bonds is deposited, as in the case of 
PSre Marquette Railroad (Lake Erie & Detroit River Railway) 4^% bonds, due Au- 
gust I, 1932. The effect of this is to make the collateral-trust bonds substantially a 
first mortgage on the property covered by the collateral. 

' In Massachusetts there have been issued by various railroad companies, such as 
the Boston & Albany Railroad, the Old Colony Railroad, and the Boston & Maine 
REuhoad, so-called "plain" bonds. These bonds are debentures with a provision 
that no mortgage can be placed on the property without including the debentures. 
See Acts igij, chap. 784, sec. 15, and Acts 1854, chap. 286, sec. 3. 

* The title to the equipment rests usually with the_equipment bondholder until 
the last installment is paid oS. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 163 

stallments covering a period of perhaps ten years; terminal bonds, 
secured on freight or passenger terminal property including real 
estate, and often guaranteed by railroad companies; and short- 
term notes, having usually from one to three years to run. 

The considerations which determine the strength of railroad 
bonds are considerably different from those applying „ ., , , , 

. . ^\ •' ° Railroad bonds 

to government, state, or mumcipal bonds. The latter payable not 
classes are payable out of taxes, whereas raihroad froS property 
bonds are payable out of the property or earnings of " **™°s^ 
the corporation. 

In considering the safety of railroad bonds, the vital Leading fac- 
questionsare:- 'Xlf^^ 

(i) Relation of assets or property to debt.^ ^°^ ''°°<*s 

(2) Relation of net earnings to fixed charges. 

In case of default in interest or principal of mortgage bonds, the 
bondholders have the right to foreclose on the property, just as the 
holders of real-estate mortgages have the right in case Remedies for 
of default to foreclose on the real estate. In the case non-payment 
of default on plain or debenture bonds, the bondholders have the 
right to sue at law on the bonds and also on the coupons, but 
stand on no better footing than other imsecured creditors.^ As far 
as legal rights go, first-mortgage bondholders have the right to 
have their entire claim paid from the proceeds of foreclosure sale 
before anything goes to the holders of second-mortgage or deben- 
ture bonds. As a matter of history and practice, however, holders 
of defaulted first-mortgage bonds often have had, like other bond- 
holders, their claim satisfied in reorganization through the issue of 
new securities in place of their old bonds.' This subject will be dis- 
cussed more fully later on in this chapter. 

' In determining the strength of collateral-trust bonds or guaranteed bonds, there 
are two or more companies to be considered instead of one; that is, in the case of 
collateral-trust bonds, not only the issuing corporation, but also the corporation or 
corporations responsible for the value of the collateral; and in the case of guaranteed 
bonds, not only the issuing but the guaranteeing corporation. 

* In England the word "debenture" usually implies a charge upon the property 
of the corporation and a priority over subsequent creditors and over existing creditors 
not possessing such a charge. Depending, of course, on the terms used in each case, 
it may be said, in general, that a debenture in England partakes of the nature of an 
equitable mortgage. See Jones, Corporate Bonds and Mortgages (3d ed.), sec. 32. 

' It is to be remembered that in many railroad receiverships and reorganizations 
certain underlying issues are not in default and are not disturbed at all. 



164 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Beginning in England and in this country in an important way 
in the early thirties, the railroad business has shown an enormous 
Beginnings and almost continuous growth from that time until 
o?th?rdiroad the present. The first railroad of any importance in 
business England was the Liverpool & Manchester Railway 

opened for public traffic in 1830 "with eight of Messrs. Stevenson 
& Co.'s locomotive-engines." ' In the United States, the first im- 
portant railroad was the Baltimore & Ohio, which had in operation 
twenty-three miles of road in 1830. It was for two years thereafter 
worked with horse power. ^ Among other early railroads in the 
United States were the Boston & Providence, the Boston & Lowell, 
the Erie, the Philadelphia & Reading, and portions of the New 
York Central and Delaware & Hudson systems. A short time 
before and not long after the Civil War many of the western rail- 
roads were built, such as the Chicago, Burlington & Quincy, the 
Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul, the Chicago & Northwestern, the 
Illinois Central, the Atchison, Topeka & Santa F6, and the Union 
Pacific. In 1832, there were in operation in the United States only 
229 miles of line; in 1912, there were in operation 246,816 miles.' 

Outside of pubUc securities and possibly real estate, railroad 
securities are the best-known medium of investment throughout 
Steam railroad the civilized world. Until the past fifteen or twenty 
have bietfa years in this country, steam raihoad bonds prac- 
mSimnof tically havc divided with govermnent, state, and 
investment municipal issucs the entire bond market. 

In our opinion there are many considerations, however, which 
Conditions should prompt investors to use great care in select- 
surrounding j^g raikoad bonds. It is to be remembered: (i) that 

the railroad . ° ,.,,_., r, 

industry caU m most cases, railroads m the Umted States are en- 

for the exer- , . ^.^. , . ^i ^ • • 

dse of great gaged m a competitive busmess, that is, m any given 
lart of ' ^ territory of any considerable size, there are usually 
investors ^^q qj more important railroad systems competing 

' Alexander Gordon, A Treatise on Elemental Locomotion, etc. (London, 1836), p. $5. 

• Poor's Manual of Railroads for 1872-73, p. xxvi. The first tram-road in the 
United States was opened in 1826. It ran from the Quincy Granite Works in Massa- 
chusetts to the Neponset River and was operated with horse power. (Poor's Manual 
for i86g-7o, p. xxii.) 

' Poor's Manual of Railroads for igis. Introduction, p. cxxxvii, and Interstate 
Commerce Commission, Twenty-fifth Annual Report on the Statistics of Railways in 
fZv {/Mtted 5fii(» (Washington, 1914), p. II. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 



i6s 



with each other more or less keenly; (2) that the gross income of 
railroads, owing to the fact that it is derived in most cases largely 
from the movement of freight, may fall off a good deal in times of 
general business depression; (3) that the railroads have been and 
are now subject to dual and more or less conflicting regulation by 
federal and state authorities; (4) that, owing to a variety of causes, 
the cost of financing and operating the railways, particularly during 
the past fifteen years, has risen without the railways having been 
able to obtain a sufl&cient increase in earnings to offset the increased 
cost. These conditions, combined in many cases with incapable or 
dishonest management, have led from time to time to very unfortu- 
nate results for investors. 

With a few notable exceptions — of which we may mention now 
the New York Central, the Pennsylvania, the Chicago, Burlington 
& Ouincy, the Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul, and „ . 

^ -" ' ° ' ' Receiverships 

the Illinois Central — the important railroad systems and reorgani- 
now serving the United States have been in the hands 
of receivers or have been reorganized, in whole or in part, from one 
to three times. Out of a total bonded debt for aU roads, January i, 
187s, of about $2,000,000,000, there were in default at some time 
between September 20, 1873, and January i, 1876, bonds amount- 
ing to $783,967,665.1 The following table " shows the number, 
mileage and total capitalization of railroads placed in the hands of 
receivers for the years involving the largest total capitalization 
from 1876: — 



Year 



Number of roads 



Miles 0} road 



Bonds and stocks 



1876 

1884 

1893 
1908 

1913 
191S 



42 
37 
74 
24 

17 
12 



6,662 

11,038 

29,340 

8,009 

g,020 

20,143 



$467,000,000 
714,755.000 

1,781,046,000 
596,359,000 
477,780,820 

1,070,808,628 



On June 30, 1894, there were in the hands of receivers 192 rail- 
ways operating 40,819 miles of road and with a total capitalization 

1 Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 22, p 76. 

• Railway Age Gazette, December 31, 1915 (vol. 59), p. 1222. 



l66 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

of about $2,500,000,000.' The roads in the hands of receivers at 
this time operated nearly one fourth of the mileage and had nearly 
one fourth of the total capitalization of all the railroads in the 
United States.^ In October, 1915, there were in the hands of re- 
ceivers 41,988 miles of road with a total capitalization of $2,264,- 
002,178.' 

A variety of causes may be given to account for these experi- 
ences, but the leading reasons may be given as follows: (i) Over- 
building of railroads or building ahead of the growth 
of railroad of the country; ^ (2) heavy bonded debts and fixed 

trou es charges; (3) unrestrained competition; (4) increased 

costs of labor, materials, and supplies, and increased taxes; (5) 
mismanagement, misjudgment, or lack of integrity of those in con- 
trol; (6) excessive interference on the part of legislatures, commis- 
sions, and other government bodies; (7) the industrial depressions 
following the panics of 1873, 1884, 1893, and 1907.^ 

.„ , . , A brief statement* of some of the forms which rail- 

Difficulties of . ..,..,, 

individual road difficulties took m cases 01 certam mdividual 

railroads may be of interest. (See page 167). 

Since the receiverships following 1893, there have been two 

periods in which railroad difliculties have become of considerable 

importance: one after the panic of 1907, when such roads as the 

* Interstate Commerce Commission, Seventh Annual Report on the Statistics of 
Railways in the United States (Washington, 1895), p. 10. 

' Ibid., pp. 12 and 41. 

' Railway Age Gazette, October 15, 1915 (vol. S9)> p. 6y6. The figures include 
two small Canadian roads. 

• Between 1870 and 1885, the total miles of road in the United States increased 
from 52,922 miles to 128,320 miles, or over 142 per cent; between i88o and 1895, a 
period of fifteen years, the total mileage increased from 93,262 miles to 181,115 miles, 
or over 94 per cent. (See Introduction to Poor's Manual of Railroads for igiz, p. 
cxxxvii.) 

■i See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 22, p. 76; Investors' Supplement 
of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, October 25, 1884, p. i; Introduction to 
Poor's Manual of Railroads for 1885, pp. v to x; Investors' Supplement of the Com- 
mercial and Financial Chronicle, March 31, 1894, p. 2; Poor's Manual of Railroads 
for i8qs, pp. V to viii. (The depression of 1913 and the effect of the European War 
might be added.) 

' The material for the accompanying table has been taken from Stuart Daggett, 
Railroad Reorganization (Boston and New York, 1908), pp. 16-17, 20-22, 34-40, 
48, SI, S3-S4, 58-59, 61, 75, 77, 81, 96-101, 118, 121-26, 158, 164, 166-68, 175-78, 
193, 196-97, 199, 202, 204-09, 221-24, 228-29, 231-33. 235-36, 240, 264-65, 267, 
280-81, 284, 286-87, 289. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 



167 



Raikoad 



Date 



Erie. 

(NewYork&ErieR.R.) 



(Erie Railway.) 



(New York, Lake Erie 
& Western Railroad.) 



Nofthem Pacific Rail 
road. 



Philadelphia fir Reading 
Railroad. 



Form of failure. 



Atchison, Topeka &• 
Satiia Fi Railroad. 



Southern system. 

(Richmond & W.P. 
Terminal Ry. & Ware- 
house. Richmond & 
Danville R.R. Central 
RR.& Bkg. of Georgia.) 

Union Pacific Railway. 



BaUimore &• Ohio Rail- 
road, 



1842 
187s 



1884 
1893 

187s 
1893 

1880 
1884 
1893 

1889 
1893 

1892 
1893 

1896 



Causes of trouble 



Assignment. 
Receivership. 

Receivership. 



Default followed by reor- 
ganization without re- 
ceivership or foreclosure. 

Rewiver^ip. 



Receivership. 
Receivership. 

Receiverdiip. 
Receivership. 
Receivership. 



Reoi^nizatioD without 
receivership or foreclo- 
sure. 

Receivership. 



Receiverships. 



Receivership. 



Receivership. 



Difficulty of getting enterprise under 

way. 
Rate war with N.Y. Central. Heavy 
storms and ice floods, 1857. Panic of 
1857 and depression which followed. 
Gross overcapitalization and waste of 
assets under Gould and Fisfc._ Inade- 
quacy of previous reorganizations. 
Severe competition. Falsification Of 
accounts and payment of dividends 
not earned. Six-foot gauge. 
Heavy capitalization of previous reor- 
ganization. Irregularities. Failiure 
of Grant & Ward. 
Failure of previous reorganization to 
reduce fixed charges sufficiently. Pro- 
hibition of pooling. Unprofitable 
lease of the N.Y., Penn. & Ohio. 
Lack of population and business in ter- 
ritory served. Failure of Jay Cooke 
& Co. before completion of the road. 
Extensive building and purchase of un- 
profitable branches. Unprofitable 
leases. Unwise distributions to stock- 
holders. 
Heavy capitalization. Excessive and 
undiscriminating purchases of coal 
lands. 
Inefficiency of previous reorganization. 
Unprofitable leases and purchases. 
Payment of dividends not earned. 
Lack of profit in coal-holdings of the 
Philadelphia & Reading Coal & Iron 
Company. Unprofitable leases. Pur- 
chases of stock of the Boston & 
Maine Railroad and other New Eng- 
land railroads to an extent not justi- 
fied by the resources of the Reading. 
Competitive overbuilding and exten- 
sions into thinly settled territory. 

Overexpansion, including acquisition of 
the St. Louis & San Francisco Rail- 
road. Conversion of income bonds of 
previous reorganization into bonds 
carrying a fixed charge. Misrepresen- 
tation of the earnings and true condi- 
tion of the company. 

Large part of mileage unprofitable. 
Poor physical condition. Graft and 
mismanagement. 



High original cost of construction, in- 
cluding the Credit Mobilier scandal. 
Consolidation with the Kansas Pacific 
and Denver Pacific Railroads on ab- 
surd terms, and acquisition of other 
lines at the dictation and for the 
{>rofit of Jay Gould. Severe compe- 
tition. Rapid extension of unprofitable 
branch line mileage. 
Excessive competition, tbtough rate- 
cutting and other methods, leading 
to a ^adual weakening of the whole 
financial structure of the company. 
Irregularities of those in control. 
Payment of dividends not earned. 



l68 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Seaboard Air Line, Chicago Great Western, Western Maryland, 
and Wabash were placed in the hands of receivers; 

Railroad diffi- , ,. ^ , ,^^.„_ 

cuities 1907 and another ui 1913 to 1915, when the St. Louis & San 
1913 191 prancisco, Cincinnati, Hamilton & Dayton, Interna- 
tional & Great Northern, Rock Island, Missouri Pacific, Missouri, 
Kansas & Texas, and many other roads were placed in the hands 
of receivers.* The difficulties of these railroads have been too 
recent to make possible a careful and impartial statement of the 
special causes of failure. 

A consideration of the specific causes of many of our earlier rail- 
road troubles shows that these difficulties were caused partly by 

the general conditions surrounding railroad operation 
causes of rail- and partly by the lack of judgment or unscrupulous 

management of those who controlled the properties. 
Just how far one set of causes and how far the other affected the 
results in any given case it is impossible to say. 

In 1887, a step was taken which has led already to important 
restraints on the management of railroads by private interests. 
^ . vf V . This was the establishment of the Interstate Com- 

Establisnment , , . . , ... 

of the merce Commission.^ Originally this commission sim- 

Commerce ply heard cases of alleged unjust discrimination in 

ommission service and rates, and the Commission found most of 

these cases to be not well founded.' 

Later the Commission received additional powers. In 1906, it 

obtained the power not merely to set aside existing 

Increase in ., , . 

powers of the railroad rates as imjust or unreasonable, but to estab- 
ommissiou ^^-^ ^^^ ones.* In 1910, it obtained authority to sus- 

' In October, 1915, it seems reasonable to say that the raikoads as a whole have 
"turned the comer," for the time being, from their most acute troubles. 

^ An act to regulate commerce, approved February 4, 1887, and in effect April 5, 
1887 (24 Stat. L. 379), as amended by an act approved March z, 1889 (25 Stat. L. 
855) ; by an act approved February 10, 1891 (26 Stat. L. 743) ; by an act approved 
February 8, 1895 (28 Stat. L. 643); by an act approved June 29, 1906 (34 Stat. L. 
584); by a joint resolution approved June 30, 1906 (34 Stat. L. 838); by an act ap- 
proved April 13, 1908 (35 Stat. L. 60); by an act approved February 25, 1909 (35 
Stat. L. 648); by an act approved June 18, 1910 (36 Stat. L. 539); by an act approved 
August 24, 1912 (37 Stat. L. 566); by an act approved March i, 1913 (37 Stat. L. 
701). See U.S. Compiled Statutes (1913), vol. 4, Title lviA, chap. A, sees. 8563-8604. 

' See Charles Lee Raper, Railway Transportation (New York and London, 1912) 
p. 264. Also Reports, Interstate Commerce Commission, passim. 

* Act approved June 29, 1906 (34 Stat. L. 584). 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 69 

pend changes in rates pending a hearing. 1 This power to suspend 
rates is the power of which the railroad managers have complained 
at times so bitterly. The Commission in these matters may act on 
its own initiative. 

In addition to the regulation exercised by the Interstate Com- 
merce Commission, there has been an immense amount of regula- 
tion and attempted regulation by state legislatures ^^ uiation b 
and later by state public-service commissions. Accord- state legis- 
ing to James J. Hill: "Within three years, ending in pubUc-service 
1907, twenty-five States enacted car-service laws,^ commissions 
twenty- three regulated train service and connections, twenty- two 
fixed maximum passenger rates, nine enacted maximimi freight 
rates, thirty-six regulated the general corporate affairs of common 
carriers." * To be included, perhaps, in the last-named class of 
legislation may be mentioned laws forbidding combination and con- 
solidation, compelling changes in construction of road or rolling- 
stock, and shortening the hours of labor of employees.* Many of 
these laws were enacted without any adequate examination or 
proper understanding of their fairness, and many of them later 
were declared xmconstitutional by the courts.* 

In general it may be said that, under present conditions, the rela- 
tion of steam railroads to the public is in great confusion. Unhke 
street-railway, gas, and electric light properties lo- j^gi^^ji^^Qf 
Gated wholly within one State, most of the steam rail- steam raikoads 
roads are subject to regulation both by the Federal is in great 
Government and by individual States. The viewpoint '^° "^'°° 
of the railroad men is expressed as follows: "A misdirected public 
opinion is demanding rates too low, taxes too high, wages too high, 
service too elaborate, and there are not cents enough in the dollar 
to meet all these demands and still permit the business to be attrac- 
tive enough so the man with a dollar will invest it." ® It is to be 

' Act approved June 18, 1910 (36 Stat. L. 539, sec. 12). 

' For a discussion by railroad interests of the so-called "full-crew laws," see 
Bureau of Railway Economics, The Arguments for and against Train-Crew Legisla- 
tion (Washington, D.C., 1915), consecutive no. 73. 

' James J. Hill, Highways of Progress (New York, igio), p. 272. 

< For citation of some of these laws, see Appendix, pp. 305-306. 

' For examples of such laws which have been held unconstitutional, see Appen- 
lix, pp. 306-307. 

' Howard Elliott, The Truth About the Railroads (Boston and New York, 1913), 

pp. IS4-SS- 



I70 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

noted that at least three different bodies are in a position to inter- 
fere with the net income of raihroads: that is, (i) the Interstate 
Commerce Commission may suspend or reduce rates; (2) the state 
legislatures or commissions may reduce rates and may prescribe 
regulations which will increase expenses; and (3) arbitration boards 
may raise wages. * 

Furthermore, the regulation of any given railroad by the States 
through which its lines run may conflict, not only as to service and 
rates, but in the matter of issue of new securities. 
States of issues Interstate railroads under present conditions some- 
o secun les tij^gs have to obtain the authority of two or more 
States in order to finance themselves. Examples of this may be 
found in our New England railroads, where, for instance, the con- 
sent of New York State as well as of Massachusetts is necessary 
for the issue of bonds by the Boston & Albany Railroad; of Maine, 
New Hampshire, and Massachusetts for the issue of securities by 
the Boston & Maine Railroad; and of Massachusetts and New 
York for security issues by the New York, New Haven & Hartford 
Railroad. 2 

In view of the fact that interstate traffic, according to James J. 
HiU, constitutes from 65 to 97 per cent of the total traffic over 
large areas of the cotmtry,' and in view of the diffi- 
probiemmay* culty of distinguishing between state and interstate 
by theTedeiai traffic,^ it would Seem that the final solution of this 
Government difficult qucstion lies in some form of control by the 

alone Ai i 

Federal Government alone. 
A step in this direction was attempted in the decision of Judge 
Sanborn, of the United States Circuit Court, in the so-called 
Minnesota Rate Cases.* The legislature of the State of Minnesota 

' Arbitration, however, is not compulsory. See "An Act providing for mediation, 
conciliation, and arbitration in controversies between certain employers and their 
employees," approved July 15, 1913 (Public Laws of the United States of America 
r63d Cong., ist Sess., 1913], chap. 6, 38 Stat. L. part i, p. 103). 

' Maine, Laws 1913, chap. 129, sec. 35; Massachusetts, Acts igi3, chap. 784, 
sec. 16; New Hampshire, Laws zgil, chap. 164, sec. 14a, as amended by Laws 1913, 
chap. 14s, sec. 14; New York, Consolidated Laws of the State of New York (1910), 
vol. DC, chap. 48, sec. sSt and chap. 49, sec. 8, par. 10. 

' Highways of Progress, p. 280. See also Raper, Railway Transportation, p. 252. 

* See Marshall M. Kirkman, Railway Rjdes and Government Control (Chicago & 
New York, 1892), pp. 295-301. 

» Shepard s. No. Pac. Ry. Co., 184 Fed. 763. (1911.) 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 171 

had enacted statutes reducing passenger fares within that State 
about 33^ per cent and reducing freight charges on Decision of 
certam commodities withm the State about 7.37 per jn'MinneJota 
cent. By orders of the Minnesota Railroad and Ware- ^^'^ ^^^^ 
house Commission, general merchandise freight charges on ship- 
ments wholly within the State were reduced by from 20 to 25 per 
cent, and certain specific charges on freight shipped from distribut- 
ing points just within the border of the State to other points in 
the State were reduced. Suits were brought by shareholders of the 
raikoads affected involving the question whether the orders of ihe 
commission, and the acts of the legislature described, substantially 
burdened and regulated interstate commerce on the railroads of 
these companies. Judge Sanborn found that " each of the acts and 
orders challenged has the natural and necessary effect substantially 
to burden and directly to regulate interstate commerce, to create 
undue and unjust discriminations between localities in Minnesota 
and those in adjoining States, and it is unconstitutional and void." 
He said further: "To the extent necessary completely and effectu- 
ally to protect the freedom of and to regulate interstate commerce 
the nation by its Congress and its courts may affect and regulate 
intrastate commerce, but no farther. To the extent that it does not 
substantially burden or regulate interstate commerce a State may 
regulate the intrastate commerce within its own borders, but no 
farther. If the plenary power of the nation to protect 'the freedom 
of and to regulate interstate comanerce and the attempted exercise 
by a State of its power to regulate intrastate commerce, or the 
attempted exercise of any of its other powers, impinge or conflict, 
the former must prevail and the latter must give way, because the 
Constitution and the acts of Congress passed in pursuance thereof 
are the supreme law of the land, and ' that which is not supreme 
must yield to that which is supreme-'" This decision, it seems to 
us, would have the practical effect of giving the Federal Govern- 
ment substantial control of almost ah railroads. 

The decision later was reversed by th§ United States Supreme 

Court ^ in an opinion delivered by Mr. Justice Hughes. The court 

took the position that (i) although the power of Congress over 

interstate commerce is paramount, and (2) although a State has 

> Simpson et d. v. Sbepard, 230 U.S. 352. (1913.) 



172 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

no power to regulate directly interstate commerce, and (3) al- 
Decision of the *^°"sli> whcncver CongTcss exercises its power over 
United States interstate commerce in any respect, no state action 

Supreme Court , i • i it ..,.,, 

intheMinne- of any kind Can modify or unpair directly or m- 
sota Rate Cases (jjj.g(,j.iy g^jj national action, yet (4) the several 

States have power, in the absence of action by the Federal Govern- 
ment, to regulate their own intrastate commerce and (5) state 
regulation of intrastate commerce is not void by reason merely of 
its indirect effect on interstate commerce, unless it conflicts with 
some actual exercise by Congress of the national power over inter- 
state commerce. 

In the Shreveport Rate Cases, ^ in which also the opinion was 
deUvered by Mr. Justice Hughes, the court took the position that 
Comparison of where the Interstate Commerce Commission previ- 
shreveport^"'^ ously had fixed an interstate rate on a basis higher 
Rate Cases ^gj^ ^j^Q^^_ permitted by the State of Texas for intra- 
state rates, the interstate rate should prevail. In the Minnesota 
cases, the railroads could avoid that "unjust discrimination" 
which Congress had forbidden by reducing their interstate rates to 
the basis of the Minnesota intrastate rates; but in the Shreveport 
cases, the railroads could not do this, because the rate already fixed 
by the paramoimt national authority was higher than that allowed 
by the state authorities. The only alternative was to disregard the 
Texas intrastate rates. 

We have discussed these two cases rather fully for the reasons 
that they are both fairly recent and also because they bring out the 
Significance of ever-recurring difficulties of harmonizing state and 
Court decSilns federal control of railroad rates. While the two deci- 
in the two cases gjons of the Supreme Court are not inconsistent, it 
may be fair to say that in one case emphasis is laid on the state 
power over rates, whereas in the other it is laid on the federal 
power over rates. 

A possible escape from this situation may be either (i) the fed- 
„ , ... eral licensing of all railroads doing an interstate busi- 

Federal license / \ , r t ■, • • r n • 

or federal ness or (2) the federal mcorporation of all mterstate 

mcorpora on j-aUroads. Under the first plan, the railroads would 

> Houston, East & West Texas Railway et al. v. United States et at., 234 U.S. 
342. (1914-) 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 73 

retain their state charters, but would obtain permission to do an 
interstate business only on such terms as the Federal Government 
might impose, which permission might amount practically to exclu- 
sive federal regulation. Under the second plan, the railroads doing 
an interstate business could get rid entirely of state regulation. In 
the words of the former Commissioner of Corporations, "The one 
merit of the federal incorporation plan is that it is based upon a 
clean-cut, legal theory, that it brings the entire matter of interstate 
commerce under one jurisdiction, and reduces to a minimum the 
friction that must occur between federal and state authorities in 
the attempt on the part of the Federal Government to regulate 
interstate commerce." ^ Either federal licensing or federal incor- 
poration of the interstate railroads would be a long step toward 
exclusive federal control of all the railroads, and therefore toward 
the solution of this phase of the railroad problem. 

We have spoken of exclusive federal control as probably the best 
solution of this conflict between federal and state authority over 
the railroads. We have suggested federal licensing or Government 
federal incorporation of interstate railways. There is ownership , 
another alternative. That alternative is government ownership.^ 

Government ownership may work out in two ways: (i) Owner- 
ship and operation by the Government; (2) ownership by the 
Government and lease to private companies for oper- „ 

r- r I- Government 

ation. This latter method was recommended in 1881 ownership may 
by an Italian commission which investigated the 
entire subject of government ownership in practically all coun- 
tries.^ In general, however, we will discuss government ownership 
as being sjoionymous with government operation. 

' Report, Commissioner of Corporations, December, 1904, Appendix C, pp. 61 
and 62. 

2 The only experiments which the United States Government has made along 
these lines are: (i) Panama Railroad, which the Government piirchased in 1904 and 
has since operated, and (2) the proposed federal railway in Alaska. Neither of these 
experiments is likely to be of any particular significance in connection with the broad 
question of government ownership. (For Panama Railroad, see Poor's Manual of 
Railroads for igi5, pp. 1912-13, and Annual Reports of the Panama Railway Com- 
pany. For act authorizing the President of the United States to locate, construct, 
and operate railroads in the Territory of Alaska, approved March 12 1914, see 
Public Laws of the United States of America, no. 69, 63d Congress, 38 Stat. L., part j, 

p. 30S-) 
• Raper, Railway TransportoHon, pp. 109-10. 



174 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The extent to which government ownership of railroads prevails 
throughout the world is not, perhaps, fully appreciated. In 
Europe, out of the total mileage in 1912 of 207,295 
government milcs, 107,663 miles, or SI. 9 per cent, were state- 
owners p owned.' Great Britain was the only important 
European country which had no state-owned railways. In Asia, 
58 per cent of the mileage, in Africa, 59.7 per cent, and in Aus- 
tralasia, 93.6 per cent of the mileage was state-owned. The total 
mileage of the world for 1912 was 639,621 miles, of which 188,258 
miles were state-owned.^ This becomes even more striking when we 
remember that the United States alone in 1912 had 241,056 miles 
of road, all privately owned. 

There are many strong arguments in favor of government 
ownership and operation of all the railways in the United States. 
Arguments in In Order to get the bearing of the whole subject on 
goveri^ent raihoad credit, we will summarize the leading argu- 
pwpership ments as follows: (i) It would do away forever 

with the perplexing conflict between federal and state regulation; 
(2) it would solve the still more dif&cult problem of trying to 
prevent by regulation so-called discrinunation between persons 
and places and yet at the same time forcing under the Sherman 
Act ' competition between the railroads; (3) it might lead to a 
comprehensive if not entirely economical use of railroads and water- 
ways for the benefit of the whole country; (4) it would put an 
end to the immense railroad lobby system by which in the past 
attempts, too often successful, have been made to influence legis- 
latures and courts; (5) it would lead, if properly managed, to 
a greater standardization of service; (6) it should result in elimi- 
nation of many expenses at present necessary to the railroads, such 
as complete executive staffs for each railroad and solicitors whose 
business is simply to get freight for one railroad as against another; 

' Out of a total mileage of 37,973 in Germany, 34,604, or gi.i per cent, was state- 
owned; in France out of a total mileage qI 39^668 only 5,509, or 18 per cent was 
state-owned. 

' Figures from London Times, October i, 1912, p. 15 ("The World's Railwaj^"), 
and based on Archiv fiir Eisenbahnwesen, May and June, 1912, published by the 
Prussian Ministry of Public Works, Berlin. See also Samuel O. Dunn, Government 
Ownership of Railways (New York and Londo^, 1915), pp. 381-84. 

' See act approved July 2, 1890, 26 Stat. L. 2og,US. Compiled Statutes (igoi), vqL 
3, p. 3200. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS I75 

(7) it might make less difficult the raising of the immense amounts 
of new capital which almost all railroad men agree are necessary in 
order that the railroads may perform adequate service; (8) it 
might have, if properly handled, the effect of knitting together the 
country still more closely than at present and of bringing the people 
in closer touch with the Government. Some of these objects could 
be attained, to be sure, without govenmient ownership, but they 
all might be accomplished under that system. 

Against government ownership and operation of railroads in the 
United States at the present time may be urged the following: 
(i) Operation of the railways by the Government Arguments 
probably would result, as it has in Europe, in a set of gOTe°rment 
rules or principles for service and rates too rigid prop- owne'si^P 
erly to serve and develop the country; (2) allowing for the loss 
in taxes, it would probably result, as it has in most European 
countries, with the possible exception of Germany, either in 
a net loss or a very slight profit from operation; (3) there is no 
reason to suppose that it would result, any more than it has in 
Europe, in better freight service or in lower freight rates; (4) it 
would place over 1,800,000 men,' the present employees of the 
railroads, with their families, imder possible political domination, 
a situation likely to result in injustice to the men and in danger 
to our system of government; (5) it would entail on the Federal 
Government the creation of a huge debt, the safety of which would 
depend to a large extent on ihe success with which the railroads 
were operated; (6) the strongly individualistic character of our 
people, the complicated structure of our government, and the 
many widely scattered large centers of wealth and population, as 
against the highly centralized conditions in such coxmtries as 
France and Germany, would indicate less success for government 
ownership in this country even than in Europe; (7) until regula- 
tion has been tried thoroughly on the most intelligent and most 
modem lines government ownership is imnecessary. 

The experience with state-operated railways in Europe and else- 
where has not been of a kind to induce the United „ , 

, Results of 

States to enter on the expenment. The most sue- state operation 

cessful state railways abroad have been the Prus- '" ^°^ 

' Interstate Commerce Commission, Twenty-sixth Annwtl Report of the Statistics of 
Railways, p. 23. 



176 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

sian. These have been operated so as to give excellent and cheap 
passenger service, fair freight service, and so as to show to the Gov- 
ernment a considerable net income above all charges. They have 
been managed with all the military efficiency of the Prussian Govern- 
ment. It is questionable whether the operation of the Prussian rail- 
ways has been for the best interests of iadustry and commerce.^ 
The state railways of Japan, with practically the lowest freight and 
passenger rates of any railways in existence, have been operated 
with distinct financial success. This has been made possible by 
the efficiency of the Government and by the low cost of Uving.* 
The operation of the state lines in Italy, whatever the reasons, has 
been so far notably unsuccessful in almost aU respects.' The op- 
eration of the state railways in Austria has not resulted in par- 
ticularly low rates and it has resulted in a net loss to the Govern- 
ment.'* The Hungarian state railways usually have earned less 
than their interest. The same is true to a greater or less degree 
of the state railways in France, Russia, Belgium, Canada, Argen- 
tina, and even Germany, outside the Prussia-Hesse lines.* The 
Swiss state-operated railways have sought to please all the people 
by lowering rates, increasing faciUties, and raising wages. Roads 
which under corporate management had been making a good 
showing have shown imder ten years of govenunent administra- 
tion a deficit.® On all state operated railways, except possibly in 
Prussia and Japan, the tendency has been to increase the ntun- 
ber of employees beyond all reason.^ It is perhaps fair to say that, 
with the exception of Prussia and Japan, state operation has not 
justified itself on economic groimds.* On political grounds, it may 
have done so, though this always wiU be a matter of opinion.^ 

' Dunn, Government Ownership of Railways, pp. 130, 310-13, 325; Raper, Railway 
Transportation, pp. 143, 150, 155, 164, 303; Logan G. McPherson, Transportation in 
Europe (New York, 1910), pp. 168-69. 

» Dunn, pp. 296, 313-14, 324-26. 

» Dunn, pp. 315-16; Raper, pp. no, 119-20; McPherson, pp. 173-75. 

* Dunn, p. 317; Raper, p. 295; McPherson, p. 173. ' Dunn, pp. 303-30. 

' McPherson, pp. 172, 200. For a doubt raised as to whether the Swiss state rail- 
ways have shown a net profit or a net deficit, see Dunn, p. 324. 

' McPherson, pp. 199-200. 

' For another statement of financial results of government operation in Germany, 
France, Belgiimi, Holland, Switzerland, Russia, Austria-Hungary, and Italy, see 
McPherson, pp. 168-75. 

' The great war in Europe has led to military or govenunent operation of most of 
the railways in the countries at war. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 177 

Regulation is not open to many of the objections that apply to 
government ownership. It has been in Great Britain and in the 
United States a natural development and one con- Regulation not 
sistent with the individual initiative of the people open to many 
and the democratic nature of their government, tions to govem- 
While the principles and methods of regulation to be °""' "^^-^^i-ip 
applied have at times been in great confusion, the broad outlines 
to-day are becoming pretty well defined. 

Regulation in Great Britain, where all the railways are privately 
owned, has been based on practical expediency. In Great Britain 
and Ireland, the railways are under the supervision „ , ,. . 

, . . „ , , -r. M , ^ , /-I Regulation m 

01 a commission called the Railway and Canal Com- Great Britain 

. . , . r. . , , and Ireland 

mission, composed of five members, servmg a term 
of five years: two members appointed by the Crown and three 
ex-officio. Of the appointed members one must be an expert on 
railway transportation. The ex-officio members are, in England, 
the Lord Chancellor; in Scotland, the Lord President^of the Court 
of Session; and in Ireland, the Lord Chancellor of Ireland. These 
ofl&cials can in each case designate a judge of the highest court to 
serve on the Railway and Canal Commission. The Commission at 
work must be composed of the two appointed members and one 
ex-offi^io, the former to be judges of fact and the latter of law. Regu- 
lation in Great Britain has tended toward the monopoly prin- 
ciple and has gone on the basis of minimum interference with the 
operation of the railways. It has been, on the whole, fairly eflident 
and satisfactory.* 

In France, where nearly five sixths of the mileage is operated 
by private companies,'' the railways are under the control of the 
Ministry of Public Works. Attached to this Ministry Regulation 
are six departments, one for each of the large systems '° France 
including that operated by the State. Supervision is divided on 
the lines of (i) technical control; (2) commercial control; (3) finan- 
cial control. There is a commercial advisory coimcil in which two 

* Raper, pp. 52, 55, 58, 100, 212. See also Dunn, pp. 17-ig. 

* In France, the Government has made large advances in the cases of the privately 
owned railways in the form of guarantees of interest and dividends. By the end of 
1938, unless present plans are changed, all the railways will be amortized and will 
become the property of the Government without compensation. (Raper, pp. 72-73; 
Dimn, pp. 20-22.) 



178 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

elements'are represented: (i) liie Government; (2) commercial and 
industrial interests and the general public. French control of the 
railways has paid more attention to abstract justice than to prac- 
tical expediency. It has represented, perhaps, the masdmvim of 
interference. Supervision has covered all important matters of 
operation and finance, including the approval of the issue of new 
securities. French control of the railways has been strong and 
effective, but has been too much inclined to act with rigid uni- 
formity.' 

We have outlined the systems of regulation in Great Britain 

and France for the sake of the light they may throw on our own 

railroad problems. These two countries are the only 

Europe has '^ , •' 

much to teach ones of unportance in Europe havmg a large railroad 
regulation mileage under private operation. Germany, Italy, 

o rai ways ^^^ Russia, in their machinery for the state operation 
of their railways, have many points of interest to any one attempt- 
ing to outline a plan of exclusive federal regulation for railways in 
the United States. 

There have been recently many suggestions, some of them based 
on European models, of plans for regulating the railways. There 
interstate ^^ ^ general agreement that the Interstate Commerce 

Commerce Commission, with its membership limited as at pres- 

Commission , ' ^ ^ 

at present eut, IS physically unable to consider and solve the 

to handle vast and complicated problems arising from the 

epro em financing and operation of something like 250,000 
miles of railroad, traversing forty-eight States, and serving a 
population in the neighborhood of 100,000,000. In its magnitude 
OutKne for ^'^'^ ™ ^^ Complexity, the problem is entirely dif- 
exciusive fed- ferent from that of regulation of railroads in such 
in the United a territory as that of Great Britain. 
^^^ A possible outline for exclusive federal regulation, 

at least of all interstate railways, is as follows: * 

(i) Enlarging the membership of the Interstate Commerce Commis- 
sion so as to include men experienced in railroad operation, traffic 

' Raper, pp. 95 and 100; Dunn, pp. 19-24. 

• See Samuel Rea, as quoted in the Annalist (New York), vol. 4, p. 442. E. P. 
Ripley, as quoted in the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. gg, p. 1334. See also 
Annalist, vol. 4, p. 392. Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 99, pp. 1505, 1509; 
Raper, Railway Transportation, passim; McPheison, Transportation in Europe. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 79 

and finance and also men of broad business experience. This would 
be thoroughly in line with the machinery used in some form of 
other in France, Germany, Italy, and Russia. 

(2) Making the term of office for a long period of years and the com- 
pensation sufficient to attract and retain men of the widest experi- 
ence and greatest ability. 

(3) Dividing the United States into sections for railroad supervision 
much as the national banking system has been divided under the 
Federal Reserve Act. Such units as the Interstate Commerce 
Commission uses in reporting statistics of the railways or any other 
convenient units could be used. This division of territory would 
follow the precedents set in France, Germany, and Italy. 

(4) Compelling the railroads to give reasonably efficient service. 

(s) Allowing combination and consolidation of railroad properties 
where such action will lead to improved service or lower rates. 

(6) Allowing the railroads to charge rates ^ for their services which will 
insure efficient and economical operation, allow reasonable provi- 
sion for maintenance, depreciation, and obsolescence, and give a 
return to the security-holders sufficient to make possible the rais- 
ing of new capital. 

(7) Having Congress refer to the Interstate Commerce Commission 
for investigation and report legislation concerning service, rates, 
wages, and other matters affecting the net income of the railways. 

(8) Limiting the power to suspend rates without a hearing to a period 
not over sixty days, after which, unless otherwise ordered, advanced 
rates shall become effective. 

(9) Supervision by the Interstate Conamerce Commission when effec- 
tively organized of tie issue of new securities including amounts to 
be issued and the purposes for which the money is to be spent.* 

(10) Publicity of accounts. 

This general plan could be modified as experience showed its 
defects. The adoption of some such plan would increase greatly 
the safety of railroad bonds. 

In the matter of giving the Interstate Commerce Sarsuper- 
Conrniission or some other federal body the authority y>sion of the 

..... issue of new 

to supervise the issue of new secunties, it is mterest- securities 

• For eonfirmation by the United States Supreme Court of broad supervisory 
power of the Interstate Commerce Commission over rates, see the so-called Inter- 
mountain Rate Cases, decided June 22, 1914. (United States of America, Interstate 
Commerce Commission et al., v. Atchison, Topeka & Santa F6 Ry. Co. et al., 234 
U.S. 476). 

* See Twenty-eighth Animal Report, Interstate Commerce Commission, part i, p. 6$. 



l8o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

ing to note that such diverse interests as Mr. James J. Hill, on 
the one hand, and the National Association of Railway Commis- 
sioners, on the other, agree as to the wisdom of this.^ 

Regulation of rates — the only other point in this programme 

of regulation which we will discuss at the present time — is the 

crux of the whole "railroad question." In the regu- 

Rates must be. ii-ii •!• 

reasonable and lation of rates the fundamental considerations are 
compensatory ^-^ofold: (i) The rates must be just and reasonable; 
(2) they must not be so low as to be confiscatory. Neither the 
States nor Congress itself can force a railroad company to serve 
the public without just compensation. What rates are reasonable 
and what rates give a fair return to the railroads are questions 
very difficult to decide.^ 

The basis of rate-making in the United States, before authority 
was given to the Interstate Commerce Commission to change 
Bases of rates, was to charge shippers all that the traffic would 

rate-making bear, in connection, of course, with whatever compe- 
tition a given railroad had to meet. Since the grant of authority 
to the Commission over rates, there has been more of a tendency 
than formerly to use the cost-of-service principle as a basis for 
rates. This is very largely the practice on the state-owned railways 
in Europe. Charging what the traffic will bear usually is best 
adapted to developing the country, but it is likely to lead to dis- 
criminations; ^ charging on the basis of the cost of the service is 
likely to be too rigid to allow for the proper growth and develop- 
ment of the country. 

Very often not only what is a proper rate, but what is a possible 
rate has to be decided. In discussing the limits of high and low 
raihoad rates, Mr. James J. Hill has called attention to the fol- 

* Highways of Progress, p. 136. Report of the Committee on Railway Capitali- 
zation, Proceedings of the Twenty-fifth Annual Convention of the National Asso- 
ciation of Railway Commissioners (Washington), pp. 212-13. 

' See Constitution of the United States, Amendment v and Amendment xiv, sec. i. 
Act February 4, 1887, Stat. L., chap. 104, sec. i, p. 379. U.S. Comp. Stats. 1913, sec. 
8563, and the following of the many cases dealing with this question: Smythe v. Ames, 
169 U.S. 466; Lake Shore & Michigan Southern Railway Co. v. Smith, 173 U.S. 684; 
and Interstate Commerce Commission v. Brimson, 154 U.S. 447. 

' As Mr. Hill has remarked, railroad rates in a wheat country must insure the 
profitable raising and sale of wheat, and in a lumber country they must favor the 
Ixmiber industry. This is discrimination, but it is discrimination for the purpose of 
developing the country. Q. J. Hill, Highways of Progress, pp. 256-58.) 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS l8l 

lowing principles: (i) That the raikoad must obtain a rate which, 
in addition to the cost of taxes and a proper allow- ^. ., ... . 

- . . , , , Limits of high 

ance tor maintenance and other necessary charges, and low rates 
will pay interest on its bonds and fair dividends on ^ » ea ra e 
its stock; (2) that the shipper must obtain a rate that will enable 
him to market his products at a living profit; (3) that the ideal 
rate, if it can be ascertained, is one which will result in the greatest 
good for both parties — that is, one which will secure to the rail- 
road the greatest volume of business and the largest net return 
consistent with equal benefits to the producer and shipper. ^ 

The above principles may be described as the starting-points 
for rate-making. The determination, however, not only of what 
rates are practicable from the point of view of the ^ , , , 

, , .-, , , , ■, , ■, Federal valu- 

common prospenty of the railroads and of the whole atjon of the 
country, but also of what rates are reasonable and 
compensatory, leads us to the question of railroad valuation. As 
is well known, there is now being undertaken, under the general 
supervision of the Interstate Commerce Commission, a compre- 
hensive valuation of all the railways in the United States.'' This 
valuation is at present in charge of Mr. C. A. Prouty, formerly of 
the Interstate Commerce Commission. 

In discussing the basis on which this valuation is to be made, 
Mr. Prouty has said that the following factors must be considered: 
Reproduction new; same, less depreciation, dona- Factors to be 
tions of cash, land, etc., by Governments, individu- fedSff'*^ " 
als, or associations; original cost of all lands and valuation 
terminals and present value; all other elements of value and parts 
of value assignable to each State. He declares that the work will 
involve an accurate map and inventory of the property of every 
railroad engaged in interstate business as of June 30, 1914, to- 
gether with other maps and plans showing all subsequent addi- 
tions to the property. These inventories must be verified by the 
Commission with surveying parties going over every mile of road.* 

' Highways of Progress, pp. 2S4-SS- 

' Amendment approved March i, 1913, to Interstate Commerce Act. See 62d 
Cong., 3d Sess., chap. 92, 37 Stat. L. 701. 

' Speech of Mr. Prouty before Chamber of Commerce of the United States, Febru- 
ary II, 1914, as reported in the New York Times Annalist, February 16, 1914, p. 196. 
Mr. Prouty since has estimated the total cost of ascertaining the value of all the prop- 



1 82 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Mr. Prouty points out the difficulties of using this valuation as 
conclusive in making rates. "It is impossible," he says, "to shake 
„ , . a single railroad free from every other and fix its 

Valuation not , ,,.-,. .,. 

conclusive in Charges upon the basis of a fan: rettirn upon its fair 
value, as you would m case of a gas or water plant. 
The rate established for one, of necessity influences and frequently 
absolutely determines the rate of all." ' A rate calculated to give 
a return, for instance, of 6% on the value of a road advantageously 
situated and with a large business might mean a return of less 
than 6%, and sometimes very much less than 6%, on the value of 
other roads competing with it. 

In summing up the benefits to be derived from valuation of the 
railways, Mr. Prouty says, "It can be known with certainty 
Benefits to be ''^^ether the general level of rates is or is not too 
derived from high." He coutiuues : "While this valuation wiU be of 
according to incidental benefit to the investor, while it is essential 

r. routy ^^ ^^ work of the rate-making tribunal, it seems to 
me that its greatest immediate value is political. The state of the 
public mind toward our railways is such that this information is 
absolutely necessary." ^ 

We ourselves are thorough believers in this valuation of the 
railways by federal authorities. While it will take imdoubtedly 
many years and many millions of dollars to complete, 
valuation and while it will not be final, or perhaps even im- 

ques on portant, in determining the rates to be charged by 

any given railroad, it wiU, in our opinion, do these three things: (i) 
It will make possible at least an approximation of the value of the 
property on which a fair return by the railroads of the coimtry 
as a whole should be earned; (2) it will clear up a great many 
misapprehensions and misunderstandings on the part of the public 
as to the fair value of railroad property compared with capitaliz- 
ation; (3) if government ownership ever becomes necessary, such 

erties of the carriers at something over $50,000,000, of which the railroads would 
spend about $35,000,000 in preparing maps and other data. He has spoken of July, 
igig, as the time when the valuation may be completed. (See Commercial and Finan- 
cial Chronicle, vol. 99, pp. 1508-09, and Boston News Bureau, November 4, 1914, p. 6.) 

' Speech before Chamber of Commerce of the United States, New York Times 
Annalist, February 16, 1914, p. 197. 

' Speech of Mr. Prouty, New York Times Annalist, February 16, 1914, p. 197. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 83 

a valuation will, of course, be a necessary preliminary to purchase 
of the railroads by the Government. 

In this connection the valuations of railroad property already 
made by certain of our States is interesting. We 
give here a table (on page 184) showing value com- of railroad 
pared with capitalization of railroads in the States of by'certS™^ * 
Michigan, Wisconsin, Minnesota, South Dakota, and ^'**^* 
Washington.* 

This table shows a capitalization in the States of Minnesota 
and Washington very much below the estimates for the cost of 
reproduction and considerably below the estimates of present 
value; in Michigan, Wisconsin, and South Dakota, it shows a 
capitalization somewhat above the estimated cost of reproduction 
and conaderably above the estimated present value. 

We are of the opinion that a valuation of all the railways in the 
United States, if made on the basis of allowing for all proper 
elements of value, will prove an agreeable surprise to ^^^^ . 
security-holders and to the public. There will be un- ation Ukeiy 
doubtedly some exceptions in cases where flagrant agreeable^" 
and imjustified overcapitalization has taken place. ^"'P"^* 
In the early days, of course, as special inducements for raising capi- 
tal to build the railways, Kberal nominal issues of bonds and stocks 
were made compared with the amoxmt of money received for the 
same. The increased value of railroad property, however, together 
in many cases with the drastic reorganizations of 1893 to 1898, have 
resulted either in bringing up present value or in reducing capital- 
ization so that the margin between the two is very much less than 
it was once. 

In addition to federal supervision and federal valuation of the 
railways, there are various reforms that perhaps can be put into 
Dractice with great advantage to the holders of rail- „ 

, ... rrrt i- 11 • ' J. t. i_ Suggested 

road securities. The foUowmg pomts have been sug- railroad 
gested: (i) That executive officers actually should '^^°™^ 
represent the great body of stockholders and not bankers or other 
parties that might have motives other than the general good of 
the railroad; (2) that voting by proxy should be abolished in favor 

* These valuations are not always made up on exactly the same basis, but they will 
serve as a reasonably fair comparison. 



184 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



en 

o 



o 
u 

CO 

< 

CO 

13 



< 
O 



I 



8 



ec t^ r*- 
tC pT ^ 



*o 






CO O « 
10 10 Ov 

O 10 M 

t-T rC i-T 

W CO CO 



\0 t^ O 

O ' ' 00 *o 



CO O O 



^ CO O O 00 

•^ ^ t-* H C* 

tC w" cf cooeT 
^ ^ ^ M 10 



00 COOO 
Oi to w 
CO O r* 

so ^ d 

^0 O Tf 
w « « 



O t^ ■^ w V) 

so O w CO w 

M H 10 M O 

o" toso" 10 tC 

GO vO O Ov On 

^ lo r-O r^ 



i 



t3 

Co 



so M 

•* . *^ 

O; CO 



•H o *>* *o fO 

O W M CO ^ 

N c* 10 OS to 
10 ^ ^ P4 O 



10 M 00 CO O 
Os-^ ■* O ■* 

»o d" hT ^ tC 

CO Ci so Oi »0 
t^CO^ O; ■* O^ 

"-T CO d^ -^ 

M r>.so O 0» 

'^ CO CO H w 



l&la 



O" 
Os IT) 

HI O 

- OS 



O* Os 



a 

li 



- 4) <0 ^ *4 S 

8 g-s-sti'S-a 
.s.Shhh 9 S3 



C/}^ 










J §.35.= 
-j: M ** lu o- 

sai§-&': 
I'i §1 g" 

a- 



I! 



4s 






?.isU& 






B«.3 S~, . 



R3 a™-° i 



SB 

a o 



5 3 g o 






S n V w ^ d 

g «flg g Si.* 

•l?&a Si 

*.H'^_^^0'<? <" fa ® 

u p S 2 ryi.yj3'" « 

.§si„-g|9^5 3.2 

2'3~ V It ea 5 g 2 CO** 

SHE|«p„Sg| 
3^ aS'o~-i!'a S^ 



steam-railroad" bonds 185 

of personal voting or possibly of voting directly by mail; (3) that 
railroad directors should direct and should receive adequate com- 
pensation for satisfactory service; (4) that at least one represent- 
ative of the employees should be given a seat on the board of 
directors; (5) that meetings of boards of directors should be open 
to stockholders and to the public; (6) that minority stockholders 
should have a right, when they disagree with the decisions of 
the directors, to ask the courts to compel the corporation to pay 
the expenses of an appeal; (7) that railroad ofl&dals should be 
compelled to advertise for bids for all purchases ;' (8) that railroad 
accounting should be uniform, so that every one can see how any 
given property is being managed compared with any other; (9) 
that raUroad accoxmting should be so clear as to make impossible 
expenditures of money for influencing legislation without the 
knowledge of the public. ^ 

In discussing in this book the lines on which, in our opinion, 
exclusive federal regulation of the railways may be 
carried out and in discussing possible reforms in rail- lation and 
road management, we have in mind not so much the "f*tii?rdf-° 
establishment of the railways on a basis to give the resuft1n°bitter 
best service to the country, — though from another ^q™" *and1n 
point of view this is of paramount importance, — as greater safety 

for investors 

we have the prevention of the recurrence of the un- 
fortunate experiences of investors in railroad securities in the past. 

We have discussed many of the general and special causes of 
railroad receiverships. We shaU try now to give a brief outline 
of the way in which some of our important railroad Railroad re- 
reorganizations have worked out both for the rail- organizations 
roads and for the old security-holders. 

In seven reorganizations between 1880 and 1889, — Atchison 
(two). East Tennessee, Erie, Reading (two), and Rock Island, — 
according to Mr. Stuart Daggett, the total amoimt of Reorganiza- 
bonds was increased from $651,318,271 before reor- ^8^o_gp 
ganization to $797,570,454 after reorganization. In and 1893-98 
seven reorganizations from 1893 to 1898, — Atchison, Baltimore 

* See in this connection section lo of the "Clayton Act," approved October 15, 
IQ14; 38 Stat. L., part i, chap. 323, pp. 730, 734. 

' See statement of Charles S. Mellen, as reported in the Boston American, May 31, 
1914; also Boston News Bureau, June 2, 1914, p. i. 



1 86 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

& Ohio, Erie, Northern Pacific, Reading, Southern and Umon 
Pacific, — the total amount of bonds was reduced from $924,978,- 
070 before reorganization to $882,574,531 after reorganization.' 
In the reorganizations before 1893, fixed charges were increased 
slightly from $43,276,372 to $43,449,306; whereas in the reor- 
ganizations of 1893 to 1898, fixed charges were reduced from 
$65,984,219 to $45,576,984, a reduction of over 30 per cent.^ In 
the earlier period, rentals increased nearly 10 per cent; whereas 
in the later period, rentals decreased nearly 60 per cent.* 

The reorganizations of both periods resulted in an increase in 
total capitalization. Those before 1893 resulted in a substantial 
General sum- increase in bonds, while the items of preferred and 
gamzations°in common stock remained practically stationary; the 
the two periods reorganizations of 1893 to 1898, on the other hand, 
resulted in a considerable decrease in the amount of bonds, a very 
large increase in preferred stock, and a substantial increase in 
common stock. In other words, the reorganizations before 1893 
were effected principally with securities the charge on which was 
obligatory, whereas those from 1893 to 1898 were effected to a 
large extent with securities the charge on which was optional.* 

In the reorganizations both of the earlier and of the later period, 

assessments were general. These assessments bore most heavily, 

of course, on the junior securities, particularly on the 

common stock. This was true to a less degree in the 

earlier period of reorganization than in the later. 

In general, it may be said that the earlier reorganizations, as 
was shown by the subsequent failures of many of the same roads, 
EarUer reor- Were much less effective than were the later reorganiz- 
fe^sTeffecSve ations. In the earlier period security-holders were 
than later ones handled too tenderly, and the necessary reductions in 
fixed charges were not made and often the necessary amounts of 
new capital not raised. In most of the later reorganizations, fixed 
charges were reduced sufficiently and the necessary amounts of 
new capital raised. 

Perhaps it will be of interest to see how the holders of various 
securities fared in some of the reorganizations of 1893 to 1898; 

' Daggett, Railroad Reorganisation, p. 363. ' Ibid., p. 337. 

» Ihid., p. 370. * Daggett, p. 373. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 1 87 

in other words, to find out what the various bondholders and 
stockholders received for their old securities and ^i,at gggurity. 
what contribution they had to mate toward new holders re- 

., , rr,, . , , nr, ccived In lOUT 

capital. The accompanying tables on pages 188-191 reorganizations, 
show new securities issued in exchange for old secu- '^53-98 
rities and assessments in these four reorganizations: Atchison, 
Topeka & Santa F6, according to plan dated March 14, 1895; 
Union Pacific, according to plan dated October 15, 1895; North- 
em Pacific, according to plan published March 16, 1896; Balti- 
more & Ohio, according to plan dated June 22, 1898. 

It is to be noted that in the Atchison reorganization, there was 
a Uberal scahng-down of the principal of the debt by using to a 
considerable extent new preferred stock; that in the ^ 

Summary of 

Umon Pacific reorganization, the principal of the old these reor- 
bonds was scaled down somewhat, but the chief ^^"^^ '°°* 
feature was a reduction in interest for the new bonds as well as 
a considerable use of preferred stock; that in the cases of the 
Northern Pacific and Baltimore & Ohio, the reorganizations were 
effected to a large extent through a reduction in interest for the 
new bonds as compared with the old, rather than through a reduc- 
tion in principal, and that in both cases preferred stock was used 
to a considerable extent. 

One thing more needs to be noted about these reorganizations. 
In the three cases where the roads were reorganized after sale at 
foreclosure, — namely, Atchison, Union Pacific, and Foreclosure 
Northern Pacific, — the price obtained in each case ?"■=« ^oes 

' ^ not necessanly 

at foreclosure sale was very much less than the par bear dose reia- 
value of the old debt; for instance, the property and to the value of 
franchises of the Atchison, Topeka & Santa F6 Rail- ^^^P^°P^y 
road were sold at foreclosure for $60,000,000,^ as against a prin- 
cipal of the old debt before reorganization of $233,595,248;'' the 
old Union Pacific Railway main line and securities involved pay- 
ments of $85,677,224, as against total debt, including debt to the 
United States Government, October i, 1895, of $111,070,224;^ the 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 61, p. 1063. 

' IWd., vol. 60, p. 659. 

' Annual Report Conunissioner of Railroads (Washington, 1898), p. 9; Commercial 
and Financial Chronicle, vol. 61, p. 705; vol. 65, p. 870. Of the total debt of the Union 
Pacific as given, $53,039,512 represented debt to the United States Government. 



1 88 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



00 

H 



1 § 



§ s 9 

111 



69. 

1 

.5 



1 
I 



sis 






|*S 



3 



1 



§ 



I I 



o o 

"5 00 
I HI H 



I I I I 



K I I I I 



o 



I 



•a 
§ 

< 



§ 

.a 



2 S 

a i 
1 I 



flsf 

g S i 5tf *> 

•illli ^ 




STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 



189 



1 
s 






.a 

■1 






8888^88888 



2 

A*. 






8 8 8 % Mo5 (0(8 d 



-a 




IS 



!! 



as, 

*0 






fl? 



Si 



h 1 



CD p 



•i^ 



a 



190 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



a 






€ 



iJi 



i 



•a 



ill 

§a is 



o o 

in o 




I 8 8^888 

lO l/> O M >/) IJ^ 



I I ^1^1 "S I I 



1^ 



% I I 8 I I I 






O O O V) 



I 



3 






tt a 



bo 

S> SP y 






a I 

v 



^sl|5 



"Sag 



I '-3 "3 ' 



Id 

■3i 



i'^'B 



Qi ai V a O 

o o o u u 



u 
■J? ^ 



Is 



■ S 
1^ 



II 



g-g 
lis 

■" MOO 

III 



•9 ° i 






I 



■so-s *1 

*-si i 

m 1 

mi 

S'S 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 



191 



I 

a 






00 



f^ i ^ 

O 3 I 

E 2-1 



■■a 



a 









a 



i 



§ 



888 

4ft « « 



mi\ 






:|§§§l 111 I 



tnOOOOioQinC 
OOOOOOOOC 

MMMHHHHM^i 



S I I I 1 I II I 



p OtO«0 o » 



1 1 






iilili 



S « S S Ef« 



1 6? 






1 

'*0 Jj 



g.lil 



0.2.2.S.2 a 3.2 d'e.2 o o ^2 
600003 6o:|q3 8.Suo 




■Ml 




192 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Northern Pacific Railroad and lands were bought in for $1 5 ,938, 200/ 
as against total debt of the company, June 30, 1896, of $132,376,- 
500.* The purpose of these figures is to show that the foreclosure 
price bears no necessary relation to the debt or to the value of the 
property. In all such cases, the bids at foreclosure are made on 
the basis of what bid is necessary in order to get the property and be 
in a position to dictate the reorganization. Minority bondholders, 
however, or those who do not assent to the plan of reorganization, 
must take in satisfaction of their old claim a pro rata of the fore- 
closure price; that is, if properties are sold for $60,000,000, for 
instance, which have bonds outstanding of $120,000,000, the non- 
assenting bondholders receive only fifty cents on the dollar less 
expenses. On the other hand, if they go into the reorganization, 
they get the new securities as arranged for by the plan. 

In reorganizations the apportionment of new securities usually 
is on the basis of the degree of safety of the old securities, and also 
Factors deter- Very largely on the basis of what class of new security- 
^rdomSnt^of holders furnish the bulk of the new money necessary 
new securities (-q pyj- j-j^g property into Satisfactory condition. In 
other words, if interests representing the old common stock fur- 
nish most of the new money, the old common stock gets bet- 
ter treatment than it otherwise would. Just as the old common 
stockholders probably have suffered most through the difficul- 
ties of their road, so in a successful reorganization, if they pay 
their assessments, they are placed in a position to profit most.' 

As has been stated earlier in this chapter, many imderlying 
issues of bonds have not been disturbed at all in reorganizations, 
Lat«r market ^^'^ hzNe received their interest right along. Even 
vaitie of seam- bonds that wcrc disturbed received an assortment 

ties received m 

certain re- of new securftics, which if held for a reasonable time 

organizations attained a market value that satisfied and usually 
much more than satisfied the entire claim of the old bondholders. 
We give herewith on page 193 a table showing the market value 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 63, p. 189, and Daggett, p. 308. 

• Interstate Commerce Comimssion, Statistics of Railways (Washington, 1897), 
P- 336. 

» Very often a large part of the common stock of the new company gets into the 
hands of bankers, who hold the stock until the road is at least on its feet. Sometimes 
bankers control the reorganized road through a voting trust for a certain period. 



STEAM-RAELROAD BONDS 



193 



in January, 1901, November, 1907, and January, 1912, of new 
securities received in exchange for some of the leading classes of 
old securities, according to the four reorganization plans we have 

MARKET VALUE OF NEW SECURITIES (LESS ASSESSMENTS) 
RECEIVED IN REORGANIZATION IN EXCHANGE FOR 
EACH $1000 LEADING OLD SECURITIES 1 



Old securities 



Atchison, Topeka fie Santa FS Railroad. 

General mortgage 4% bonds , 

Second mortgage, class A bonds 

Second mortgage, class B bonds 

Income bon(& of 1889 

Capital stock 

Union Pacific Railway. 

First mortgage 6% bonds 

Sinking-fund 8% bonds 

Middle Division 6% bonds , 

Denver Extension first mortgage 6% bonds. . . 
Kansas Pacific consolidated first mortgage 6% 

bonds 

Capital stock 

Northern Pacific Railroad. 

General first mortgage 6% bonds 

General second mortgage 6% bonds 

General third mortgage 6% bonds 

Consolidated mortgage s% bonds 

Collateral trust 6% notes 

Preferred stock 

Common stock 

Baltimore 6* Ohio Railroad. 
Baltimore & Ohio consolidated mortgage of 

1887 S% bonds 

Baltimore & Ohio sterling loan of 1872 6% 

bonds 

Baltimore & Ohio sterling loan of 1874 6% 

bonds 

Baltimore & Ohio loan of 1885 S% bonds . . . . 

Philadelphia Division 4^% bonds 

Baltimore & Ohio Terminal bonds of 1894 4J% 

Baltimore & Ohio Stock — first preferred . . . . 

second preferred . . 

conmion 



January 
4, igoi 



$1109.14 
938.86 
982.18 
938.86 
431-63 



1467.17 
1614.44 
1467.17 
1467.17 

1432.71 
7SS-88 



1413.68 
1667.77 
1266.45 
1004.7s 
1217.92 
730.00 
656-25 



1199.39 
1127.71 

1229.11 

"64.33 
1224.85 
1000.92 
1236.75 

"9S-2S 
786.50 



November 
1, 1(107 



$968.25 
909.20 
951.20 
909.20 
720.25 



1321-67 
1491.25 
1321.67 
1321.67 

1340.84 
I053-7S 



1271.25 
1615.88 
I293-9S 
1070.55 
1141.67 

932.50 
915-00 



1091.27 

1026.90 

1116.90 

1058.85 

1082.92 

884.17 

977-50 

1157-50 

755-0O 



January 
5, 1912 



$1108.88 
1108.36 
1159.18 
1108.36 
1059.13 



1467-SO 
1675.63 
1467.50 
1467-SO 

1515-75 
1688.00 



1348.31 
1683.52 
1323-58 
1087.18 
1198.7s 
989.38 
1028.7s 



1162.84 

1090.33 

1197.13 
1130.2s 
1215.8s 
980.00 
1225.38 

1534-25 
1015.50 



> The prices for market value are taken from the Commercial and Financial Chrimicle, vol. 73, pp. 34, 
35, 36, 38, 3g; vol. 85, pp. 1126, 1128, 1130, IZ31; vol. 9*, PP. SS, S7i S9, 60. 



194 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

given. It can be seen from this table tbat old bondholders and 
even old stockholders ultimately had a chance to recoup at least 
a large part of their losses and sometimes came out much better 
than this. 
In spite of the difficulties under which our railroads have been 
. operated and all the troubles through which they have 

American rail- gonc, railway transportation in the United States has 
vrith tS'"* been, on the whole, remarkably efficient. The accom- 
o urope panying figures for railways in the United States 

compared with railways in Great Britain and Ireland, France, 
and Germany may be of interest- 

AMERICAN AND EUROPEAN RAILWAYS COMPARED 



Country 


Capitalization 
per mile of 
line, igi2* 


Miles of line 

per 10,000 

inhabitants, 

igizi 


Average re- 
ceipts per pas- 
senger per 
mile,igi2t 
(.cents) 


Average re- 
ceipts per ton 
per mile, 

jgizt 

{cents) 


United States 


563,535 
273,360 
147,787 
"S,4S4 


25-93 
S13 
6.36 
S-68 


1.987 

i-7So§ 

1.070 

.901 


• 744 


United Kingdom 

France (1911) 


2.000** 
1. 17? 


Gennanv 


1. 179 





* Interstate Commerce Commission, Annual Report on the Statistics of Railways in the United Stales 
(Washington, 1914), p. 32; Interstate Commerce Qimmission, Twenty-fifth Annual Report, Railway Re^ 
ktms; Returns of the Capital, Traffic, Receipts, and Working Expenditures of the Railway Companies of 
the United Kingdom for the year zgiz (London, igis), pp. zviiandzx; Sialisitcal Abstract for the Principal 
and Other Foreign Countries (London, 1914), pp. 387, sgo. 

t Interstate Cx>mmerce Commission, Statistics of Railways in the United States (1914), p. 11; RaUway 
Returns of the United Kingdom, p. xvii ; Statistical Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Cotmtries 
(1914), pp. 13. 387. 390, 407* 

t Interstate Commerce Commission, Statistics of Railways in the United States (1914), p. 42; Statistical 
Abstract for the Principal and Other Foreign Countries (1914). PP- 387. 390. 

I Approximate. See Dunn, Government Ownership of Railways, p. 291. 

** Approximate. Includes collection and delivery. Raper, Railway Transportation, p. 242. Dunn, p. 291, 
gives the same figure. See also Annual Railway Reports, French Ministry of Public Works, and 
Archiv filr Eisenbaknwesen. See also Bureau of Railway Economics, Comparative RaUway Statistics United 
States and Foreign Countries (1912), consecutive no. 83 (Washington D.C., I9i5)> 

A glance at the figures in the above table shows that the 
railways of the United States have by far a smaller capitaliza- 
tion per mile of line than the railways of the United Kingdom, 
France, or Germany,' They receive, with the possible exception of 
the railways in Great Britain,^ a larger average fare per passenger 

^ The cost of construction in densely populated Europe is, of course, far 
greater. 
' Actual average passenger rates not known. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS I9S 

per mile. This is owing partly to the use of second-class and 
third-class service to a great extent in Europe. For freight service, 
however, the railways of the United States receive a rate per ton 
per mile not much over one third that received by the railways 
of Great Britaiu and Ireland and not quite two thirds that re- 
ceived by the railways of France and Germany. Furthermore, 
wages on the American railways have been substantially higher 
than anywhere in Europe.^ 

In discussing various phases of the railroad situation, we have 
strayed, perhaps, somewhat from our special subject 
of railroad bonds. We believe, however, that all the discussed above 

..J. J 1 1 1 J- i have bearing 

questions discussed above have a more or less direct on safety of 
and important bearing on the safety of such bonds. '^^°^^ ^°'^^ 

In general, railroad bonds are dependent for their safety mainly 
on the relation of the total debt to the value of the Leading factors 
property and on the relation of net earnings to fixed °* ^^^ 
charges. 

The territory served by any given road, the density of the 
freight and passenger business, and the future growth of the ter- 
ritory, as well as the physical condition and operating 
efficiency of the road and its ability to withstand 
competition or proper regulation, all are highly important.^ 

A first-mortgage bond on a first-class road is, as a rule, the best 
kind of security obtainable. Such an issue is the Chicago, Burling- 
ton & Quincy Railroad (Illinois Division) 3!% and ^^^ j 
4% issue, due July i, 1949. These bonds are the strong rail- 
obligation of a company which has never defaulted 
on principal or interest of any of its obligations, and which has 
paid good dividends through a long series of years, including 
some of the most serious depressions ever experienced in this coun- 
try. The bonds are part of what is now a closed first mortgage 
on the valuable terminal property of the company in the city of 
Chicago, on practically all the mileage in the State of Illinois, 
and on the line running from Chicago to St. Paul, Minnesota. 

' Raper, Railway Transportation, p. 190. 

' If tiie bonds are sectired on a portion of the road, the question always should be 
considered as to whether this piece of road could be operated successfully as an inde- 
pendent property. 



196 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

They are followed by $64,247,000 general mortgage 4% bonds 
and by $215,227,000 "joint" bonds issued against the stock of 
the company. Other especially strong mortgage issues are New 
York Central & Hudson River Railroad 3^%, 1997; Pennsylvania 
Railroad 4%, 1943 and 1948, and 4|%, i960; Lake Shore & Michi- 
gan Southern Railway 3!%, 1997; Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul 
Railway general mortgage 3!%, 4%, 4!%, 1989; Chicago & North- 
western Railway general mortgage 4% and 5%, 1987; and Illinois 
Central main line 4%, 1951. Many other exceedingly well-secured 
issues could be given in a longer hst. 

In the matter of the prices of raikoad bonds, we find, in com- 
paring the prices of 1902, for instance, with those of 1912, a decline 
Prices of ill price or increase in net income similar to what we 

railroad bonds jj^ve f oimd in the cases of state and mimicipal bonds. 
The accompanying table illustrates this point. 



Bands 


Prices 


igoz" 


igiz\ 




3-90% 
3-85 

3-43 
3- 10 
3-25 
3.38 
3-25 
3-8s 
3-4S 
3-73 


4.04% 


Baltimore & Ohio, orior lien xk^n. 102 k 


4. ^0 


Chicago, Builington & Quincy KailroaJd (Illinois Division), 3^%, 


4- IS 
4- OS 
4. 10 


Chicago, Milwaukee & St. Paul Railway, general 4%, 1989 

Chicago & Northwestern Railway, genend 3^%, 1987 


Tllinnis CjPT\tr:\\ RailroaH, first mortgage, 4% TQ5r 


3-90 
4.00 


New York Central & Hudson River Railroad, 3!%, 1997 

Northern Padfic Railroad, prior lien 4%, 1997 




3-8S 
3-95 


Union Pacific Railroad land grant 4%, 1947 





* Prices January 3, 1902. See Quotation Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronidet Februaiy 
8, zgo2, pp. 23, 24, 27, 28, 30; Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 74, pp. 33-36. 
t Prices Januaiy 5, 1913. See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, January 6. 1912, vol. 94, pp. 55-60. 

The lowest average prices of railroad bonds recorded during the 
past fifteen years occurred in the fall of 1907 and in the summer 
and early autumn of 1915. As showing the effect of the war, the 
average price of twelve issues of railroad bonds listed on the New 
York Stock Exchange showed a net decline between July, 1914, 
and July, 19x5, from 90.9 to 87.7, or 3.2 points.' 

In closing this chapter on railroad bonds, we will say that the 
' Babson's Desk Sheet of Tables and Charts, July 29, 1915. 



STEAM-RAILROAD BONDS 197 

railroad industry in the United States is substantially equal in 
magnitude to all the manufacturing industries and is 
exceeded to any extent only by farming. ' The mileage of railroad 
is over one third the total mileage of the world. The '° "^"^ 
industry has, as stated earlier in this chapter, over 1,800,000 
employees," which, on the usual basis of figuring five in a family, 
involves the well-being of about 9,000,000 people. According to> 
the figures of the Interstate Commerce Commission for the year 
ending June 30, 1913, the net capitalization of all the railroads in. 
the United States is $15,330,131,446, and the gross capitalization 
$19,796,125,712." 

On the whole, the service which the American railroads have 
given to the country has been not only efl&cient, but absolutely 
necessary for the development and even the existence ^ _, , 

•' '^ ... Importance of 

of the United States as one country. This service has service per- 
established free communication and made possible the American 
free interchange of commodities over a vast territory, "^^ '°^^ 
and has brought into being thickly populated communities which 
otherwise probably never would have come into existence. Fur- 
thermore, the railroads have performed this immense service on 
the basis of an exceedingly moderate capitalization compared with 
capitalization in other important civilized countries. They have, 
paid higher wages to their employees and have given freight ser- 
vice at very much lower figures per ton per mile tiian Railroads 
the railroad systems of Europe. |^,ft^ ^«dlrai 

This great industry certainly is entitled to receive ^^4"g„ti°igj "J; 
rates which will make possible efficient service in the rates which 
present and future growth to correspond with the good service 
growth of the country. It should be subject, in our retum^t" 
opinion, to federal regulation in such a way as to '°vestors 
safeguard the interests of the public and of investors. In the 
broadest sense, the general prosperity of the coimtry and of the 
railroad industry are essential to the safety of railroad bonds. 

1 See Bureau of Railway Economics, Bulletin no. 39, Comparison of Capital Values 
— Agriculture, Manufactures, and the Railways (Washington, 1912), p. 14. 

' Interstate Commerce Commission, Twenty-sixth Annual Report, Statistics of 
Railways in the United States (Washington, I9i4)> P- 23- 

» IMd., pp. 28 and 30. 



CHAPTER VI 

PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 

If we exclude steam-railroad bonds, which we have discussed in 
prindpai the previous chapter, public-service corporation bonds 

uc?sem°ce^ror- ^^y be issued by the following principal classes of 
poration bonds corporations : — 
(i) Electric railways. 

(2) Gas companies. 

(3) Electric light and power companies. 

(4) Telephone companies.* 

We will use the term "public-service corporation bonds" in the 
rest of this chapter as referring only to the above classes of bonds. 

The above classes may be subdivided; for instance, there are 
city street railways and interurban railways; there are gas com- 
panies which do principally a lighting business and 

Public-service ^ . , . , ^ . , . . 7, - , 

corporations compames which furmsh gas prmapally for heatmg 
miTkind™^' or cooking; there are electric light and power com- 
usiness panies which develop their power principally from 

steam and others which develop their power principally from 
water power; and there are electric light and power companies 
whose principal business is that of furnishing light and others 
whose principal business is furnishing power to industries. There 
are often, moreover, corporations which do both a street-railway 
and an electric light and power business, or a gas business and an 
Prices of some electric light and power business, or all three com- 

leading public- Vn'npfl 2 
service corpo- uiiicu.. 

ration bonds ^^g gjyg ^gio'vp prices on an incomc basis of certain 

' Years ago there were a good many private water companies serving local com- 
munities, but most of these have since been taken over by municipalities for municipal 
ownership and operation. 

* Of recent years, there has been a large development of the holding company as a 
vehicle for controlling public-service corporations, often of various kinds and some- 
times located in different States. (See The North American Company, Public Service 
Corporation of New Jersey, The United Gas Improvement Company.) 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS ig9 

well-known public-service corporation bonds in April to July, 
1914:1 

Ladede Gas Light (St. Louis) first-mortgage 5% 1919. .4.66% 

New York Telephone 4!% 1939 4.68% 

Detroit Edison first-mortgage 5% 1933 4-77% 

Cleveland Railway 5% 1931 4-83% 

Commonwealth Edison (Chicago) 5% 1943 4.86% 

Seattle Electric 5% 1930 4.87% 

Union Electric Light and Power (St. Louis) 5% 1932 . . .4.88% 

Southern Power 5% 1930 4-95% 

Boston Elevated Railway 5% 1942 S-oo% 

American Telephone & Telegraph 4% 1929 S-oo% 

Interborough Rapid Transit (New York) 5% 1966 .... 5.08% 

These are fairly representative of the best grade of public- 
service corporation bonds. 

A brief sketch of the origin and development of the business 
now done by public-service corporations may be of interest. The 
earliest developments in this field were in gas-lighting, origin and 
In 1792, one WilHam Murdock Ughted with gas his pubUc-Se°' 
house and ofl&ce in Cornwall, England. In 1813, gas business— gas 
was used to light Westminster Bridge; and in 1816, it became 
common ia London. The first city in the United States to install a 
system of gas-lighting was Baltimore, in 1817. Since that time the 
growth of the gas business has been uninterrupted.^ We give on 
page 200 a table showing quantity of gas made, capital, and num- 
ber of employees for the gas business in the United States at periods 
from 1859 to 1909 inclusive. These figures show a steady growth 
of the gas business in the United States. 

The first street railway in the United States was built in New 
York City on Fourth Avenue from Prince Street to Harlem in 
1832. Between that date and 1873, horse railroads street and 
were introduced into all the large American cities, ekctnc raUways 
After 1 88 1, electrical construction and operation was used to a 

' Prices from dealers' offerings April to July, 1914, and from the Boston, New York, 
and Chicago Stock Exchanges as reported m the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 
July 4, 1914, pp. 32-39- 

2 For above material see Encyclopedia Britannica (11th ed., Cambridge, England, 
1910), vol. XI, p. 483; Chambers's Encyclopeedia (London, Edinburgh, and Philadel- 
phia, 1893), vol. 5, p. 103; Encyclopedia Americana (New York, 1904-05), vol. 7, 
"Gas Illumination, History of." 



200 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 
GAS COMPANIES* 



Date 


Quantity of gas made 
(cubic feet) 


Capital 


Number of em- 
ployees 


lien 


36,519,512,000 

67,093,553,000 

"2,549,979,000 

150,835,793,000 


$28,848,726 
71,773,694 
258,771,795 
567,000,506 
725,035,204 
915,536,762 


5,730 
8,723 
12,996 
28,363 : 
39,972 
10.7^0 '. 


\ 


i860 


\ 


1880 


\ 


iSgg 


\ 


1004. 




IQOQ 









I 



Thirteenth Census, vol. X, p. 637, 

Average number of wage-earners only. 

Salaried employees and average number of wage-earners. 



considerable extent, and at the close of 1888 there were nearly 
one hundred and fifty miles of electric line in operation.^ The fol- 
lowing table shows the miles of line operated, cost of construc- 
tion and equipment, and number of employees for street and 
electric railways in the United States at periods from 1890 to 191 2 
inclusive. This table shows a rapid growth imtil 1907 and a mod- 
erate growth after that date. 

STREET AND ELECTRIC RAILWAYS* 



Date 


Miles of line 
operated 


Cost of construction 
and equipment 


Number of 
employees 


i8oo 


5,783 
16,645 

25,547 
30,437 


$389,357,289 
2,167,634,077 
3,637,668,708 
4,596,563,292 


70,764 
140,769 
221,429 
282,461 




1007 







* Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Bulletin 124, CaOral Blectrk LigU and Pimer 
Stations and Street and Electric Railways, 1912 (Washington, 1914), p. 64. 

The first really successful electric arc lamp was patented in 
1857; and in 1858, a lamp designed by Duboscq was used to show 
Electric Ught electric light at sea from the South Foreland Light- 
and power jjouse m England. From 1878 to 1879, electric arc 

lamps were used widely for lighting large rooms, streets, and spaces 



' Encyclopedia Americana, vol. 14, 
Encyclopedia, vol. 4, p. 285. 



'Street Railway Construction"; Chambers's 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 



201 



out of doors. In 1879, Edison invented the first successful incan- 
descent lamp; and from that time the growth of the incandescent 
electric-lighting industry has been rapid.'' The accompanying table 
shows total horse power, cost of construction and equipment, and 
number of employees for central electric stations in 1902, 1907, and 
1912, and the same data for hydro-electric stations and for central 
electric stations and hydro-electric stations combined in 191 2. 

ELECTRIC LIGHT AND POWER 



Date 


Total horse power 


Cost of construction 
and equipment 


Number of employees 


Central dectric sta- 
tions* 


1,845,048 
4,098,188 
7,528,648! 

3,179,244 
10,707,892 


$504,740,352 
$1,096,913,622 
$2,175,678,266! 

5922,954,341 
$3,098,632,607 


30,326 


1007 


47,632 


1012 


70,^^'? 


Hydro-electric sta- 
tions^ {Reporting 
water - power of 
1000 horse power 
or more) 


17,160 


Total central dectric 
stations and hydro- 
electric stations 


9649s 







• Bureau of the Census, Bulletin 124, Central Electric Light and Power Statiorvs, etc., pp. 14 and 15. 
t Ibid.i p. 21. 

These tables show the importance and rapid growth of the 
electric industry. 

Professor Alexander Graham Bell, on February 14, 1876, filed 
in the Patent Ofl&ce specifications and drawings of the original 
Bell telephone. The first important test of the new ^ , , 

. . • 3 r\ I. Telephones 

invention was m a conversation earned on, October 
9, 1876, by Professor Bell and Thomas A. Watson over a tele- 
graph Une between Boston, Massachusetts, and Cambridge, 
Massachusetts." The table on page 202 shows number of stations 

' Chambers's Encyclopedia, vol. 4, pp. 281-82; Encyclopedia Americana, vol. 6, 
"Electric Lighting." 

' Chambers's Encyclopcedia, vol. 10, p. no; Herbert N. Casson, The History of the 
Telephone (Chicago, 1910), p. 49 and plate. 



202 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 
TELEPHONE BUSINESS* 



Dale 


Number of stations 
or telephones 


Total capitalization 
outstanding 


Number of 
employees 


1880 


54,319 

233,678 

2,315,297 

4,906,693 

7,326,748 


$14,605,787! 

72,341,736 
348,031,058 
758,122,214 
991,294,115 


3,338 


1890 


8,645 


1002 


78,752 




131,670 


IQ12 


183,361 







Points of 
similarity in 
different classes 



* Department of Commerce and Labor, Bureau of the Census, Telephones, igii (Washington, igis), 
P- 13- 
t Partial figures. 

or telephones, total capitalization outstanding, and number of 
employees for the telephone business at periods from 1880 to 1912 
inclusive. These figures show a growth almost unbeHevable. It is 
now possible to talk over the telephone from New York City to 
San Francisco. 
The business of public-service corporations, with the possible 
exception of that of interurban railways and of that 
portion of the electric light and power business which 
may be called industrial power business, is similar in 
three leading respects: — 

(i) In being based on a franchise or privilege of some sort. 

(2) In being, as a rule, monopolistic. 

(3) In being affected to a comparatively slight extent as to earn- 
ings by general businesss expansion or depression. 

Some of these conditions are inherent in the nature of public- 
service business and some are the result of comparatively recent 
developments. 

In attempting to judge the safety of any given issue of public- 
service corporation bonds, one of the first considerations is the size 
and character of the community served. The cities 
in the United States having a population of 100,000 
or over naturally furnish the best field, other things 
being equal, for the development of street-railway or 
retail gas and electric business. In the same way, 
those of our States having a large population, like Massachusetts, 
New York, Ohio, and Illinois, furnish the best field for the great 



Size and char- 
acter of the 
community 
served an 
important fac- 
tor in safety 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 203 

Bell telephone concerns. The character of the population, the ex- 
tent and diversity of their interests, and their attitude toward 
public-service corporations, also are important. 

Another leading consideration governing the safety of public- 
service corporation bonds, and perhaps the most important con- 
sideration of all, as in the case of steam railroads, is „ . , ^ ^ 

., , ^. , , , , , -, , , Ratio of debt 

tne relation 01 debt to property or assets. In Massa- to assets is 
chusetts, the ratio of debt to property on gas and ™p°''^' 
electric light companies is not over fifty per cent,^ that is, for every 
issue of bonds there must be paid ia at least an equal amoimt of 
capital stock including premiums." Street railways iu Massachu- 
setts have the right to issue bonds to an amotmt twenty per cent in 
excess of the amoxmt of paid-in capital stock.' Outside of Massa- 
chusetts, it is more common to find public-service corporations 
having a debt from seventy-five to ninety per cent of the property 
or asset value. 

Many considerations may modify the safety or lack of safety of 
a debt representing a large proportion of the property value; for 
instance, control of the business in a valuable terri- _, ^ 

... , Factors modi- 

tory on the basis of givmg good service at low rates, Wng impor- 
large net earniug capacity, diversification of business, between debt 
strong franchise situation, or particularly efl&cient ^" property 
management. 

As stated above, almost all public-service corporations, using 
the term as we have defined it in this chapter, are monopolistic in 
their character. There is, as a rule, only one street 
railway, one gas company, or one electric light and senSre'cor-'^ 
power company in a given city or community. In to^f^°havea 
earlier days, when such enterprises were in their in- f?°?°g°|? '° 
fancy and when the relation of street railways, gas 
companies, and electric light and power companies to the public 
had hardly been thought out, even in its broadest lines, there 
were often two or more corporations attempting to perform the 
same or similar service in one community. This state of affairs 
was paid for, as it always is, either by the community in poorer 

' In some cases, as in that of the Edison Electric Illuminating Company of Boston, 
the debt compared with the property value is so small as to be unimportant. 
' Acts 1914, chap. 742, sees. 38-40. • Ibid., chap. 671. 



204 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

service or higher prices or else by security-holders in losses on 
their investment. Gradually consolidations took place until in 
most communities there was only one corporation attempting to 
perform the same or similar service. 

As soon as it became clear to the public that duplication of 
facilities was not only uimecessary, but involved an absolute loss 
to the community or to security-holders, States and 
of^mfflMpoS' munidpahties, in giving public-service corporations 
ied'to^'Stric- ^^ ^E)^^ to do business, imposed conditions of a some- 
tions on private ■vfhat different and of a much more stringent character 

management . . . , . 

than before. For if corporations furmshmg street- 
railway service, gas, electric Hght and power, or telephone service 
— essential to the every-day life of the community — were to 
have a monopoly of the business, they should be compelled to give 
satisfactory service at reasonable rates. 

Publicly granted rights to operate public utilities usually are 
called franchises. All franchises come from the State, although the 

legislature may and often does delegate to municipal 

Franchises ,,. i-i t^i . -i 

authorities the nght to take final action m the pro- 
cedure resulting in the creation of a franchise.^ Indiana and Cali- 
fornia may be mentioned as examples of States where the power to 
grant franchises is exercised indirectly through the act of munici- 
palities to which the State has delegated its power.'' Franchises 
give public-service corporations the right to operate street-railway 
liaes, gas, electric light, or telephone properties, as the case may be, 
and the right to use the streets, erect poles and wires, and do other 
things necessary to carry on the business of the corporation. Fran- 
chises generally have been held to be in the nature of contracts.' 
Franchises" in earlier days sometimes contained burdensome 

restrictions, such as compelling corporations to pave 
restrictions in an imusual distance outside the tracks, place an 

unreasonable portion of their wires in imderground 

' Skaneateles W. W. Company v. Skaneateles, i6i N.Y. 154, i6Si per Parker, 
Ch. J.; S5 N.E. 562; 46 L.R.A. 687; (on appeal) 184 U.S. 354. 

' Acts igos (Indiana), p. 383, as amended by Acts igii, p. 181 (Bums's Annot. Ind. 
Stats. [1914], vol. 4, sec. 8939); Constitution of California, art. xi, sec. 19. 

• Minneapolis v. Minneapolis St. R. Co., 213 U.S. 417; 54 L. Ed. 259; Chicago 
Municipal Gas Light, etc., Co. v. Lake, 130 111. 42; 22 N.E. 616. For collection of 
authorities, see Public Utilities, by O. L. Fond (Indianapolis, 1913), sec. 95, note. - 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 205 

conduits, or charge a rate incompatible with a fair return to secur- 
ity-holders. 

Many franchises, and until recently most franchises, have been 
granted for a definite term of years, ninning usually from twenty 
to fifty years. Some franchises have been considered Length of 
by the corporations and some held even by the courts fra,iicUses 
as perpetual.^ 

Street-railway franchises and possibly gas and electric light 
franchises in Massachusetts " are revocable licenses. Revocable 
or simply rights to operate during good behavior. Metendnate 
In Wisconsin,' all franchises, and in Indiana,* many pe^^ts 
franchises are what may be caUed indeterminate permits. 

In most States, a corporation must obtain the consent of the 
local authorities to the location of tracks, conduits. Consent of local 
poles and wires, and other portions of its plant which fnstamltion of 
may interfere with the public use of the streets. property 

In the slow improvement of the franchise situation which has 
been going on for many years, irregularities and mismanagement 
of those in control of public-service corporations, just D^^„jt;e3 c 
as in the case of steam railroads, combined with a lack arriving at a 
of clear or of any ideas on the part of the public as to franchise 
the principles involved, have led to many difficulties ''"^^*'°° 
in bringing about even a reasonable working solution of this impor- 
tant problem. 

In the opinion of the most enlightened public-service corporation 

■ See Louisville v. Cumberland Valley Telephone Co., 224 U.S. 649 (holding the 
franchise of the Ohio Valley Telephone Company in the city of Louisville to be per- 
petual); per Lamar, J., at 664. "The earher cases are reviewed in Detroit St. R.R. v. 
Detroit, 64 Fed. Rep. 628, 634, which was dted with approval in Detroit v. Detroit St. 
R.R., 184 U.S. 368, 395, this court there saying that 'Where the grant to a corporation 
of a franchise to construct and operate its road is not, by its terms, limited and 
revocable, the grant is in fee.' " 

' As to revocation of street-railway locations, see Acts igo6, chap. 463, part 3, sec. 
66; Acts igog, chap. 417, sec. 6; Medford & Charlestown St. R.R. Co. v. Somerville & 
Middlesex R.R. Co., in Mass. 232. As to gas and electric light locations, see Boston 
Electric Light Co. v. Boston Terminal Co., 184 Mass. 566; Natick Gas Light Co. v. 
Natick, 17s Mass. 246-52. 

' Laws igoy, chap. 499, as amended; see Wis. Slats, igii, chap. 87, sec. 1797M-74; 
Laws zgJ3, chap. 610. 

* The Indiana law leaves the acceptance of an indeterminate permit optional with 
the utility and fixes a limited period within which to make the change. {Laws of 
Indiana, 1913, chap. 76, sec. loi.) 



206 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

managers to-day, as well as in the opinion of publicists, the best 
Best sort of sort of franchise is one that is fair and reasonable 
franchise ^jq^Ii ^q ^j^g community served and to the corporation. 

As exceedingly interesting franchise arrangements of a more 
or less special character and yet embodying the 
franchise principle of fair dealing between the community served 

arrangemen ^^^ ^^^ corporation, we wish to caU attention to the 
following: 

(i) The Boston Sliding Scale Act,^ which established for a ten-year 
period from June 30, 1906, the relations in certain respects between 
the Boston ConsoUdated Gas Company and the community 
served. This act, passed after a valuation of the properties under 
the direction of the Massachusetts Gas and Electric Light Com- 
missioners, provided for a standard price for gas of ninety cents 
per one thousand cubic feet and a standard rate of dividends on 
the capital stock of 7% per annum. It provided further, that for 
every one-cent reduction in the price of gas below the standard 
price, the company might increase its dividend one-fifth of 1%.* 

(2) Franchises of the Chicago City Railway Company and the 
Chicago Railways Company granted by an ordinance' passed 
February 4, 1907, and approved at popular election April 2, 1907. 
These franchises fixed valuations for municipal purchase and pro- 
vided for a distribution in cash of the surplus earnings on a five- 
cent fare basis between the city of Chicago and the companies. 

(3) Franchise of the Cleveland Railway Company granted by an 
ordinance * passed by the City Coimcil and approved by the 
Mayor, December 18, 1909, and ratified by the voters of the city 

* Acts ic)o6, chap. 422. 

' The Boston Sliding Scale Act has been followed by general legislation embodying 
substantially the same principles in the following States: New York, Pennsylvania, 
Maryland, Ohio, Wisconsin, Missouri, Idaho, Arizona, and California. New York: 
Laws igio, chap. 480, sec. 65(4); Birdseye, etc., Cons. Laws, vol. 8, p. 2200, chap. 48, 
sec. 65(4), in efEect June 14, 1910; Pennsylvania: Laws 1(113, no. 854, art. 3, sec. 1(0), 
ineflEect January i, 1914; Maryland: Laws igio, chap. 180, sec. 31^, p. 375, in effect 
April s, 1910; Ohio: Laws igii, p. 554, House Bill no. 325, sec. iq, in effect June 30, 
1911; Wisconsin: Laws, 1907, chap. 499, in effect July 11, 1907; Wisconsin Stats. 
(1911), sec. 1797M-17; Missouri: Laws 1913, p. 603, Senate Bill no. i, sec. 68(4), 
in effect April 15, 1913; Idaho: Session Laws 1913, chap. 61, sec. 20, in effect May 7, 
1913; Arizona: Laws ipi2, chap. 90, sec. 21, Rev. Stats. 1913, sec. 2297; California: 
Stats, igii. Extra. Session, chap. 14, sees. 20-21, in effect March 23, 1912. 

' Council Proceedings (Chicago, 111., 1906-07), pp. 2944-90. 

* Ordinance no. 16238A, entitled "An ordinance granting renewal of the street- 
railway grants of the Cleveland Railway Company," as amended by Ordinance no. 
20890B, passed July 10, 1911. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 207 

at a referendum election, February 17, 1910. This franchise, 
granted after a valuation of the company's property made by a 
court, provided for municipal purchase under certain conditions 
and for a fare which would take care of operating expenses and 
maintenance, interest on the debt, and 6% on the valuation as 
represented by the capital stock. 
(4) Agreement^ between the City of New York and the Interborough 
Rapid Transit Company for building the new subways. This 
agreement provided that the new subways should be owned by 
the City of New York, and operated by the company, that part of 
the cost of construction should be paid by the city and part by 
the Interborough Rapid Transit Company; and that the company 
should have a first claim on the earnings to an amount sufficient to 
insure a satisfactory return on its investment. 

All these franchise arrangements show an adaptation of sound 
general principles to peculiar local conditions.^ 

The franchises granted in Chicago and in Cleveland were the 
result of independent negotiations between the cities and the com- 
panies. They were made effective before even the interborough 
existence of any public-service commissions having Rapid Transit 

•' '^ ° agreement 

jurisdiction. The Interborough Rapid Transit agree- made effective 
ment, on the other hand, while the result of nego- PubUc-Service 
tiations between the City of New York and the Commission 
company, was made effective only through the approval of the 
Public-Service Commission, First District, State of New York. 
These facts suggest how recent is the idea of control of local public- 
service corporations by state commissions. 

To-day, however, not only the franchise question in its narrow- 
est sense, but the whole question of the relation of public-service 
corporations to the communities which they serve centers around 
regulation by state commissions. This is of the greatest impor- 

' City of New York, by the Public-Service Commission, First District, with Inter- 
borough Rapid Transit Company, Contract no. 3, dated March ig, 1913; the City of 
New York, by the Public-Service Commission, First District, with Interborough 
Rapid Transit Company, lessee and grantee, supplementary agreement dated March 
ig, igi3; Public-Service Commission, First District, to Interborough Rapid Transit 
Company, certificate dated March 19, 1913; Public-Service Commission, First Dis- 
trict, with Manhattan Railway Company, certificate dated March 19, 1913. 

' For an interesting, but not, as it seems to us, entirely soimd, franchise settlement, 
see new franchise ordinance of the Kansas City Railway & Light Company. This pro- 
vides among other things that the city shall have five representatives on the Boaid of 
Directors. (Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 99, p. 196.) 



208 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

tance to investors. The regulation of public-service corporations 
Relation of ^y State commissions affects the safety of public- 
pubUc service scrvice Corporation bonds fundamentally. While this 

corporations to ^ . , . , . 

communities regulation may not always be exercised wisely, it 
centers around Substitutes for the more or less capricious action of 
state rom-''^ private bankers in investigation and supervision the 
missions actiou of State commissions raised above private and 

local considerations. For this reason, together with the fact that 
the subject is comparatively new, we will discuss state regulation 
of public utilities at considerable length. 

Among the earliest commissions approaching at aU the character 
of the modem state public-service commissions were the New 
Early com- Hampshire Board of Railroad Commissioners estab- 
missions j^gj^g^ ^ 1844,1 the Massachusetts Board of Raihoad 

Cormnissioners estabhshed in 1869,^ and the Massachusetts Gas 
Commission established in 1885.' Some of the early commissions, 
such as the Massachusetts Board of Railroad Commissioners, had 
no power to enforce their recommendations, except the power of 
pubhc opinion; whereas, others, like the Massachusetts Gas Com- 
mission, could, after a hearing, order changes in the quality and 
price of service and decide appeals as to the entrance of new com- 
panies into a field already served. Most of the early commissions 
had Jurisdiction over steam railroads only. 

The estabhshment on a large scale of modem public-service 
commissions having jurisdiction usually over all public utilities 
,, , , ,. dates from 1007. New York State by an act approved 

Modem public- • j ■,,•-, ■, , ,• • • 

service com- Jimc 0, 1907,* cstabushed two public-service commis- 
""^^^ sions; one for the coimties of New York, Kings, 

Queens, and Richmond, and the other for the rest of the State. 
Wisconsin, by an act approved July 9, 1907,^ gave to the Railroad 
Commission fuU jurisdiction over all pubhc utiUties. To-day 
every State in the Union, except Delaware, Wyoming, and Utah, 
has state raihoad or public-service commissions of one kind or 
another; and Massachusetts, New York, and South Carolina have 
each two distinct commissions. 

1 Laws 1842-47, chap. 128. ' Acts i860, chap. 408. 

• Acts z88$, chap. 314, p. 769. * Laws 1907, chap. 429. 

* Laws igoj, chap. 499. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 209 

We give herewith on pages 210-12 a list of present state com- 
missions, with the date of their establishment, which present state 
have jurisdiction over street-railway, gas, electric hl'X'^^uri'i 
light and power, or telephone properties. This list of diction over 

, ,. . . . 1 , 1 street-railway, 

pubuc-service commissions shows how recent has gas, electric 
been the establishment on any wide scale of state of teitpho^nr'' 
commissions for the regulation of local pubKc utili- §^"T"''^*'' 

ties. establishment 

The leading principles of regulation followed by these commis- 
sions with many variations as to details are as follows: — 
(i) To control competition in the interests of the j^^^. ^ _ 
public served and of security-holders. dpies of state 

(2) To insist on adequate and satisfactory ser- pubUc-service 

yj[(,g_ corporations 

(3) To maintain rates that are just and reasonable as based on 
the value and cost of the service including a fair return on a fair 
value of the property devoted to public use. 

(4) To supervise the issue of securities and the keeping of 
accoimts. 

Around these general principles has been built the modem elab- 
orate and comphcated system of state regulation of public utilities. 

Owing to the great number of state commissions and to the fact 
that most of these have been established, as stated above, only 
recently, the working-out of these principles of public p^^^^ ^, 
regulation can be seen best perhaps by discussing the sources of 
state laws and some of the most recent leading deci- in discussing 
sions and reports of the Board of Gas and Electric '^^'^ «e"iation 
Light Commissioners in Massachusetts; of the two Public-Service 
Commissions in New York State; of the Wisconsin Railroad Com- 
mission; and of the California Railroad Commission, together 
with a few decisions of special interest from other States. 

The question of the control of competition has j^^^^ .^.^^ 
come, in most cases, to mean the recognition of mo- of monopoly 
nopoly.' Recognition of monopoly is often a ques- certificates 
tion of granting rights to operate. In a great many convenience 
States, nowadays, including Massachusetts, New ^J^"! necessity 

* This does not, of course, predude competition from sources not under public con- 
trol or only partially under public control — as witness the "jitneys." 



2IO AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



PRESENT STATE COMMISSIONS HAVING JURISDICTION OVER 
ELECTRIC RAILWAY, GAS, ELECTRIC LIGHT AND POWER, 
AND TELEPHONE COMPANIES 



SUUe 


Name of commission 


Date of laws establishing 


Jurisdiction • 


Alabama! 


Railroad Commission 


Approved April 23^ 1907 


"Electnc railwaj^ and tele- 




of Alabama 




phone companies 
All public-service corpiora- 


Arizona* 


Arizona Corporation 


Approved May 28, 1912 




Commission 




tions 


California " 


Railroad Commission 


Constitutional amendment 


All public-service corpora- 




of California 


adopted October 10, 1911; 


tions — subject to the right 






act approved December 


of municipalities to retain. 






33 » 191 1 


relinquish, and resume 
their present rights over 
local utilities 


Colorado * 


Public Utilities Com- 


Approved April 12, 1913 


All public-service corpora- 




mission 




tions 


Connecticut ' 


Public Utilities Com- 


Approved July 11, 1911 


All public-service corpora- 




mission 




tions 


Florida » 


Railroad Commission- 
ers for the State of 
Florida 


Approved May 26, 191Z 


Telephone companies 


Georgia » 


Raihoad Commission 


Approved August 23. 1907 


All public-service corpora- 




of Georgia 




tions 


Idaho 8 


Public Utilities Com- 


Approved March 13, 1913 


All public-service corpora- 




mission of the State 




tions 




of Idaho 






Tllirois ■ 


State Public Utilities 


Approved June 30, 1913 


All public-service corpora- 




Commission 




tions 


Indiana*" 


Public Service Com- 


Approved March 4, 1913 


All public-service corpora- 




mission of Indiana 




tions 


Kansas" 


Public Utilities Com- 


Approved March 14, 1911 


All^ public-service corpora- 




mission for the State 




tions except those owned 




of Kansas 




by mimicipalities 


Kentucky " 


Railroad Commission 


Approved March 15, 1912, 


Telephone companies — 






and March 19, 1912 


limited jimsdiction 


Louisiana *' 


Railroad Commission 


Constitution in effect 


Telephone companies 




of Louisiana 


May 12, 1898 




Maine " 


Public Utilities Com- 


Approved March 27, 1913 


All^ public-service corpora- 




mission 




tions 


Maryland « 


Public Service Com- 


Approved April s, 1910 


All pubUc-service corpora- 




mission 




tions 



* Tliis statement is intended to indicate the scope of the jurisdiction of the various state commisaons 
only in so far as it affects those public -service corporations here in question, namely, electric railway, 
gas, dectric light, power, and telephone companies. In addition, most of the state commissions have 
jurisdiction over steam railroads, and many have jurisdiction over municipal plants, and over private 
water companies, telegraph companies, express companies, irrigation companies, pipe-lines, and other 
miscellaneous public-service enterprises not dealt with in this chapter. 

> Alabama Code Civil C1907), chap. 130, sees. 5632, 5633, 5637, s647-40» and, in general, sees. 5632- 
5725. 

* Laws IQ12, chap. 90; Rev. Stats, of Arizona (1913), sees. 2277-2360. 

* Constitution of California (1879, as amended), art. xn, sees. 10-24; l-aws igii (First Extraordinary 
Session), chaps. 14-40J see Henning's General iawjo/Ca/i/i?f«w Ci9i4)»chap. 430,p. iS33;5toto. i87S-76t 
p. 783. 

4 Laws igi3, chap. r27. See also Session Laws 1883, p. 307. 

* Public Acts ipiif chap. 128. 

" Laws 1911, chap. 6186, no. 67, and Laws 1911, chap. 6187, no. 68, superseded by Laws iQiSt chap. 
6525, no. 105. 

' Laws IQ07, no. 223, p. i^-^Codty igii, sees. 2615-70. 

8 Session Laws 1913, diap. 61; approved March 13, 1913, in effect May 7, 1913. 

" Laws IQ13, p. 459. 

10 Acts 1Q13, chap. 76; approved March 4, 1913, in effect May i, 1913. 

" Laws iQii, chap. 238; approved March 14, 1911; in effect May 22, 1911. 

" Acts 1912, chap. 99; approved March is, 1912; Acts 1912, <Jiap. 143; approved March 19, 1912. 

i> Constitution, arts. 283-289; in effect May 12, 1898. (Wolff's Constitution and Revised LawSt vol. i, 
p. 1994.) Additional powers. Acts 1908, no. 199. 

" Laws 1913, chap. 129; in effect, October 31. 1914. 

^ Laws igiOt chap. 180; amended by Laws igi2, chap. 563. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 2X1 

JURISDICTION OF STATE COMMISSIONS (continue^ 



State 



Name of commission 



Date of lavs establishing 



Jurisdiction 



Massadiusetts ^o 



Micbigan ^f 

Mississippi ^ 
Missouri " 

Montana 30 
Nebraska" 

Nevada 28 

New Hampshire *3 
New Jersey =* 
New Mexico ^^ 
New York " 



North Carolina »' 



North Dakota as 
OhioM 



Board of Gas and Elec- 
tric Light Commis- 
sioners 

Public Service Com- 
mission 

Michigan Railroad 
Commission 

Railroad Commission 

Public Service Com- 
mission of the State 
of Missouri 

Public Service Com- 
mission of Montana 

Nebraska State Rail- 
way Commission 

State Railroad Com- 
mission "Public 
Service Commis- 
sion" 

Public Service Com- 
mission 

Board of Public Utility 
Commissioners 

State Corporation 
Commission 

Public Service Com- 
missions 
First District 



Second District 
Cor^ration Com- 
mission 



Board of Railroad 

Commissioners 
Public Utilities Com- 
mission of Ohio 



Approved July 3, 19x4 
Qune II, i88s) 

In efiEect June 13, 1913 

(June IS, 1869) 
Approved Jime 2, 1909 

Approved November 1,1892 
Approved March 17, 1908 
Approved March 17, 1913 



Approved March 4, 1913 

Constitution amended No- 
vember 26, 1006; act ap- 
proved March 27, 1907 

Approved March s, 1907, 
and March 23, 1911 



In effect May 15, 1911 

Approved April 21, ign 

Constitution adopted 
November 21, 1910 
Approved June 12, 1907 



Approved March 6, 1899: 
March 14, 1901 ; March 
II, 1907; March 11, 1913 



Approved March 8, 1897, 
and March 3, 1911 

Approved May s, 1913 
(May 31. 1911) 



Gas and electric companies 

Street railways^ and tele- 
phone companies 

Electric power and telephone 
companies, interurban 
electric railways 

Telephone companies and 
electric railways 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 

Street railways^ and tele- 
phone companies 

Electric railways and tele- 
phone companies, gas, 
electric light and power 
companies 

All_ public-service corpora- 
tions 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 

Electric railways, power, and 
telephone companies 

All public -service corpora- 
tions 

Counties of New York, 
Kings, Queens, and Rich- 
mond 

Balance of State 

Street railways and tele- 
phone companies, gas, 
electric ^ light and power 
companies — except those 
owned by municipalities 

Telephone companies 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 



!• Acts 1885, chap. 314, and acts in amendment thereof. For present law see act approved July 3, 1914; 
Acts I0I4, chap. 742; Acts i86g, chap. 408. Present board established by act in effect June 13, 1913; Acts 
jgzst chap. 784- 

" PubUc Acts igoQ,iio. 300, approved June 2, i909,)ineffectSeptember 1,1909, succeeding former Rail- 
road Commiission. See also Pvbhc Acts, igii, no. 138, as amended hy Public Acts 1013, no. 206. Public 
Acts IQOQ, no. 106. 

u Mississippi Code igo6, chap. 139, sees. 4826-^; Laws igo8, chap. 80. 

M laws IQ13, p. 556. » Laws 1913, chap. 52. 

>i ConsHluHon, art. 5, sec. 19a; Statutes 1007, chap. 90; Revised Statutes, igi3, sees. 6104-55. 

^ Statutes IQ07, chap. 44; approved March 5, 1907' See R. L. 1912, sees. 4549~85; StaitUes /p77,chap. 
162; R. L. I0I2, sees. 4515-48; R. L. igi2, sec. 45So(2), 

28 XflWi ipzj, chap. 164; Public Statutes and Session Laws (Supplement, I9i3)» PP- 33S-6o. 

M Laws igii, chap. 195. 

*> Constitution, art. xi, sees, 7-11: adopted November 21, 1010. See also Laws 1012, chap. 78. 

10 La-ios 1007, chap. 429; approved Jxme 12, 1907; in effect July i, 1907; amended by Lawj igiOj chaps. 
480, 673; and by Laws 1913, chaps. 344» 5o4. Sos. 5o6, 597. etc. For the law as amended, see Birdseye, 
Cons. Laws (Suppl. 1910-13), pp. 2145-2245. For list 01 all amendments, see Lawj 1013 CExtraordinary 
Session), Table of Laws and Codes amended or repealed, p. 72. 

*' Pi^Uc Laws 1809, chap. 164: Public Laws igoi, chap. 679; Public Laws 1007, chaps. 469, 966; Pell's 
Reoisal of 1^08., sees. 1054 to 1118, as amended by Public Laws 1011, chap. 197; Public Laws 1013 (Extraor- 
dinary Session), chap. 63; Public Iaiws 1913^ chap. 127. 

" Laws 1807, chap. 115. Compiled Laws igiSt sees. 4708-83; also ibid., sees. S79~6oi. See also Laws 
zgiz, chap. 241. 

>B House Bill no. 582; approved May 5, 1913 (Laws 1913, p. 804). superseding Public Service Commis- 
sion established by House Bill no. 325; approved May 31, igzi; in effect June 30, igiz {Laws igzi. 
p. 549)- 



212 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 
JURISDICTION OF STATE COMMISSIONS {continued) 



State 



Name of commission Date of lava establishing 



Jurisdiction 



Oklahoma '" 
Oregon " 
Pennsylvania " 

Rhode Island " 
South Carolina " 



South Dakota » 

Tennessee 8^ 
Vennont " 

Virginia '8 



Washington » 
West Virginia *" 
Wisconsin ** 



Corporation Commis- 
sion 

Railroad Commission 
of Oregon 

Public _ Service Com- 
mission of the Com- 
monwealth of Penn- 
sylvania 

Public Utilities Com- 
mission 

Railroad Commission 



Public^ Service Com- 
mission 
Railroad Commission 
Railroad Commission 
Public Service Com- 
mission 
State Corporation 
Commission 

Public Service Com- 
mission 

Public Service Com 
mission 

Railroad Commission 
of Wisconsin 



Constitution adopted 1907; 

act approved March 25, 

1913 
In effect November 2g, 

Z912 

Approved July 26, 1913 



Approved April 17, 1912 

Constitution adopted 

December 3i> 1S95; act 

approved February 25, 

1904; act in effect 

February 24, 1913 
Approved February 23, 

zgio 
Approved March 10, 1911 
Approved April 3, 1913 
ApjOTOved January 20, 1909 

(December 14, 1906) 
Approved April 15, 1903 

and March 27. 1914 

Approved March 18, 1911 
Passed February 21, 1913 
Approved July 9, 1907 



All public-service corpora- 
tions 

All public-service corpora- 
tions except those owned 
by municipalities 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 



All public-service corpora- 
tions 

Interurban electric railwaj^, 
power t, and telephone 

companies 



Gas and electric companies 
except in certain cities 

Telephone companies 

Telephone comi)anies 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 

All^ public-service corpora- 
tions; limited in case of 
electric railways 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 

All^ public-service corpora- 
tions 

All public-service corpora- 
tions 



80 Constitution of 1Q07, art. K, sees. IS-3S; Session Laws 19x3^ chap. 93. 

»i taws iQiif chap. 279. " Laws IQ13, no. 854. ^a l^ws igia, chap. 795. 

84 Laws iQiOj no. 286; Laws 19x2, no. 310; Constitution (adopted December 31. i89S)» art. ix, sec. 14; 
Laws i8g8, no. 486; Laws 1904, chap. 281; Laws 1913, no. zig. See Civil Code 1912^ sees. 3i3&~64* 

85 Session Laws igii, chap. 207. 
88 Public Acts IQ13, chap. 32. 

8' Laws iQoSj chap. 116; Laws IQ12, no. 166; Laws 1906, no. 126. 

88 Acts 1903-03-04, chap. 147. Pollard's Code (1904)* sec. 1313a; see also iWd., sec. I2g4a; Acts 1914, 
chap. 340- 

w Laws 1911, chap. 117. ** Ads 1913* chap. 9. 

«i Laws 1907, chap. 499; approved July 9, J907; published Jxily 11, 1907; Laws 1907, chap. 578; ap- 
proved July 12, 1907; published July 13, 1907. See also Laws 1907, chaps. 454 and 614; Laws 1911, chap. 
663. For these and other amendments see Wisconsin Statutes (1911), sees. 1795-1797T-12. See also 
Laws i$i3, chap. 772. sees. 101-03; chaps. 63, 66, 331, 401, 4S3« 5i8. S23» 603, 621, 681, and 755- 

t Jurisdiction over power companies is not clear. 



York, Pennsylvania, Ohio, Wisconsin, and California,* these rights 

are granted through the issue of certificates of public convenience 

and necessity. 2 

* Massachusetts: Acts IQ06, chap. 463, part 2, sees. 18, 21, 24, and 71; and part 3, 
sec. 7, as amended by Acts igog^ chap. 417, sec. i; Acts 1914, chap. 742, sees. 155-60; 
Acts igi4, chap. 787, sees. 9 and 10; see also Acts 1910, chap. 518; Acts igo6j ehap. 463, 
part 3, sees. 9 and 44; Acts igiij chap. 442; Acts iQo8f chap. 266; New York: Laws 
igio, chap. 480, sees. 53 and 68; chap. 481, sees, g and 10; chap. 673, sec. 3; N,Y. Cons, 
LawSy chap. 48, sees. 53, 68, and 99 (i); Pennsylvania: Laws zpij, no. 854, art. 3, 

^ It has been remarked with some show of reason that, xinder modem conditions, 
public-service corporation franchises exist to enable bankers to sell the bonds. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 213 

Certificates of public convenience and necessity are not issued 
unless the commissions are convinced that the granting of addi- 
tional facilities is for the public good. The commis- conditions 
sions have taken the position that duplication of under which 
plants is paid for, in the long run, either by the public of pubUc 
in poorer service or higher rates or by security-holders anTnecSy 
in losses on their investment. Accordingly, unless the "® '^^"^"^ 
granting of rights to do a competitive business is absolutely neces- 
sary, in the opinion of the commission, in order to obtain good ser- 
vice or reasonable rates, such rights are not granted.^ In Indiana ^ 
and in Wisconsin ' even a municipality cannot compete with an 
existing public-service corporation without first obtaining a certifi- 
cate of public convenience and necessity.* 

Closely coimected with the recognition by commissions of the 

sees. 2, 3, and 5; art. 5, sees. 18 and 19; Ohio: Laws ipiz, House Bill, no. 325, sec. 54; 
Wisconsin: Laws igi3, chap. 621; chap. 755, sec. 2 (sec. 1596, 62-64),' Laws igoy, chap. 
4S4, sec. 1797-39; California: Stats, igii, Extra. Session, p. 18; Henning's General Laws 
of California (1914), chap. 430, act 3775, sec. 50. For laws of other States covering 
certificates of public convenience and necessity see Arizona: Laws ipi2, chap. 90, 
sec. so; Rev. Stats. 1913, Civil Code, sec. 2326; Colorado: Session Laws 1913, chap. 127, 
sec. 3s; Connecticut: Public Acts i8gg, chap. 158, sees. 1-4; General Stats. igo2, sees. 
3846, 3917, 3920; Idaho: Session Laws igi3, chap. 61, sec. 48; Illinois: act approved 
June 30, 1913, sec. ss; Laws igi3, p. 488; Indiana: Acts igi3, chap. 76, sees. 97-98; 
Kansas: Laws igii, chap. 238, see. 31; Maine: Rev. Stats., chap. SS, sec. i, as amended 
by Laws igi3, chap. 129, sees. 27 and 28, in effect October 31, 1914; Maryland: Laws 
igio, chap. 180, sees. 26 and 33; Michigan: Public Acts igi3, no. 206, sec. 9; Missouri: 
Senate Bill no. i, approved March 17, 1913, sees. S3, 74, and 96; Laws igi3, p. 556; 
New Hampshire: Laws igii, chap. 164, sec. 12 (o) and sec. 13 (a), as amended by 
Laws igi3, chap. 145, sec. 13; South Dakota: Session Laws igii, chap. 211; Vermont: 
Public Stats. igo6, sec. 4338. 

1 Weld II. Gas and Electric Light Comrs., 197 Mass. ss6, 84 N.E. loi; Atty.-General 
»; Haverhill Gas Light Co., 215 Mass. 394; Atty.-General ex rel. v. Walworth L. & P. 
Co., IS7 Mass. 86, 31 N.E. 482, 16 L.R.A. 398; In re Longaere Electric Light & Power 
Co., Public Service Com. Reports, ist Dist. (New York), vol. i, p. 226, affirmed on 
appeal in People ex rel. The N.Y. Edison Co. v. Willcox et al., 207 N.Y. 86 (reversing 
151 N.Y. App. Div. 832); Calumet Service Co. v. Chilton, 148 Wis. 334, 135 N.W. 131; 
State ex rel. Kenosha G. & E. Co. v. Kenosha Electric Ry. Co., 145 Wis. 337, 129 N.W. 
600 (confirmation by State Supreme Court of monopoly principle) ; Pacific G. &. E. Co. 
V. Great Western Power Co., Opinions and Orders of the Railroad Commission of Cali- 
fornia, vol. 1, p. 203; In re Oro Electric Corp'n. Transmission Lines, ibid., p. 253; 
In re Application Oro Electric Corp'n, ibid., p. 700. 

2 Acts igi3, chap. 76, see. 98. 

' Laws igoy, chap. 499, sec. 1797M-74, sees. 3 and 4. 

* In Massachusetts, the same result is arrived at by the statute compelling a muni- 
cipality, which has voted to establish a municipal plant, to purchase at a fair value the 
existing plant of the local public-service corporation. {Acts 1914, chap. 742, sec. 100.) 



214 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

monopoly principle is the power to approve consolidations. The 
Attitude of general rule is that consolidations are permitted when 
towSd con- i^ the judgment of the commissions they will result in 
soUdations better service or lower rates.^ 

In Massachusetts, when two companies are consolidated, the 

capital of the new company at the time of consolidation shall not 

exceed in amount the smn of the separate capitals of 

Basis on which . o t -..x \t i r^/ . .1 

consolidations the former compames/ In New York state, the 
are penmtte gccond District Commission recently has been per- 
mitting the purchase of one company by another at a price in excess 
of the original cost of the physical property, provided such excess 
is amortized or charged off from earnings during a reasonable period 
of years.' In Wisconsin, the purchase of the property of one public- 
service corporation by another shall be at a price not in excess of 
the value, as determined by the commission.* 
„ ., , In view of the general recognition of public-ser- 

Possible . ^ 1- ^T. , r 

municipal vice Corporations as monopoues, the laws of many 

pure ase States, among which may be mentioned Massachu- 

setts,^ Illinois,® and Wisconsin,^ provide for possible purchase of 

^ For recent cases in consoKdations see Massachusetts: Springfield-Chicopee, 
Twenty-eighth Ann. Rep., Board of Gas and Electric Light Comrs. (1912), p. 67; New 
Bedford Gas Co. and New Bedford Elec. Co., Fourth Ann. Rep., Board of Gas and 
Electric Light Comrs. (1889), p. 73; Worcester Gas Light Co. and Worcester Electric 
Light Co., Sixth Ann. Rep., Board of Gas and Electric Light Comrs. (1891), p. 12; 
New York: In the Matter of the Joint Application of Rockland Light and Power Co. 
and Rockland Electric Co., etc.. Public Service Com., 2d Dist. (New York), no. 176, 
decided April 28, 1914. California: In the Matter of the Application of Midland Coun- 
ties Public Service Corporation, 3 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 598; In the Matter of the 
Application of Valley Gas and Fuel Co., etc., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 589; In the 
Matter of the AppUcation of Livermore Water & Power Co., etc., 2 Cal. R. R. Com. 
Dec. 618. See also New York Laws 1910, chap. 480, sec. 54, as amended by Laws 
IQ14, chap. 220. 

' Acts igi4, chap. 742, sec. 168. In view of the fact that in Massachusetts public- 
service corporations cannot have a total capitalization in excess of their physical value, 
this is equivalent to saying that companies formed through consolidations cannot have 
a capitalization in excess of the physical property. 

' See Public-Service Commission, New York, 2d District, Eighth Annual Report 
(1914), p. 67, and no. 176, dated April 28, 1914 (Rockland Light and Power case). 

* Wisconsin Statutes (1911), chap. 85, sec. 1753-11; Laws igu, chap. 593, sec. 
17S3-11, as amended by Laws igii, chap. 664, sec. 133, 

' Ads igi4, chap. 742, sees. 92 to 125. 

° Laws igi3, p. 455. (Senate Bill no. 538, approved June 26, 1913.) 

' Laws igo7, chap. 499, sec. 1797M-79 to 82, as amended by Laws igog, chap. 213, 
and by Laws igii, chaps. 13 and 596, and by Laws igi3, chap. z6o. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 21 5 

the property of local public-service corporations by the munici- 
palities. In our opinion, this right, whether exercised or not, should 
exist in all States. 

As soon as the principle of monopoly is recognized, the questions 
of rates and service become of prime importance. We „ , . 

.,11 ,-1 1 . !• . 1 Regulation 

Will take up first the regulation of service as estab- of rates and 
lished by statutes and by commission decisions and 
reports. 

In the past, standards of service often have been prescribed by 
direct legislative enactment.' The modem tendency, however, is 
to give public-service commissions general authority Regulation 
to enforce standards of service. In Massachusetts, <>' service 
New York, Wisconsin, and California, as well as in many other 
States, the powers so granted to the commissions are fairly com- 
plete and comprehensive. The authority of the commissions in 
Massachusetts ^ to investigate and change service is especially com- 
plete. The Wisconsin ' law goes so far as to make mandatory on 
the commission the ascertaining and prescribing, "for each kind 
of public utility, suitable and convenient standard commercial 
units of product or service." The extent of the authority of state 
commissions over service shows a tendency all the time to increase. 

In the matter of service there are usually three elements to be 
considered: — _, , ,. 

Three leading 

(1) Safety. elements of 

(2) Extent of service. 

(3) Character of service. 

Any two of these elements, and sometimes all three combined, 
are likely to appear in a single case involving the regulation of 
service. 

On the question of the safety of service, the statutes in a large 
majority of the States confer specific authority on the commis- 
sions to prescribe such regulations as may insure safety of 
safety of operation.* This is true m the four States, ^^'^^ 

• Standard quality of gas fixed in Connecticut. See Gen. Stats. igo2, sec. 4569, and 
in Ohio, General Code igio, sees. 9326-31. 

2 Acts igi4, chap. 742, sees. 161, 162, 163; Acts 1913, chap. 784, sees. 23-24. 
' Laws igo7, chap. 499, sec. i7g7M-22 to 23. 

* See Commission Regidation of Public Utilities, New York (1913), p. 651, and 
following. 



2l6 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Massachusetts/ New York,'' Wisconsin,' and California,^ which 
we have taken as illustrating many of the principles in this 
chapter. 

In the matter of the extent of the service, the general rule is that 
service shall be as nearly imiversal in extent as is practicable under 
Extent of th^ circumstances. Service in excess of the reasonable 

service needs of a community and service inadequate to the 

reasonable needs of a community, both are discouraged, although 
the commissions naturally are inclined to approve service too elab- 
orate rather than service at all likely to be considered inadequate.^ 

Provision is made in many States, including Massachusetts,® 
Wisconsin,^ and California,* for joint use of facilities or through 
Joint use of scrvice by two or more public-service corporations. 
faauties -pjjg California Commission in a recent case ' ordered 

physical connection, through routes and joint rates, for telephone 
service against the objection of one of the companies. 

In the matter of the character of the service, the commissions 
either lay down definite imiform standards, £is in Wisconsin, or de- 
Character cide the question of service on the merits of each indi- 
of service vidual case, as in Massachusetts. To enforce a proper 
standard of service, the Massachusetts Conamission, upon com- 
plaint, and the Wisconsin Commission upon its own initiative and 
as a matter of periodic practice, make, sometimes with the assist- 

' Acts igo6, chap. 463, part 3, sec. go, as amended by Acts igi3, chap. 357; chap. 
784, sees. 23-24. 

* Laws 1 910, chap. 480, sec. 49, 2; see Birdseye, C. & G. Consol. Laws, Suppl. 1910- 
13, p. 2180; Laws igio, chap. 480, sec. 66, 2; see Birdseye, C. & G., Consol. Laws, 
Suppl. 1910-13, p. 2201. 

' Laws igii, chap. 297, sec. 1797-90 and 96; Laws 1907, chap. 454, sec. 1797-57, 
as amended by Laws igog, chap. 475, Laws igii, chap. 590, sec. 1797-1216. 

* Stats, igii, Extra. Sess., p. 18, as amended by Stats, igis, p. 942. See Henning's 
Gen. Laws of California, vol. s (1914), chap. 430, sec. 42, p. 1549. 

' See decision of the California Railroad Commission ordering the San Joaquin 
Light and Power Corporation to serve certain ranchers, irrespective of whether such 
additional consumers will provide a return equal to that from the present patrons, 
provided the system as a whole is operated at a profit. (Raoney v. San Joaquin Light 
and Power Co., s Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 587.) 

' Acts igii, chap. 487. 

' Laws igo7, chap. 499, sec. 1797M-4, as amended by Laws igii, chap. 546. 

' Stats, igii, ist Extra. Sess., p. 18, sec. 40-41. Henning's Gen. Laws of California 
(19 14), vol. s, chap. 430, p. 1549. 

« Tehama County Tel. Co. v. Pacific Tel. & Tel. Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Decisions, 
104 (1913). 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 217 

ance of the public-service corporations themselves, thorough tests 
of the facilities and service furnished. 

In all matters of service, the general principle, familiar in rail- 
road regulation, is laid down that service shall not be other pnn- 
discriminatory as against persons or places. 1 Further- regulation 
more, service shall be, as far as possible, free from ȣ service 
accidents, uninterrupted and uniform. 

Regulation of service should be at once efl&dent and flexible. It 
is to be remembered that conditions of service in different places and 
at different times vary greatly. "Every State pre- ^^ j^^^^^ 
sents some peculiar conditions that deserve consider- of service 

. . _, 1 • T T should be 

ation. A praine state which has no water-power, no efficient and 
cheap fuel, which is essentially an agricultural dis- *" 
trict, with few, if any, large cities, certainly differs from one with 
large urban centers, which abounds in natural resources and which 
possesses many large isolated power users." " Furthermore, the 
cost of the service, the commercial possibilities, and every other 
factor entering into each individual case should be taken into con- 
sideration.' 

The interrelationship between service and rates is obvious. If 
the rates for street-railway, gas, electric Ught and power, or tele- 
phone service are too low, the character of the service , , . 

, . Interrelation- 

is almost sure to suffer. On the other hand, if the ship of service 
service prescribed is elaborate and expensive, the 
rates charged for such service must be, other things being equal, 
correspondingly high. 

' Postal Cable Telegraph Co. v. Cumberland T. & T. Co., 177 Fed. Rep. 726; 
Hatch V. Consumers' Co., Ltd., 17 Idaho, 204, 104 Pac. 670, 40 L.R.A. (N.S.) 263; 
Central Union Telephone Co. v. State ex rel., 118 Ind. 194, 19 N.E. 604; Kjlboum City 
V. Southern Wis. Power Co., 149 Wis. 168, 135 N.W. 499; Pond, Ptiblic Utilities 
(Indianapolis, 1913), chap, xm, sees. 208 to 229. 

* L. H. Harris, Service RegtUations for Electrical Utilities in State Regulation of 
Public Utilities (Philadelphia, 1914), p. 286. 

' For a few recent cases in commission regulation of service see Massachusetts: 
Petition of the Cambridge Board of Trade relative to service of the Boston Elevated 
Railway, First Annual Report, Public-Service Commission (1914), p. 133; Petitions 
of E. H. Vaughan in re Worcester Consolidated Street Railway, ibid., p. 157; Peti- 
tion of Customers v. Natick Gas Light Company, Twenty-eighth Annual Report, 
Board of Gas and Electric Light Commissioners, p. 32. New York: In the matter of 
Additional Cars on Brooklyn Lmes, 3 P. S. C. R. (ist Dist., N.Y.), 37 and 716. Cali- 
fornia: City of San Jos6 v. Pacific Tel. & Tel. Co., 3 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 720 (1913). 
Wisconsin: Civic League et al. v. Beaver Dam Water Co., 10 W. R. C. R. 661. 



2l8 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

In the matter of rates to be charged by public-service corpora- 
tions, the following principles prevail: (i) Rates must be reasonable 
Principles of both to the customer and to the corporation, and if 
pubii?tS^ce" they caimot be reasonable to both, they must be to the 
corporations customer — that is, the customer cannot be made to 
pay more than a fair value of the service rendered; * (2) there must 
be a fair return on the reasonable value of the property at the time 
it is being used for the pubUc.^ These principles have been estab- 
lished by federal and state laws and confirmed by nimierous de- 
cisions of the courts.' 

To-day a large number of the States give the public-service com- 
missions mandatory power over rates. The right to initiate rates 
A *T, -^ r is reserved almost everywhere to the utilities. In a 

Autnon^ of i .• 

commissions large number of the States, however, the commissions 

ov6r r3.tcs ■ 

are given authority to suspend the operation of rates 
fixed by utilities pending an investigation by the commissions as 
to their reasonableness.* 

Provided the rates charged for service are not in excess of the 
value of the service to the consumers, rates for public service are 

based on what may be called, in the broadest sense, the 
ser^ce,\ost° cost of the service. This cost has been early defined 
the broadest ^ Massachusetts ^ as made up of the following three 
sense, is the factors: (i) Fair cost, meaning fair manufacturing 

cost of the product or service; (2) a fair return on a 
reasonable amoimt of capital; (3) such excess as will give the cor- 
poration sufficient surplus to meet extraordinary accidents and con- 
duct its business with the highest economy. In New York State,^ it 

' Brunswick & T. Water Dist. v. Maine Water Co., 99 Maine, 371, 59 Atl. 537 
(1904); Covington & Lex. Turnpike Co. v. Sandford, 164 U.S. 578; Spring Valley 
Water Works v. San Francisco, 192 Fed. Rep. 137. 

" Peckliam, J., in Willcox v. Cons. Gas Co., 212 U.S. 19, at 41. 

' See Smjfth v. Ames, 169 U.S. 466, at 546. 

* See State Regulation of Public Utilities (Philadelphia, 1914), p. 16. For commission 
orders changing rates see Massachusetts: Mayor of Worcester v. Worcester Electric 
Light Co., Board of G. & E. Lt. Comrs., Twenty-eighth Annual Report (1912), p. 15; 
New York: Fuhrmaiin v. Cataract Power and Conduit Co., 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist., N.Y.), 
p. 656 (1913); Wisconsin: City of Milwaukee v. The Milwaukee E. R. & L. Co., 10 
W. R. C. R. I (1912); California: City of San Jos6 v. Pacific Tel. & Tel. Co., 3 Cal. R.R. 
Com. Dec. 720 (1913). 

' See petition of customers of the Springfield Gas Comf)any for reduction in price, 
Report, Board of Gas and Electric Light Commissioners (1894), p. 6. 

' Laws igio, chap. 480, sec. 97. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 219 

is provided by statute that in making rates due regard must be 
given to a reasonable average return upon the value of the property 
actually used in the public service and to the necessity of making 
reservation out of income for surplus and contingencies. In Wiscon- 
sin, 1 the Railroad Commission has laid down the following rule : that 
"under normal or ordinary conditions, public utilities are entitled 
to earnings that will cover the operating expenses, including de- 
predation and a fair return on the investment." The methods of 
determining the cost of service as a basis for rates in Massachusetts, 
New York, and Wisconsin have been followed, in a general way, 
by all the other state commissions. 

The factor in the cost of service that has caused the most diffi- 
culty and the most discussion is what has been called a fair return 
on a reasonable amoimt of capital or on a reasonable ^ . 

1 •■ 1 !• r™ • Fair return 

value of the property devoted to pubhc use. This on fair value 
question involves, (i) what is a fair rate of return; (2) ° ^'°^^ ^ 
what constitutes a fair value of property devoted to public use. 

The rate of return on capital invested in public-service corpora- 
tions is governed, in a broad way, by the rate of return on other 
forms of investment.^ Obviously, however, the rate 

, , •. 1 • . 1 ■ .. 1 Rate of return 

of return on capital mvested m corporations under 
public protection should be less than the rate of return on capital 
invested in competitive or extra-hazardous undertakings. Again, 
the rate of return where the business is well managed should be 
greater than the rate of return where it is poorly managed. In gen- 
eral, the rate of return should be a rate that permits continued 
investment in old properties and induces original investment in 
new properties.' No hard-and-fast rule can be laid down as to 
what constitutes a fair rate of return, but this rate must be deter- 
mined in each individual case and after taking into consideration 
all the factors which bear on the problem.* 

' In re Appl. Manitowoc Gas Co., 3 Wis. R.R. Com. Rep. 163, at 171 (1908). 

2 New Memphis Gas Light Co. ti. Memphis, 72 Fed. Rep. 952. 

' An interesting suggestion has been brought forward recently called the "variable 
rate of return." This plan involves increasing the rate of return in proportion to a 
reduction in the average selling price of the product or service and is similar to the 
sliding scale arrangement discussed earlier in this chapter. (See Henry I. Lea, The 
Fixed Rate of Return on Utilities, reprinted from the Gas Record, Chicago, November 

25. 1914-) 

* See United States Supreme Court: Willcox v. Consolidated Gas Co., 212 U.S. 19, 
29 Sup. Ct. 192; S3 L. ed. 382 (1909), six per cent; New York: (ist Dist. Commission) 



220 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Determination of what is the fair value of the property devoted 
to public use leads to the vast and extremely complicated subject 
Fair value of of Valuation as a basis for rates. In Massachusetts 
property ^j^^ ^ California, among other States, the commis- 

sions may make valuations, and in Wisconsin, the commission 
must make valuations of the property of any and all public-service 
corporations.^ 

There are to-day two leading theories as to the proper method of 
valuation as a basis for rates: (i) The so-called original-cost theory; 
Two theories and (2) the theory of cost of reproduction.^ Some 
asTbasS™ commissions base their findings almost entirely on 
ferrates ^hg original-cost-theory; for example, the St. Louis 

Public-Service Commission.^ Other commissions ^ have appeared 
at times to accept without reservation the cost-of-reproduction 
theory. 

The best and most recent authorities, however, are disposed to 
Best modem f oUow no ouc theory, but to base their findings as to 
practice favors valuation upon all the factors which may enter into the 

considenng all . -r ■• »• 1 • 1 c i 

elements in de- question. In Massachusetts, owmg to the fact that 
vatoe'as a S^is HO public-service Corporation has been able to issue 
for rates capital stock except for cash or property, there has 

Mayhew v. Kings County Lighting Company, 2 P. S. C. 659 (1911), 7I per cent; 
Wisconsin: State Journal Printing Co. v. Madison Gas and Electric Co., 4 W. R. C. R. 
SOI, 626-49 (1910); California: Contra Costa Water Co. v. City of Oakland, 159 Cal. 
323; 113 Pac. 668 (1911); City of Palo Alto v. Palo Alto Gas Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. 
Dec. 300 (1913) ; Massachusetts: Haverhill Petitions, Board of Gas and Electric Light 
Comrs., Twenty-eighth Annual Report,.p. 41. 

' Massachusetts: Acts igis, chap. 784, sec. 14; California: Stats, igii, ist Extra. 
Sess., chap. 14, sees. 47 and 70, as amended hy Stats. IQ13, chap. 339; Wisconsin: 
Laws 190S, chap. 362; Slats, jgii, sec. 1797-20; Laws 11)07, chap. 499, Stats, igii, 
sees. 1797M-S to 1797M-7, 1797M-16, 1797M-42. 

^ There is another theory of valuation which has sometimes been called the cost-of- 
replacement theory, which considers the cost of replacing to-day, not the same prop- 
erty, but property which will perform the same service: there is also a "fair-exchange 
value," which is based largely on what the property may be expected to earn. How- 
ever useful these theories may be in cases of purchase or condemnation, they are of 
very little use, it seems to us, in fixing a basis for rates. See Missouri Rate Cases, 230 
U.S. 474, 33 Sup. Ct. 975 (1913); Public-Service Gas Co. v. Board of Public-Utility 
Comrs., 84 N.J. Law, 463, 87 Ati. 651 (1913); Fuhrmaim v. Cataract Power and Con- 
duit Co., 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 656 (1913). 

' See Report St. Louis Public-Service Commission, to the Municipal Assembly of 
St. Louis, on the Southwestern Tel. & Tel. Co. (October 14, 1913), pp. 9, 12-13. 

* See Report, Public-Utilities Commission (Connecticut, 1912), pp. xxvn and 

XXXVI. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 221 

not been developed any particular theory or system of valuation.* 
In New York State, the Second District Commission in the Buffalo 
Gas case * discussed various theories of valuation. After stating 
the objections to these theories, Chairman Stevens said: "It is 
a question whether any of these theories can be applied alone to 
a given case and produce a result of substantial equity and 
justice." The Wisconsin Commission in a recent case said: "The 
value of a plant and its business that is ultimately found to be fair 
and equitable under the circumstances may not agree either with 
the original cost or with the cost of reproduction, but in most in- 
stances it is likely to be foimd at some figure in the neighbor- 
hood of these costs." ' The CaUfomia Commission in certain cases 
disallowed reproduction cost where that cost was in excess of the 
original cost.* 

In another case, the California Commission laid emphasis on the 
importance of considering all elements of value.^ In ascertaining 
the value of the property of the Stockton Terminal & Eastern 
Railroad Company, the California Commission considered the 
following matters: (i) Organization, construction, and operation; 
(2) stocks and bonds; (3) revenues and expenses; (4) original cost, 
as defined; (5) reproduction value, as defined; (6) present value, as 
defined. " In the case of new properties, emphasis may be laid, per- 
haps, on original cost; in the case of properties built many years 
ago, it is more difficult to determine original cost and more natural 
to take cost of reproduction as a guide in determining value. To 
sum up, the best modem practice favors considering all proper ele- 
ments of value as a basis for rates. The origin and development of 
the business, the conditions under which the plant was constructed, 
the actual investment made, the present value of the plant, and any 
other factors having a bearing in any given case should be considered. 

On the question of valuation when finally appealed to the United 

• See Haverhill Gas Light case, Twenty-eighth Annual Report, Board of Gas and 
Electric Light Comrs., pp. 41-60. 

' Buffalo Gas Co. v. City of Buffalo, 3 P. S. C. (ad Dist. N.Y.) SS3, at 632 (1913). 
' City of Milwaukee v. The Milwaukee Electric Railway & Light Co., 10 W. R. C. 
R. I (1912). 

• San Jos6 v. The Pacific Tel. & Tel. Co., 3 Cal. R.R. Com., Dec. 720 (1913). 

' Re Water Rates and Service in the County of San Diego, 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 
464, at $11-12 (1913). 

• 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 777, 779 (1913). 



222 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

States Supreme Court, the court held, in Smyth v. Ames,' that " the 
,, . , „ basis of all calculations as to the reasonableness of 

United States . ... 

Supreme Court rates to be charged by a corporation mamtammg a 
a° a basts™ highway tmder legislative sanction must be the fair 
for rates yalue of the property being used by it for the conven- 

ience of the public. And in order to ascertain that value, the origi- 
nal cost of construction, the amount expended in permanent im- 
provements, the amount and market value of its bonds and stock, 
the present as compared with the original cost of construction, the 
probable earning capacity of the property imder particular rates 
prescribed by statute, and the sum required to meet operating ex- 
penses, are all matters for consideration, and are to be given such 
weight as may be Just and right in each case. We do not say that 
there may not be other matters to be regarded in estimating the 
value of the property." In the Minnesota Rate Cases,^ it held that 
"the ascertainment of that value is not controlled by artificial 
rules. It is not a matter of formulas, but there must be a reasonable 
judgment having its basis in a proper consideration of all relevant 
facts." In these latter cases, the court spoke of the cost of reproduc- 
tion as an important element in determining value, but it warned 
against accepting results which depend on mere conjecture. 

All the various details of the valuation question, we will not 
Methods of attempt to discuss in this chapter. We will simply 
certain™etaiis Consider briefly some of the most important and in- 
of valuation tcrestiug phases. Among these may be mentioned: — 

(i) Should land be valued on the same basis as other parts of the 
property? 

(2) In estimating cost of reproduction new of plant, should 
present unit prices be taken or average unit prices for a series of 
years? 

(3) In estimating cost of reproduction new, should present con- 
ditions of construction other than the present cost of material and 
labor be taken or should there be taken the conditions under which 
the plant actually was constructed? 

(4) Should depreciation be deducted either from original cost 
or cost of reproduction new? 

' 169 U.S. 466, at 546. 

' Hughes, J., in the Minnesota rate cases, 230 U. S. 352, 434, 33 Sup. Ct. 729 (1913). 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 223 

(5) How much should be allowed for overhead charges in con- 
struction, for development expense, for going concern value, or for 
franchise value ? 

The practice of some of the leading commissions in these matters 
will further illustrate their attitude toward valuation. 

In valuing land for the purpose of fixing rates, commissions gen- 
erally use the present value of land."- In New York State, the Com- 
mission for the First District has tried to avoid Methods of 
making the community pay rates which are higher in ^''""e land 
proportion to the growth and increase in activities of the commun- 
ity itself. It has treated the estimated average annual increase in 
the value of land of the company as income, but in this the commis- 
sion has been overruled by the courts.'' In California, in the Tono- 
pah & Tide Water Railroad case, the coramission has expressed the 
opinion that the basis of return on real property shall be even less 
than "the fair average market value of similar land in the vicinity, 
including the unearned increment." ' The general rule, however, 
is for state commissions to take the present value of land. 

In the leading cases on this question taken to the United States 
Supreme Court, the theory of the present value of land as a basis 
for rates has been held as the proper one. In the „ . , „ 

-.«•• X, ^ ^ ■, „ 1 1 r United states 

Minnesota Rate Cases,* the court allowed a value for Supreme Court 
lands equal to the fair average market value of similar °° ^* """^ ^ 
land in the vicinity, but did not allow for various special costs in- 
volved in acquiring the particular land wanted. 

On the question of whether in figuring cost of repro- ^^^ practice 
duction new, prices at the time of making the valu- ^^^°^^ ^^ °^ 

' '^ , , ° average prices 

ation or average pnces for a senes of years should in estimating 
be taken, the best opinion seems to favor the use of duction new 
average unit prices for a series of, say, five years.' °* ^'^°' 

' In New York (2d Dist.), Fuhrmann v. Cataract Power & Conduit Co., 3 P. S. C. 
(2d Dist. N.Y.) 656 (1913). In Wisconsin, Superior Commercial Club v. Superior 
Water, Light & Power Co., 11 W. R. C. R. 704 (1912). The United States Supreme 
Court has adopted this view. Minnesota Rate Cases; 230 U.S. 352, 33 Sup. Ct. 729 
(1913). The St. Louis Commission has abandoned its original-cost theory, when deal- 
ing with land. (Report, St. Louis Public Service Commission, to the Municipal Assem- 
bly of St. Louis on the Southwestern Tel. & Tel. Co. (October 14, 1913), pp. 9-10.) 

* See Kings County Lighting Co. a. Willcox, 156 N.Y. App. Div. 603 (1913). 

' 3 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 205 (1913). * 230 U.S. 352, 33 Sup. Ct. 729. 

6 Petition of Berlin Elec. Light Co. et al., 3 N.H. P. S. C. 174, 196 (1913); City of 
Milwaukee ». Milwaukee Elec. Ry. & Light Co., 10 Wis. R. C. R. i, 107, 108. 



224 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The use of present unit costs is likely to be unfair if the date 
of valuation happens to be at a time of unusually high or low 
prices.^ 

The question of whether present or actual conditions of con- 
struction should be taken as the basis of estimating the cost of 
Pavement reproduction new has come up so far principally in 

over mains ^j^g f^j^j^j gf whether allowance should be made for 
pavement over mains. Where such pavement has not been part of 
the actual cost of installing property, the best practice refuses to 
allow anything for this item.^ 

As far as the position of the United States Supreme Court goes, 

there are certain statements of the court which seem to indicate an 

opinion that allowance should be made for pavement 

United states over mains. In Willcox v. Consolidated Gas Com- 

Supreme Court , . , . . . , i • i 

pany," the question was not, however, squarely raised, 
and this decision is hardly to be taken as indicating the final opinion 
of the court on this point. Where a corporation has not been at any 
actual expense to pave over mains, and where it has not expected 
any allowance to be made for this item, — in which its expectation 
would be different from that in the case of land, — the commis- 
sions, it seems to us, have no good groimd for allowing anything for 
this item in estimating value as a basis for rates. 

In the matter of deducting depreciation from the value of the 
property upon which a public-service corporation shall be allowed 
General rule ^° ^^^'^ ^ ^^^^ rctum, the rules and decisions of the 
for treatment commissions and of the courts vary considerably, 
in estimating Generally, the commissions and courts deduct accrued 
air va ue depredation from the estimated reproduction cost or 

from the original cost when making use of these factors in valuations 

' For diflSculties involved in the use of present unit prices, see Buffalo Gas Co. v. 
City of Buffalo, 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 553 (1913). 

2 New York, ist Dist. (sustained by New York Court of Appeals) : Kings County 
Lighting Co., People ex rel., v. Willcox, 210 N.Y. 479 (1914); New York, 2d Dist.: 
Buffalo Gas Co. v. City of Buffalo, 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 553 (1913); New Jersey: 
In re Rates of the Public Service Gas Co., i N.J. B. P. U. C. 433 (1912); Wisconsin: 
City of Milwaukee v. The Milwaukee Electric Ry. & Light Co., 10 W. R. C. R. 1, 116 
(1912); California: City of Palo Alto v. Palo Alto Gas Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 300 
(1913); City of San Jos6 v. The Pacific Tel. & Tel. Company, 3 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 
720, 727 (1913); United States District Court: Des Moines Gas Co. ». City of Des 
Moines, 199 Fed. Rep. 204 (1912). 

' 212 U.S. 19 (1909). 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 225 

for the purpose of fixing rates.' Where companies have created 
depreciation reserves invested in plant and working capital, the 
Wisconsin Commission, in a recent case, has deducted depreciation 
from cost new and added the depreciation reserves. ^ 

It has been argued that a plant that has depreciated still may 
render as efficient service as when it was new,* and that therefore 
no depreciation need be deducted. It has also been Treatment of 
contended that the necessity, in the absence of a ^dlrTarf^us 
depreciation fund, for stockholders maintaining the circumstances 
plant prevents the investment from becoming diminished.* Again, 
an effort has been made to distinguish between cases where proper 
allowance for depreciation in effect has been returned to the owners 
— in which cases, accrued depreciation should be deducted — and 
cases where sums set aside for depreciation are allowed to accumu- 
late for the benefit of a sinking fimd — in which cases no deduction 
for depreciation should be made.^ 

Perhaps the best statement of the proper treatment of depreda- 
tion in estimating value as a basis for rates is given by the New 
Hampshire Pubhc-Service Commission in the case of „ 

, , Summary of 

the Berlin Electric Light Company: ^ "We do not depredation 
hold that the full amoimt of depreciation should in '^^^ '°" 
every case be deducted from the cost of reproduction. It is merely 
one of the facts to be considered in making a finding of fair value. 
It stands in the same category as original cost of physical proper- 
ties, other necessary early expenditures, present reproduction cost 
of physical properties, and other facts concerning which inquiry is 
made, all of which should be determined as accurately as possible, 

1 United States Supreme Court: Knoxville v. Knoxville Water Co., 212 U.S. i, 29 
Sup. Ct. 148 (1909); Minnesota Rate Cases: 230 U.S. 352 (1913) ; New York Commis- 
sion for ist Dist., upheld on this point by the Appellate Division of the New York 
Supreme Court: People ex rd. King's County Lighting Co. v. Willcox, 156 New York 
App. Div. 603 (1913) ; see also 2 P. S. C. (ist Dist. N.Y.) 659; California: City of Palo 
Alto V. Palo Alto Gas Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 300 (1913). 

' City of Milwaukee v. Milwaukee Electric Ry. & Light Co., 10 W. R. C. R. i 
(1912); Superior Commercial Club ». Duluth Street Railway Co., 11 W. R. C. R. i 
(191 2). 

' Edwards et al. v. The Helena Light & Ry. Co., Sixth Annual Report, Railroad 
Commission of Montana, p. 194 (1913). 

* City of Whitewater v. Whitewater Electric Light Co., 6 W. R. C. R. 132, 138 
(1910). 

' Fuhrmanns. Cataract Power & Conduit Co., 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 656 (1913). 

• See In re Sale of Berlin Electric Light Co., 3 N.H. P. S. C. 174, 194, 195. 



226 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

but none of which have a uniform fixed value in each case. There 
may be cases where plants well conceived and well managed have 
suffered depreciation which in fact represents a part of the cost of 
developing the business to a point where a fair return can be se- 
cured. In other cases, as, for example, where adequate returns 
have been received to afford a fair return and to maintain a depred- 
ation reserve, but have been entirely paid out in dividends, the 
entire amoimt may properly be deducted from present cost of re- 
production in coming to the final conclusion as to the fair value. 
Between these two extremes the proper course will vary according 
to the circumstances in each case. But in every case it is desirable 
to determine, for the purpose of consideration, the fuU depreciation 
as accurately as possible." The whole problem of allowing for 
depredation is a problem in cost accoimting. The methods through 
which depredation may be determined are almost numberless. 

In the KnoxviUe Water case ^ and in the Minnesota Rate Cases, 
TT ■ J o . the United States Supreme Court has held that in 

United States ... , , . 

Supreme Court cstunatmg the cost of reproduction new, the extent of 
epreaa on g^gj^g depredation should be shown and deducted. 
In estimating value as a basis for rates, an allowance almost 
always is made for overhead charges. This item commonly is used 
to indude the cost of engineering and superintend- 
overhead ence, contractor's profit, interest during construction, 

charges in esti- i i i i • , ■ 

mating value as legal and general expenses, company organization, 
a basis or rates ^^^gg g^jj^j insurance, expenses of promotion, and con- 
tingendes. Although there have been cases in which the necessity 
for any separate allowance for overhead charges has been ques- 
tioned,'' the general tendency is to make a fairly liberal allowance 
for this item. Commissions and courts vary greatly not only as to 
the amoimt to be allowed, but also as to the method of computing 
allowances. Wherever the actual expenditures for overhead charges 
can be proved from the records of the company or otherwise, they 
wiU form the basis for allowance imder this head.' The company 

1 KnoxviUe v. KnoxviUe Water Co., 212 U.S. i, 29 Sup. Ct. 148 (1909). 

' Cedax Rapids Gas Light Co. v. Cedar Rapids, 144 la. 426, 120 N.W. 960 (1909), 
223 U.S. 655. See also Cumberland Tel. & Tel. Co. v. City of LouisvUle, 187 Fed. 
Rep. 637, 646, 647 (1911). 

* See Report, St. Louis PubUc-Service Commission, to the Municipal Assembly of 
St. Louis on rates for electric light and power (February 17, 1911), p. sa 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 227 

will not be permitted, however, by means of a contract with the 
construction company to impose unnecessary and unreasonable 
overhead charges. ^ Where actual expenditures for overhead 
charges carmot be ascertained, — a situation which prevails in a 
majority of cases, — commissions resort, as a rule, to a percent- 
age allowance upon the cost of items included in the general term 
"reproduction cost." The New York Commission, First District, 
has allowed in one case fifteen per cent for engineering incidentals 
and similar items on costs where these charges properly would 
apply, and ten per cent for general contractor's profit.'' The Wis- 
consin Commission in one case has allowed on the total inventory 
reproduction cost five per cent for engineering and superintendence, 
four per cent for interest during construction, and three per cent 
for legal expenses, organization, casualties, omissions, and other 
similar items; ' in another case, instead of allowing a total of twelve 
per cent for overhead charges, the Wisconsin Commission has al- 
lowed a total of fifteen per cent.* The California Cormnission has 
considered as an adequate allowance for overhead charges in the 
case of a gas company fifteen per cent on the reproduction cost of 
the plant.^ In determining the proper amount of overhead charges, 
the commissions should use, as in all other questions of valuation, 
discretion in each individual case. 

Another question to be determined in estimating value is whether 
any allowance should be made for going-concern value. Going- 
concern value in rate cases generally is considered to ^g^^^^^ f^^ 
be equivalent to the uncompensated losses incurred in development 
the development of the business. It is often called going-con- 
development expense. It should not be confused with "™ ^^^^^ 
good-will, which has no place in estimating the value of a public- 
service corporation under monopolistic conditions. The Massa- 
chusetts Board of Gas and Electric Light Commissioners has 
refused to consider going-concern value in rate cases.® As a general 

» litre Application of N.Y. & North Shore Traction Co., 3 P. S. C. (ist Dist. N.Y.) 

63 (1912). 
2 Mayhew v. Kings County Lighting Co., 2 P. S. C. (1st Dist. N.Y.) 659 (1911). 

• City of Ripon v. Ripon L. & W. Co., s W. R. C. R. i, 13 (1910). 

* City of Milwaukee v. Milwaukee Gas Light Co., 12 W. R. C. R. 441 (1913). 
» City of Palo Alto v. Palo Alto Gas Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 300 (1913). 

» See Re Haverhill Petitions, Twenty-eighth Annual Report, Gas & Electric Light 
Com'rs, pp. 41-50 (1912). 



228 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

rule, however, commissions and courts recognize the fact that 
development expense or going-concern value should be reimbursed 
to the company either by an increase in the fair value on which the 
return is allowed or by an increase in income to enable amortization 
of early losses. ^ Sometimes commissions have refused to make any 
allowance for going-concern value because of the insufficiency of 
the evidence offered,^ and sometimes on the groimd that early 
deficits have been recouped out of subsequent profits,' or on the 
fact that consciously or unconsciously the going-concern value has 
been included in the valuation of the physical plant.^ As stated 
above, however, the best practice favors a reasonable allowance for 
going-concern value.* 

The last question to be discussed in connection with detailed 
methods of valuation is that of franchise value. It is provided by 
Franchise Statute in Wisconsin: "In determining the value of 

value ^jjg property of a public-service corporation or any 

person furnishing service to the public for the purpose of this act, 
no franchise to be a corporation and no franchise or privilege 
granted to such corporation by the State or municipality shall be 
appraised, fixed, or considered at any greater sum or value than the 
sum paid therefor into the public treasury of the State or mimici- 
pality granting the same." ^ The above statute embodies the best 
and in fact the almost universal modem opinion as to the treatment 
of franchise value in rate cases. In spite of a few cases where, 
through failure to distinguish between rate cases and purchase 

1 See Kings County Lighting Co. b. Willcox, 2io N.Y. 479 (March 24, 1914); 
141 N.Y. Sup. 677. City of Palo Alto v. Palo Alto Gas Co., 2 Cal. R.R. Com. Dec. 
300 (1913). 

* See Bachrach v. Consolidated Gas, etc., Co. Public Service Com. of Maryland 
Reports, vol. iv, pp. 39-46 (1913). 

' Union City v. Union Heat, Light and Power Company, February 7, 1914, Indiana 
Public Service Commission (s Rate Research, 69). 

* Indiana Public-Service Commission (s Rate Research, 69). See Des Moines Gas 
Co. V. City of Des Moines, 199 Fed. Rep. 204 (1912). 

' See especially, for interesting discussions of this subject, and of other intangible 
elements which may enter into rate cases, Fuhrmann v. Cataract Power and Conduit 
Co., 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 656; Superior Commercial Club v. Superior Water, etc., 
Co., 10 Wis. R. C. R. 704; City of Milwaukee v. The Milwaukee Electric Railway and 
Light Co., 10 Wis. R. C. R. i; City of Green Bay v. Green Bay Water Co., 11 Wis. 
R. C. R. 236. 

* Laws igii, chap. 593, sec. 1753-15. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 229 

cases, an allowance has been made for franchise value,' it is now 
generally recognized that the value of a franchise is created, not 
by the company which owns it, but by the community served. 
Hence, it is unjust to compel the commimity to pay higher rates 
on account of a privilege conferred by the community itself.^ 

We have discussed above the various factors usually taken into 
consideration in estimating a fair value of the property upon which 
a fair rate of return shall be allowed. No hard-and- ^ 

. Summary of 

fast rules can be laid down. The very purpose of valuation as a 
havmg state public-service commissions with dis- 
cretionary powers is to make possible the determination of each 
case on its own merits — with due regard, of course, to certain 
general principles. If it were possible to make rigid rules to apply- 
in all cases, it would be possible to embody those rules in statutes 
enfordble simply by the courts. Aside from its impossibility, how- 
ever, a system of valuation based on rigid rules would defeat the 
principal purpose of regulation; that is, to give a square deal to the 
public and to the corporation. In the words of the Public Service 
Commission, Second District, New York, as expressed in the 
Buffalo Gas Case,^ February 4, 1913: "What is called the fixing of 
the value of the property in the public service for the purpose of 
rate-making is not a fixing of value in any proper sense of that 
word as it is correctly used in our language. It is a determination, 
of what, imder all the facts and circumstances of the case, is a just, 
and equitable amount upon which the return allowed to the cor-- 
poration is to be computed. If the time the determination is made 
happens to be at or near the time the plant is put in operation, the 
investment or original cost may be the predominant factor. If the- 
time of determination is remote from the time of investment, the- 
factor of appreciation or diminution in values arising from changes 
in costs of labor and materials may enter largely into the result. If 

' See, for example, Consolidated Gas Co. v. City of New York, 157 Fed. Rep. 849, 
872; Willcox V. Consolidated Gas Co., 212 U.S. 19, 48 (1909). 

2 See Fuhnnann v. Buffalo General Electric Co., 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 739 
(1913); In re Haverhill Petitions, Twenty-eighth Annual ife^ori, Massachusetts Board 
of Gas and Electric Light Com'rs. (1912), pp. 41, 50; Re Rates of the Public Service Gas 
Co., I N.J. B. P. U. C. 433 (1912); Public Service Gas Co. v. Board of Public Utility 
Commissioners, 84 N.J. 463; 87 Atl. 651 (1913); Cedar Rapids Gas Light Co. v. City of 
Cedar Rapids, 223 U.S. 655, 669 (1912). 

» Buffalo Gas Co. v. City of Buffalo, 3 P. S. C. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 553 (1913). 



230 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the plant is unreasonably disproportionate in size to the service 
required of it, the cost of reproduction new cannot be the sole test. 
If the actual investment has been reckless and extravagant, the 
owners should bear the loss and not the public. If the general scale 
of prices and values in the community has been increased or dimin- 
ished since the plant was built, the owners may be fairly called 
upon to share the general diminution; and on the other hand, may 
justly demand a share in the general appreciation to which the 
existence of their property has, it may fairly be assumed, con- 
tributed at least its proportionate share." This completes what we 
have to say on the subject of valuation as a basis for rates. 

We have discussed commission regulation of public-service 
Commission Corporations in the matters of monopoly, service, and 
^STtion rates. We will now take up briefly the poHcy of the 
and accounts commissions in the matters of capitalization and 
accounts. 

Control of capitalization is exercised through approval or dis- 

thorit of approval of the issue of securities. In Massachusetts,^ 
commissions to New York,'' Wisconsui,' California,^ and many other 
approve issue States, the commissions have authority to approve 
o secunties ^^ disapprove the issue of bonds and stocks. 

In New York State, the statutes provide, in substance, that pub- 
lic-service corporations may issue, when necessary, stock, bonds, 
notes, or other evidences of indebtedness payable at more than 
twelve months from the date of issue: — 

(i) For the acquisition of property. 

(2) For construction, completion, extension or improvement of 
their facilities. 

(3) For the improvement or maintenance of their service. 

(4) For the discharge or lawful refimding of their obligations or 

• Acts igo6, chap. 463, part 3, sees. 103, 104, 107, 108, 109, iii; Acts igo8, chap. 
636; Acts igog, chap. 485; Acts igio, chap. 536; Acts igi3, chap. 784, sees. 13 and 16; 
Acts igi3, chap. 764; Acts igi4, chap. 742, sees. 35, 38, 39, 40, 41, 42, 43, 44; Acts 1914, 
chap. 671. See Fall River Gas Works Co. v. Board of Gas and Electric Light Com'rs. 
214 Mass. 529 (1913). 

' Laws igio, chap. 480, sees. 55, 69, 101 (as amended by Laws igio, chap. 673). 
See also Laws igiz, chap. 289; Laws igi4, chap. 220. 

' Stats, igii, chap. 85, sec. 1733 as amended by Laws igis, chap. 398 and chap. 
773, see. 70. 

' Stats, igii, Extra. Sess., p. 18, as amended by Stats. igt3, chaps. 339 and 333; 
Herming's Gen. Laws of California (1914), vol. 3, p. 1338, act 3773, sec. 52. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 23 1 

for the reimbursement of moneys actually expended from income 
or from other moneys not obtained from the issue of securities. 

The order of the commission authorizing such issue shall state 
the amount of securities and the purposes to which the securities 
or the proceeds are to be applied; that the money, 
property, or labor to be procured or paid for by the ^curTtli in 
issue of such securities is or has been, in the opinion gtltelran 
of the commission, reasonably required for the pur- example of the 

' ,1 best practice 

poses specified m the order; and that such purposes 
are not, in whole or in part, reasonably chargeable to operating 
expenses or to income. The commission is forbidden to allow the 
capitalization of franchises beyond the actual amount paid there- 
for to the State or to any subdivision thereof. The commission 
cannot approve capitalization of a corporation formed by merger 
to an amoimt in excess of the combined capitalization of the com- 
panies merged,^ nor can it approve the capitalization of any con- 
tract for consolidation or lease. For the issue of notes and similar 
obligations, payable in less than one year, the consent of the 
commission is unnecessary.^ These provisions are typical of the 
best practice in the States where the comnaissions have authority 
over the issue of securities. 

Many people have held that if service and rates are regulated, 
there is no necessity for regulating the issue of securities. This rea- 
soning does not take into account the interests of 
investors. In the words of Dr. Maltbie, of the New commission 
York PubUc-Service Commission, First District: the issue of 
"The State owes a duty towards investors as well as ^^"^"""^ 
it does towards shippers and passengers. Further, proper regula- 
tion of securities will ultimately affect rates and service. It may 
not immediately, but in the long run better service and lower rates 
will be given by corporations that are upon a sound financial basis 
than by those having a great overcapitalization and unsound financ- 
ing." ' Undoubtedly it is true that overcapitalization has a tend- 

' See, however, Rockland Light and Power Case, dted on page 214, note 3. 

' As an illustration of the practical working of these provisions see: In the Matter 
of the Application of the New York and Ontario Power Co., i P. S. C. R. (2d Dist. N.Y.) 
453 (1909); People ex rd. Binghamton L. H. & P. Co. v. Stevens, 203 N.Y. 7 (191 1). 

' Quoted by J. M. Eshleman in " Should the Public Utilities Commission have Power 
to Control the Issuance of Securities," State Regulation ofPubUc Utilities, p. 160. 



232 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

ency to lead either to poorer service or to higher rates. Even where 
the commissions have full authority over service and rates, it is 
much more difficult for them to make this control effective, if they 
are dealing with a corporation attempting to earn an attractive 
return on an excessive amount of securities. The strongest argu- 
ment, however, for the control of the issue of securities by commis- 
sions is the protection of investors.* 

The only other important phase of regulation of public-service 
corporations by state commissions is the supervision of accounts 
Supervision and the ordering of reports. There are provisions for 
and ordering ^hc regulation of accounts in upwards of one half the 
of reports States. Usually the commission has authority to 

establish a system of uniform accounts. In Indiana, the commis- 
sion must prescribe accounting practices.^ In many States provi- 
sion is made for special depredation accounts. In practically all the 
States the public-service corporations must make regular periodic 
reports to the commissions. 

It is to be remembered that all orders of the commissions in the 
various States are subject to a greater or less degree of review by 
- ,. . , . the courts. In Colorado ' and in CaUfomia,* by stat- 
of commission ute, the findings and conclusions of the commissions 
on questions of fact are made final and are not subject 
to judicial review. In several other States the limits within which 
judicial decisions may operate are laid down by statute. In Rhode 
Island,^ Connecticut,* California,' and several other States, orders 
of the commission may be suspended pending review by the court. 
"The right of appeal and judicial review is statutory and therefore 
subject to the will of the legislature within the constitutional limita- 
tions of due process and equal protection of the law with respect 

1 Aside from the direct power of commissions to approve or disapprove the issue of 
new securities, there is a form of control which consists simply in making public the 
facts about the issue of new securities and the purposes for which they are issued. 
This is the method in the main recommended by the Railroad Securities Commission 
appointed by President Taft in 1910. 

' Acts igi3, chap. 76, sees. 15-17. 

' Colorado, Session Laws, 19x3, chap. 127, sec. 52. 

* Stats, igii, ist Extra. Session, chap. 14, sec. 67; Henning's General Laws of Cali- 
fornia (1914), act 377S, sec. 67, p. 1566. 1 

' Laws igiz, chap. 795, sec. 33. ° Puhlic Acts igii, chap. 128, sec. 33. 

' Laws igii, Extra. Session, chap. 14, sec. 68; Henning's General Laws of California 
(1914), act 377S, sec. 68, p. 1566. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 233 

to the preservation of property and contract rights." ^ This finishes 
what we have to say on the regulation of public-service corpora- 
tions by state commissions. 

There has been recently a considerable movement in some places 
in favor of regulation by the local communities instead of by the 
State. ^ There have been advanced three arguments: state c^. local 
(i) That the local community is better able to judge f«g"'a.tion 
of its own needs than is the State; (2) that local self -sufficiency or 
home-rule should not be weakened; (3) that local, instead of state, 
control will make easier purchase and operation of a public-service 
corporation by the mimicipahty. In Los Angeles, California, under 
the combined authority of the City Council and the local Board of 
Public Utilities, there has been worked out a reasonably satisfac- 
tory system of local regulation.' In view of the fact that so many 
public-service corporations operate in more than one municipahty, 
local regulation, it seems to us, is likely to lead to the same conflict 
between difierent municipahties and between municipalities and 
the State as prevails in the case of steam railroads between the dif- 
ferent States and between States and the Federal Government. 
Local regulation, moreover, is liable to be too provincial. Exclusive 
and more or less uniform regulation * of local public utilities by the 
State seems to us, on the whole, the best solution. 

' Oscar L. Pond, Methods of Judicial Review in Relation to Effectiveness of Commis- 
sion Control in State Regulation of Public Utilities (Philadelphia, 1914), p. 64. 

2 See Report of D. F. Wilcox, Chainnan of Committee on Franchises of the National 
Mimidpal League, November 13, 1913, and Report of Conference of American Mayors, 
held in Philadelphia, November 13 and 14, 1914 {Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 
vol. 99, p. 1510). 

' See State Regulation of Public Utilities, pp. 108-18. 

* There has been drawn up recently and submitted to a great many different inter- 
ests a so-called "Uniform Utilities Bill." The main provisions of this bill are as fol- 
lows: (i) State commissions to have power to prevent needless competition through 
control of the issue of certificates of public convenience and necessity; (2) state com- 
missions shall control consolidation; (3) all franchises granted to public utilities which 
do not provide for possible purchase by the municipality shall be indeterminate; (4) 
municipalities shall have the right to purchase public utilities, in case of disagree- 
ment as to price, at a value to be determined by the state commissions; (5) state 
cominissions shall enforce adequate service and shall have power to investigate ser- 
vice on their own motion; (6) state commissions shall have full power, subject to 
law, to prescribe rates; (7) they shall have supervision of the issue of new securities; 
(8) they shall prescribe uniform sj'stems of accounts. (Draft Bill for the regulation 
of public utilities with dociunents relating thereto, authorized to be published by the 
National Civic Federation, October 23, 1914). 



234 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Related to the question of regulation of local public-service 
corporations is the question of municipal ownership and operation. 
Municipal Many of the franchises granted in recent years by 

ownership munidpaUties to public-service corporations in the 

United States, as shown earlier in this chapter, provide for purchase 
of the property of the public utiKty by the municipality. In Massa- 
chusetts, 1 Illinois,* Wisconsin,' and other States, definite provision 
is made in the statutes for the purchase of public-service corpora- 
tions for mimidpal ownership and operation. 

In Massachusetts there were on June 30, 1913, thirty-six munici- 
pally owned and operated lighting plants.* Of these thirty-six 
plants, however, seventeen were distributing plants 
operation in Only and bought their product. The results of muni- 

assac use s ^^pg^^ operation in Massachusetts have varied consid- 
erably. In many cases the community has obtained its street light- 
ing at lower figures than otherwise obtainable, and has received a 
good quality of commercial service at reasonable rates. In all the 
municipal plants in Massachusetts the maintenance of a depreda- 
tion fund, usually three per cent, is compulsory. Any deficit in- 
curred in the operation of the plants is made up from taxes. Owing 
to the almost limitless number of factors which enter into the ques- 
tion of the success or failure of mimicipal operation, it is almost im- 
possible to say what the true results have been. There is nothing 
to show, however, that in most cases munidpal operation has not 
worked out reasonably well. 

There has been a considerable spread of mimidpal ownership and 
operation of lighting plants outside of Massachusetts. In 1912, 
„ . . , the total number of munidpal central electric stations 

Muiuapal . . 

ownersiiip and m the Umted States was 1562 as against 3659 stations 
whareirTthe* privately owned and operated.^ When we try to 
United states arrive at the comparative results of mxmicipal and 
private operation throughout the United States, we find the same 

' Acts igi4, chap. 742, sees. 92 to 125. 

* Senate Bill no. 538, approved June 26, 1913; Laws igzj, p. 455. 

' Laws igoj, chap. 499, sees. 1797M-74 to 1797M-86, as amended by Laws igog, 
chap. 213, and by Laws igii, chaps. 12 and 596, and by Laws igij, chap. 160. 

* See Twenty-ninth Annual Report, Board of Gas and Electric Light Commission- 
ers, pp. 209-12. 

" Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, Bulletin 124 (Washington, 
1914), p. 14. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 235 

difficulties as in Massachusetts. The differences in the compara- 
tive size of the municipal and private stations, in the character of 
the community served, in the proportions of lighting and of power 
business, in the amoimts charged to depreciation and in the meth- 
ods of keeping accounts, make a comparison of financial results at 
present of very Kttle significance. If we attempt to compare serv- 
ice, we will find ahnost always a difference of opinion. The munici- 
pal electric lighting plant in Detroit is referred to usually as a 
success. It has been in operation since 1895, and, except the plant 
in Chicago, is the largest municipal lighting plant in the United 
States. Detroit has secured its lighting on terms which compare 
favorably with the prices charged by private companies in other 
cities. The plant is managed by a Public Lighting Commission in 
much the same way as a board of directors would conduct the affairs 
of a well-managed private corporation.* The municipal electric 
light plants in South Norwalk, Coimecticut, Allegheny, Pennsyl- 
vania, and Chicago, Illinois, all have been cited as confirming the 
wisdom of municipal ownership and operation.'' Municipal opera- 
tion of gas works in Philadelphia, on the other hand, proved a fail- 
ure and was abandoned.' The results of an investigation of the 
commission on public ownership and operation of the National 
Civic Federation, published in 1907, show that it is possible to ob- 
tain two opinions almost diametrically opposite on the questions 
of service, rates, and general success or failuxe of municipal as 
against private plants. 

In Great Britain and Germany, there has been a much greater 
development of municipal ownership and operation than in the 
United States. In both countries the properties usu- Municipal 
ally have been operated without loss (after making o^l?i^n in°"^ 
due allowances) and in some cases with considerable Europe 
profit. Where changes have been made during the past few years 
from private to municipal operation, they have resulted, in most 
cases, in better service. The service given, however, is very much 
less developed than that furnished under private management in 

> John Fairlie, Essays in Municipal Administration, New York, 1908, pp. 219-29. 

2 E. W. Bemis, "Municipal and Private Operation of Public Utilities," Report to 
the National Civic Federation, Commission on Public Ownership and Operation 
(New York 1907), vol. i, part i, pp. 165, 169, 175. 

• Ibid., p. 149, and Fairlie, p. 271. 



236 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the United States.' Municipal operation of street railways in 
Great Britain, particularly in Glasgow, Scotland, and in Liverpool 
and Leeds, England, has proved on the whole satisfactory. It has 
resulted in extension of service and usually in a reduction of fares. 
It has also resulted favorably from a financial point of view.^ It is 
to be remembered that municipal operation of tramways in Great 
Britain has been developed for the most part under fairly good 
pohtical conditions. Among the well-known municipal gas plants 
in Great Britain may be mentioned those in Birmingham, Man- 
chester, Leicester, and Glasgow. London has several municipal 
electric plants which appear to have shown a fair degree of suc- 
cess.* Outside of Great Britain, we find in Vienna the largest mu- 
nicipal street railway system ia the world and also mimicipal gas 
works; in Bologna, Leghorn, Padua, and Pisa, Italy, we find munic- 
ipal gas plants.* On the whole, the service furnished by these 
municipal utilities in Vieima and in Italy has been at least fair, 
although less developed than the service furnished under private 
operation in the United States. The rates charged have not been 
particularly low for the service furnished. The financial results 
appear to be fairly satisfactory.^ To sum up, perhaps it is fair to 
say that municipal operation of public utilities in Europe has given 
reasonably satisfactory results. The political conditions have been 
more favorable than in the United States. 

Purchase and operation of public utilities by municipalities in 
Munidpai the United States involve fewer difiSculties than 
ownership of pubKc Ownership and operation of the steam railroads. 

public utilities '^ ^ _ J^ 

more feasible Under our present fairly satisfactory system of state 

but less neccs* 

sary than regulation of local utilities, however, municipal own- 

omiereSp"of ership * of these properties seems even less necessary 
railroads ^g^j^ government ownership of railroads, 

• FairUe,p. 272. 

2 "Munidpai and Private Operation of Public Utilities," Report to National Civic 
Federation, Commission on Public Ownership and Operation (New York, 1907), voL i, 
part I, pp. 263 to 297. See also lUd., vol. n, part 2, " British Tramways." 

' Fairlie, p. 301. 

' Ibid., pp. 325-28 and 341-49. ° Ibid., pp. 325-28 and 34S-49. 

° For several interesting articles on municipal ownership and on the relation of the 
public to public-service corporations, see "Public Policies as to Municipal Utilities," 
in the Annais ol the American Academy of Political and Social Science, vol. Lvn, 
no. 146 (January, 1915). 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 237 

We have confined our discussion of public-service corporations 
so far mostly to street railway, gas, and electric light and power 
companies operating in local communities. There is Relation of 
another large class of public-service corporations — compamesTo 
the telephone companies. These companies do usually *^ ^^^^'^ 
an interstate business. The question of the relation of these cor- 
porations to the public is a perplexing one. The telephone business 
is in its very nature of a peculiarly monopolistic character. We 
ourselves feel that the final solution will be either ownership and 
operation by the Federal Government or operation of the proper- 
ties as a unit under a federal license or charter — with the same 
sort of regulation as to service, rates, and capitalization as is pro- 
vided in the authority of state commissions over public-service 
corporations located wholly within one State. 

A recent report of the Postmaster-General of the j, ^ ^f j^g 
United States ^ made the following suggestions: — Postmaster- 

(i) That Congress declare a government monopoly telegraph and 
over all telegraph and telephone lines and over 
certain other means of communication. 

(2) That Congress acquire by purchase at appraised value the com- 
mercial telephone network, except the farmer lines. 

(3) That Congress authorize the Postmaster-General to issue, in his 
discretion and under such regulations as he may prescribe, revoc- 
able licenses for the operation by private individuals, associations, 
companies, and corporations of the telegraph service and such 
parts of the telephone service as may not be acquired by the 
Government. 

The report states that the United States is the only one of the 
leading nations which has left to private enterprise the ownership 
and operation of telegraph and telephone facihties. 

It is undeniable that the telephone business comes as near to 
what may be called a legitimate government mo- 
nopoly as any public-service business still in the exdiSve re^- 
hands of private owners. Furthermore, there would Fed°era^Govem- 
be certain economies in the operation of telephone mf°t of ,. 

^ . ^ telephone hnes 

lines in connection with the postal service — such as 

the use of the present real estate of the postal service and the use 

' Government Ownership of Electrical Means of Communication, 63d Cong., 2d Sess., 
Document no. 339, p. 13. 



238 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

of stamps for the collection of charges. If these properties are not 
taken over and operated by the Federal Government, or taken over 
by the Govermnent and operated by private corporations under 
licenses, there should be established, it seems to us, exclusive 
federal regulation of the private corporations. 

Another class of properties where the question of possible federal 
control enters in are the water-power developments on navigable 
Water-power Streams. Undoubtedly the Federal CJovemment has 
developments ^jjg right to exercise over these properties any degree 
of control that it sees fit. On the other hand, the States where any 
particular water-power developments may be situated are Ukely 
to feel that regulation belongs to them. There were introduced in 
the Sixty-third Congress various bills dealing with this subject. A 
suggestion which has in it many reasonable features for a settle- 
ment of this question is as follows: — 

(i) Public ownership, federal or state, of the site and of the 
water-power. 

(2) Lease to a private corporation for operation. 

(3) Control over competition, service, and rates by some com- 
mission. 

It seems to us that federal ownership of the site and water-power, 
lease to a private corporation for operation and control over com- 
petition, service, and rates by some federal commission, would be a 
reasonable solution in the cases of corporations doing an interstate 
business, and a similar programme with the State substituted for 
the National Government in the cases of corporations doing a busi- 
ness wholly within one State. The same danger of conflict of 
authority, however, together with the fact that the Federal Gov- 
ernment has ultimate control over navigable streams, may make it 
desirable to have the whole matter considered a concern of the 
Federal Government. It is to be hoped that the settlement of this 
problem will not be such as to discourage the development of 
water-power. 

In the entire matter of the relation of public-service corporations 
„ , , ^. to the public, there is likely to be from time to time 

Broad relation '^ ' •' 

of pubUc-ser- more or less of a see-saw between abuse of opportu- 
tionsTo'Se^ nities by private interests and over-severity or nar- 
peopie rowness on the part of the public or its representa- 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 239 

tives. Regulation by commissions may swing like a pendulum 
from a policy of undue interference and repression to a policy of 
undue subservience to corporation influence. It is well to remem- 
ber, as Mr. Vail, president of the American Telephone and Tele- 
graph Company, has said in substance, that the prosperity and 
even the existence of the public-service corporation is dependent 
in the last resort on the good-will and acquiescence of the public' 
Only on the basis of giving good service at reasonable rates, obey- 
ing the laws and recognizing public opinion can private ownership 
of pubKc-service corporations endure. 

In an attempt to make clear certain principles governing the 
safety of public-service corporation bonds, we have Debt and eam- 
discussed earlier in this chapter the relation of debt to 1°^;°!^"'''^'" 
property or assets. We wish now to say a few words corporations 
about earnings. 

In the matter of gross earnings, public-service corporations have 
shown a marked degree of growth and stability over a long series of 
years: for instance, whereas the gross earnings of g^^..^ 
steam railroads, operating 199,726 miles of road, for gross earnings 
the year ending December 31, 1908, — the first fuU semce "^ 
year after the panic of 1907, — showed a loss of 11.90 corporations 
per cent compared with the previous year,^ the gross earnings of 
forty representative public-service corporations for the same period 
showed an increase of about 7.15 per cent.' Again, railroads oper- 
ating 249,726 miles of road showed for the calendar year 1914 a 
loss in gross earnings of 6.79 per cent compared with 1913,* 
whereas forty representative public-service corporations showed 
for the same period an increase of about 4.13 per cent.^ The experi- 
ence of most public-service corporations has been that of a more or 
less steady increase in gross earnings through good times and bad.* 

1 See Address of Theodore N. Vail, President, at the opening of the Annual Con- 
ference of the Bell Telephone System, New York, October, igi3. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, "The Financial Review" (Annual, 1915), 
p. 106. 

' Figures from Messrs. N. W. Harris & Co., Inc. 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, "The Financial Review" (Annual, 1915), 
p. 106. 

' Figures from Messrs. N. W. Harris & Co., Inc., in letter dated March 30, 1915. 

" During the current year (1915), the "jitneys" have cut into the earnings of street 
railways somewhat seriously. Our opinion is that the "jitneys" ultimately will serve 



240 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

In the matter of net earnings, we give below some figures for net 

earnings per one hundred dollars of outstanding securities of gas 

and electric companies in most of the large cities 

of the United States as compared with figures for 

railroads and industrial concerns: — 

Net earnings per one hundred dollars of outstanding securities 
igo2-ii, inclusive 

Gas and electric companies $8.45 

Industrials 7.79 

Railroads 4.25 

As illustrating the freedom from dangerous fluctuations in 

net earnings, the following figures giving the average annual 

amoimt of securities in receivers' hands per one 

Net eanungs , , , , „ , ,. . . f . 

and receiver- hundred dollars of outstanding securities dunng a 
^^ period of thirty years, from 1882 to 191 1 inclusive, 

may be of interest: — 

Gas and electric companies $ .37 

Railroads 1.84 

Industrials 2.07 

The above figures show a far better record as to receiverships for 
gas and electric companies than for railroads and industrials.^ 

We wiU refer briefly to the question of receiverships and reor- 
ganizations of public-service corporations. The same problems of 
readjusting capitalization and exchanging old securi- 
and reorgani- ties f or ncw as wc f oimd in the cases of steam railroads 

°^ have arisen in the cases of public-service corporations. 

Interesting reorganizations are those of the Michigan Telephone 
Company (1904), controlling the Bell Telephone business in the 
State of Michigan; the Chicago Union Traction Company (1907), 
controUing a large part of the street-railway business in Chicago; 
the Hudson River Electric Power Company (191 1), controlling 
hydro-electric plants in New York State; and the Metropolitan 
Street-Railway Company (1911), controlling most of the surface 
street-railway lines in New York City. 

principally as useful feedeis rather than as dangerous competitois of the street rail- 
ways. 

' Information obtained from pamphlets published by Messrs. Henry L. Doherty & 
Co., dated February 20, 1913, and April 21, 1913. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 24I 

The properties of the Michigan Telephone Company were sold 
at foreclosure to interests representing the bondholders November 
4, 1903. There had been default in interest due July i, Reorganization 
1902, on $4,715,000 mortgage bonds. As is usual in gl^Tekphone 
such cases, many reasons may be brought forward to Company 
account for the default. In a general way, it may be said that the 
community served had grown too fast for the company. Rapid 
extensions were required, the rates were too low to pay a fair return 
on the new capital, and the physical condition of the properties 
deteriorated. On the whole, the management was not able to cope 
with the situation. There was, moreover, considerable competition 
from independents — especially in Grand Rapids. The attitude 
of the public was unfriendly. There was a considerable floating 
debt held largely by the same interests that controlled the stock. 
The physical properties of the company had been appraised at an 
amount considerably in excess of the bonded debt. The price 
obtained at foreclosure sale ^ was $4,100,000 — compared with a 
bonded debt of $5,000,000. The company was reorganized accord- 
ing to plan shown in the table on page 242. 

This reorganization may be said to have been entirely in the 
interests of the old bondholders. In December, 1909, the market 
value of the securities received in exchange for each $1000 of old 
Michigan Telephone 5 per cents was, at the bid prices, exactly 
$1300.^ Later, about ninety per cent of the common stock of 
the Michigan State Telephone Company was exchanged for 
stock of the American Telephone and Telegraph Company on 
the basis of five shares of the former for four shares of the 
latter. 

The properties controlled by the Chicago Union Traction Com- 
pany — operating mostly on the north and west sides of the City 
of Chicago — were sold at foreclosure to a protective Reorganization 
committee January 25, 1908. Many of the old fran- union xSon 
chises had expired, and the so-called "Ninety-nine- Company 
Year Act" — which the companies had considered gave them the 
right to operate all their lines in the city of Chicago — had been 

' Commerkal and Financial Chronicle, vol. 77, p. 1750. 

2 Bank and Quotation Section of tiie Commercial and Fitumcidl Chronicle, Decem- 
ber 4, igog, pp. 31 and 48. 



242 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



o 
u 

w 

o 

P-I 



i 

CO 



s 



8 



•8 






rS o 

s§ 



«^f 



•fe. 



^1 



a 
I 



a 



SB.8 






1 i 

ail: 






a 



Co 



^ 



bo t^ 



^ 



f 



B 



•a 



•2 

3 



^^„ 



5 8 8 
tsc3 



■% 



3 
O 

•a 



^ 



§ 






so 



o o a 

33 1 

DO S 

a-8 :§ 



SB i 



if 



§1- •^' 



a 






a * I 

^« J 

II I 



II 
as 



al 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 243 

held by the Umted States Supreme Court ^ to be not a franchise. 
There began a long fight, led by ex-Mayor Dunne, for municipal 
ownership and operation. During this fight the physical condition 
of the properties deteriorated badly. The holding company — the 
Union Traction Company — was grossly overcapitalized and was 
justly unpopular. Receivers were appointed for the North Chicago 
Street-Railroad Company and the West Chicago Street-Railroad 
Company, the two leading operating companies, in April, 1903.* 
At foreclosure sale,' the price obtained for the combined properties 
was $2,090,000, compared with a total debt of $33,490,126. The 
companies were reorganized in accordance with plan shown on 
page 244. 

This reorganization was in the interests, partly of the old secur- 
ity-holders, but more in the interests of the public. Perhaps its 
primary object was to make possible the giving by the successor of 
the old companies of adequate street-railway service to the city of 
Chicago. The old security-holders have not under all the circum- 
stances fared particularly well up to date. 

The properties of the Hudson River Electric Power Company 
and its seven controlled companies were sold at foreclosure sale 
August 29, 1 911. The troubles of the old companies, Reorganization 
besides the complicated nature of their relations to one ^^^^ He't^°° 
another, were due mainly to unexpected engineering Power Com- 
problems which resulted in greatly increased costs controlled 
and finally in overcapitalization. There were in addi- ™ -companies 
tion these difficulties: inadequate control of the water flow and 
inadequate steam reserve, low-priced contracts, poor earnings, and 
lack of strong financial backing. Receivers were appointed in 
November, 1908.^ The price obtained at foreclosure ^ — including 
the property of the Madison County Gas and Electric Company, 
sold August 31, 191 1 — was $7,675,000, compared with a total 
debt of the old companies of $11,965,667. The properties were 
reorganized in accordance with plan given on page 245. 

1 Act approved February 6, 1865 (amending an act approved February 14, 1859, 
and an act approved February 21, 1861), entitled "An Act concerning horse railways 
in the City of Chicago." See Blair v. City of Chicago, etc., 201 U.S. 400; 26 Sup. Ct. 427. 

* Poor's Manual of Railroads (1907), p. 1085. 

" Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 86, p. 284. 

* The Corporation Service (1910), p. 1735. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 93, p. 592. 



244 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



a 



•s. 



fc :^ 



I" 

I. 



Ph 

8 

CO 

3 I ^ 






I 

■ft. 



I 






12 



.•ge, 
§1 



II 
I" 



^■3 1 

lis 

||.S 

1^=0 .S 



!S6?2"SgS''i^"'»« 



^i 

U 



c3 +J'T 



-•3 u^S 

■s.s . 

o 3 2"^ 



.sag 



1:2 V 



BS"';© 



- - S^S u 0,2 

w m n eO "r tf) 






,o 3 O 



.2.5-5 

§-■§ a 






1 811111^1 nil rgsiTii 



"O H rt tJ jj'S""-" w 2 ^ (J <" 



OS a .3 
"IgQwi'S" 






.■a' 



I 



ail 
III 



to 



8 
f 

I 

§ 



88 8 

OO O 00 ' 



8 8 

O »0 



8§ i i| §1 I I ^ I 



^^^ 



>tjn 






IS^ 



s^ 



%mM^J 



^-5.0 S5« 






0"° 



1% 






•o a 
o 3 



- o 

10 s 



O rt 



!fiif.i 

•fl a 8 le^ 



S ojfeSS r^.9 SfeSS w.a-gp^io'^- 
■" yiHit.,-!:; bp_ •« S'^ ,-K M 9 _Q M ^ h 
.ij ce o" 









& 



a T 

a <3 

O M 

S d 

•I "^ 



3 

I 

I 

a 
3 



ll 


K? 


:^s 


s& 


^ S 


** a 


^.1 


gd 


8:1 








ro3 




■3^ 


gp^ 








3? 




Is 

n 


S-f 




r1? 


S — 








15 










•^s 


i-a 


(3 


['ig 


^fl 


■sl 








M^ 


p 


.^s 




ilS 


Uta 


*■ e 


n n 






•So 








ii.- 












a> 1 








H-^ 




Oi 





PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 



I 

04 



bSlSlS gig's 



«^4 



l'§'5| a 1 8 g is 



P4 

8 -. 

S !^ 

P -5 ^ 

1* * 
H ^ I 

I 






fti 






a^ 



a 



a 
< 



•1 



i 



8 8 



I ° 



.1 









S3 

•4-1 

a 

1 



C3 



S S 



88 



1 I I 



111 



I wy '2 

tn 

o of' 
SIPS 

> M > 

513 

9 •" 9 

O jn o 



11 

8"';>^i to 

& O ■* v_,'^ 

T3 o"" »» 



i 8 






IfSg-gg-f 






s-S 



n 



1=3^1 p-w 1=" a:: aSrt 
eg S m ;€ S 



s >: H 

a«a 

en O ci 



S-2 



24S 



.?,-« 


^ 


11 


i 


t^. 


X 


3^ 


1 


a ^ 








§§ 


to 


8! 


S 




«« 1 


§x 


■^ 


9 b 


« 



n 



1| 

Is .8| 
Si "^Id 

III 



•11 



■it 
It 



\%£ 



» 



■q-5 






•si" 
lg^ 



246 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

This reorganization, like that of the Michigan Telephone Com- 
pany, was entirely in the interests of the old bondholders. There 
was made, however, a sharp distinction between the old bonds of 
the Hudson River Electric Company, the Hudson River Electric 
Power Company, and the Madison County Gas and Electric Com- 
pany, as compared with the old bonds of the other five companies. 

The lines of the Metropolitan Street-Railway Company — con- 
troUing most of the surface street-railway traffic in New York City 
— were sold under foreclosure December 29, 1911. As is usual in 
such cases, the causes of the trouble were many and various. There 
was great congestion of traffic; and owing to the building of the 
Reorganization subways, the traffic had to be moved under changed 
ten s'treeS-'^' conditions. Through the Kberal giving of transfers, 
way Company ^-j^g average fare had been reduced beyond the point 
of profit. Added to these causes were heavy cost of repair work 
and increased expenses in other directions. There had been also 
gross over- capitalization, waste of assets, and mismanagement. 
The physical condition of many of the lines became deplorable. 
Receivers were appointed " about" September 27, 1907.* At fore- 
closure sale ^ the price obtained for the property represented by 
the old 5% bonds was $10,000,000, and for that covered by the 
refunding 4% bonds, $2,010,000, or a total of $12,010,000. This 
compared with a total debt held by the pubHc before reorganiza- 
tion of $53,585,000. The properties were reorganized in accord- 
ance with the plan shown on page 247. 

This reorganization was a good deal like many steam-railroad re- 
organizations. There was an effort to recognize all interests — in- 
cluding those of the old stockholders. As in most steam-railroad 
reorganizations, the stockholders were assessed to furnish new 
capital. 

It is to be noted that in the two street-railway reorganizations 
treated above, the total debt after reorganization was 

Summary of .,•■, ,1/. .. t 

four reorgani- Considerably greater than before reorganization. In 
the case of the New York Railways Company, how- 
ever, a large part of the new debt was represented by bonds the 

' Plan and Agreement for the Reorganization of the Metropolitan Streel-EaUviay 
Company, p. 2. 
* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 93, p. 1787. 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 



•5 



I 

I 



8 ^ 






82 «-2i -cs i^ « = 



O; 



^^^^i 



3 8«is*^S!^ 














§ 



ri 



1 
Oh 










§ 



P 

II 







0} lU 






S'8^'3 

6P Q. - 



o^ 



S2. 



So« 



i. 



gag"" 



"If SI 

:0.a ffO aj S~-»/ 



^ K g " d d I, — U 2 

843SrtOOoQ.OO 



247 



ll 



III 

8 8 °: 
= 5 s 



SS a 



o -<-> 
4-1 en 

^ g 



It 






II 



II 
II 



III 

^•3 - 






248 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

interest pajTnents on which were conditional, and in the case of 
the Chicago Railways Company, by bonds bearing at first reduced 
rates of interest. Both reorganizations sought to reduce largely 
stock capitalization. In the other two reorganizations discussed, 
— that of the Michigan Telephone Company and that of the 
Hudson River Electric Power Company and its controlled com- 
panies, — the debt was reduced after reorganization. In the four 
reorganizations the principal methods of raising new capital were: 
Michigan State Telephone Company, sale of new securities to old 
bondholders and to bankers; Chicago Railways Company, sale of 
new first-mortgage bonds to bankers; Adirondack Electric Power 
Corporation, sale of new first-mortgage bonds to bankers; New 
York Railways Company, assessment of certain old noteholders 
and of old stockholders. 

In summarizing the situation of public-service corporations we 
Summary of would Say: (i) that pubHc-service corporations to-day 
publc-°er^ce ^^^ recognized generally as regulated monopolies; and 
corporations (3) that the Stability of the business and earnings of 
such corporations are very great. 

In trying to determine the safety of any given issue of public- 
service corporation bonds, many of the same considerations prevail 
, , as in the case of steam-railroad bonds. A first-mort- 

Examples of 

strong pubUc- gage bond of a street-railway, gas, electric light and 

service corpo- ^ 1 1 i . i 

ration bond powcr, or telephone company, havmg a large margin 
issues p£ pj-Qpgjjy above its debt and located in an important 

community, is, other things being equal, well secured. Examples 
of exceedingly strong public-service corporation bond issues are: 
New York Telephone 4^% 1939, Cleveland Railway 5% 1931, 
Detroit Edison 5% 1933, and Laclede Gas Light (St. Louis), first 
5% 1919. The New York Telephone 4^% bonds are part of a 
closed mortgage for $75,000,000 ($3,340,750 of which have been 
retired by sinking fund) , and are secured by a first lien, subject only 
to $3 ,483 ,000 underlying or assumed bonds, on aU the property of the 
company now owned or hereafter acquired. The assets of the com- 
pany have been appraised at from somewhat over $200,000,000 to 
over $250,000,000. The company operates the Bell telephone sys- 
tem throughout the State of New York and also in important 
territory in New Jersey. It also controls valuable lines in Pennsyl- 



PUBLIC-SERVICE CORPORATION BONDS 249 

vania.^ The Cleveland Railway 5% bonds are part of an outstand- 
ing issue of $5,495,000, are secured by a first mortgage on all the 
lines, and are followed by $25,784,900 capital stock representing 
property.'' The company operates, under excellent franchise ar- 
rangements, the entire street-railway system in Cleveland, Ohio.' 
The Detroit Edison first 5% bonds are part of a closed mortgage 
for $10,000,000, and are secured by a first lien, direct or indirect, on 
all the property and franchises of the company in the city of Detroit. 
The replacement value of the company's property is estimated 
as somewhere near $31,000,000.* The company does all the com- 
mercial electric-lighting and industrial-power business in Detroit, 
Michigan.^ The Laclede Gas Light first 5% 1919 bonds are part of a 
closed first mortgage for $10,000,000, and are followed by $12,500,- 
000 junior bonds, by $2,500,000 preferred stock, and by $10,700,000 
common stock pa3dng dividends of 7% per annum. The company 
has an imusually strong franchise, and does all the gas business in 
St. Louis, Missouri.^ It is to be remembered that no issue of public- 
service corporation bonds, or of any other kind of bonds, is perfect 
in all respects. Each issue must be judged after taking into con- 
sideration all the factors entering into its safety. 

In the early days of public-service corporation bond issues, con- 
servative bankers, in their desire to make an issue as strong as 
possible, often drew up a financial scheme which was Financial plan 
too narrow and too rigid. For instance, many of the broad^ flexible 
corporation bond issues were limited in total amount ^°<^ ^"^ 
authorized to a figure which later proved to be entirely inadequate 

* See Poor's Manual of Public Utilities (1915), pp. 781, 785, and 2265, and Railway 
and Industrial Section of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, June 26, igiSf 

P- IS9- 

2 In the valuation of the property by Judge Taylor, as a basis for the franchise 
granted in 1909, $3,615,844 was allowed for franchise value. (See Electric Railway 
Section of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 22, 1915, p. 31.) 

' Poor's Manual of Public Utilities (1915), pp. 862-64, and Electric Railway Section 
of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 22, 1915, p. 31. 

* Information from dealers. The company is having made, for the Michigan Rail- 
road Commission, an appraisal of its property. 

' Poor's Manual, pp. 1894-97 and 2252, and Railway and Industrial Section of 
the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, June 26, 1915, pp. 147-48, and dealers' 
circulars. 

' Poor's Manual of Public Utilities (1915), pp. 1099-1100, and Railway and Indus- 
trial Section of the Commercial and Financial Chronicle, June 26, 1915, p. 154. 



250 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

for the needs of the corporation. Modem practice favors an author- 
ized issue large enough to take care of all the legitimate future needs 
of the company, but limits the actual issue of bonds in such a way 
as to keep the debt reasonable compared with the value of the prop- 
erty and otherwise make secure the loan. This enables the corpora- 
tion to finance on a satisfactory basis reasonable extensions of its 
plant and service, and at the same time it protects investors.^ In 
general, it may be said that the financial plan of a public-service 
corporation should be at one and the same time broad, flexible, 
and firm. 

One thing more remains to be said. The prices of public-service 
corporation bonds during the past ten or fifteen years, like the 
Prices o{ ublic- P'^^^^ °^ ^^ Other bonds, have shown a considerable 
service corpo- decline. This decline has been much less in the 

ration bonds r tv • ^' i. j i_ 

case of pubhc-service corporation bonds, however, 
than it has been in the cases of state, municipal, and railroad 
bonds. Even since the war, some of the very strongest public- 
service corporation bond issues, like New York Telephone 4^ per 
cents, Cleveland Railway 5 per cents, and Detroit Edison 5 per 
cents, are selling near the highest prices at which they have ever 
sold.^ This is a recognition on the part of investors of the vari- 
ous features of strength and stability which we have tried to point 
out in this chapter. 

As a final word, we would say that the issue of 

Final test is ii. • a" u j -l j j. 

willingness of pubuc-service corporation bonds based on a property 
to tfke aT ^^^ busmess which the bondholders would be glad to 
th°^b '*d ^°' take, if necessary, for the bonds is the issue which 
investors should be willing to buy. 

' For further elaboration of this idea, see Stone & Webster, Public Service Journal, 
August, 1914, pp. 99-106. 

2 Some of the less well-secured bonds, on the other hand, and bonds on some of the 
smaller properties have shovm since the beginning of the war a considerable decline. 



CHAPTER Vn 

INDUSTEIAL BONDS 

Industrial bonds, as the term will be used in this chapter; 
comprise bonds of manufacturing and trading con- Definition o{ 

cems iadustrial bonds 

The issue of industrial bonds is a development mostly of the past 
fifteen years. The very existence of a form of industrial organiza- 
tion suitable for public financing is comparatively origin and 
recent. In the early history of this coimtry, business onndusTriaf 
combinations took the form of partnerships.^ Not <:o°«™s 
until 1811, when the New York Legislature passed a General Incor- 
poration Act, did the movement for carrying on business by means 
of the corporation attain any importance.* This act was followed 
by similar legislation in other States.^ At the beginning of the nine- 
teenth century, there were in America probably not more than one 
hundred corporations — of which at least one half were in Massa- 
chusetts. By 1840, corporations had multiplied "with a flexibility 
and variety previously unknown." * Among the earliest industrial 
corporations of importance later, were the Standard Oil Company 
of Ohio ^ organized in 1870, the Westinghouse Electric and Manu- 
facturing Company * incorporated in 1872, and Swift & Company,^ 

' Robert L. RajTnond, in Barvard Law Renew, vol. xvi, p. 80. 

2 Laws of New York 1813, vol. i, p. 245. (34th Session, chap. Lxvn, passed March 
22, 1811.) The first business corporation in the United States, however, was chartered 
in Pennsylvania in 1768: "The Philadelphia Contributionship for Insuring Houses 
from Loss by Fire." {Laws of Pa. chap, dlxxvi.) See Hanard Law Review, vol. n, 
p. 165. 

' Public Acts of Connecticut 1836-43, chap. Lxili, p. 49, approved June 10, 1837. 
Laws of Michigan 1837, no. cxxi, approved March 22, 1837. Until 1851, no corpora- 
tion could be organized in Massachusetts without a special act of the legislature. A 
general law governing the organization and conduct of corporations created by special 
act was passed in 1808. {Stats. 1808, chap. 65.) See Report of the Committee on the 
Corporation Laws (1903), p. 16. P. F. Hall, The Massachusetts Business Corporation 
Law of igo3 (Boston, 1908), p. i. 

* Francis Lynde Stetson, in Atlantic Monthly, vol. ex, pp. 31-32. 

' Poor's Manual of Industrials (1913), p. 1615. 

' Ibid. (1914), p. 1112. ' Jbid. (1914), p. 955- 



252 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

incorporated in 1885. The combination in one form or another of 
the interests of individual corporations was a natural step from this. 
Between 1899 and 1902, the movement attained large proportions. 
During this period the American Can Company, the American 
Woolen Company, the International Harvester Company of New 
Jersey, the United Fruit Company, and the United States Steel 
Corporation ^ were formed by combining the business of many 
other corporations. Such imits as these were large enough to need 
financial assistance from the public and important enough to appeal 
to the public with chance of success. In 1910, according to Poor's 
"Manual of Industrials," there were outstanding for the account 
of manufacturing and miscellaneous companies bonds amoimting 
to $2,585,694,207 and stock amoimting to $8,233,035,721, a total 
capitalization of $10,818,729,928.^ 

In discussing industrial bonds, the first great difference which 
strikes one between such bonds and practically aU other classes of 
corporation bonds is the greater degree of fluctuation 
nature of "toe ^ the business: that is, whereas the gross business of 
brmanufacto- steam railroads is likely to fall off in periods of de- 
ing and trading pression f rom five to fifteen per cent and the business 

concerns '^ ^ 

of street-railway, gas, or electnc hght and power 
concerns varies in times of general depression from a small de- 
crease to an increase, say, between five and ten per cent, the pro- 
fits of industrial concerns at such times are likely to show a decline 
often of between twenty and fifty per cent. We give in the tables 
on pages 253-55 the item corresponding most nearly to net earn- 
ings of some of our leading industrial concerns engaged in many 
different kinds of business for the years 1903 and 1904, 1907 and 
1908, and 1913 and 1914, together with percentage of change.' 

The total period between 1903 and 1914 is too short to be conclu- 
sive or to be much more than an indication as to the fluctuation in 
any given business. Owing to the fact that very few of our large 
industrial concerns reported earnings much before 1903, it has been 
thought hardly worth while to go back of that date. An examina- 

• For organization of above corporations see Poor's Manual of Industrials (1914), 
pp. 33, 102, 1008, 1041, 1296. 

• Ibid. (1910), Introduction, p. x. 

• For combined table showing percentage of change in net earnings for the three 
periods, see Appendix, pp. 308-309. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 



253 






o 



en 



O 

en 

O 






I 

•3 



I 



■s. 



I 



weooo uiiji- 



O fo « M c« 



+++ 1 + 1 + 1 I +++ 1 I I ++++++++ I 



^ - *^ 1^ '^*i ^ ^ "^.^ *^ "^ ^ "^ ^ ^"^ ^ t^ «*) W r~ «o 
QQ «0 to r- ^ « oO >/lCO 0>M ^oi[Ol>*0H' 10\0 tCoO 00 O NO 
^ Ol-O O O Tj-NOOt^MOH ihIOMOOpO O, O t^ »0 N « ti 

H 00 *o w m o Oioo >o <^ "2 w t^ w o tot^iooio o oiO h 
n w" 10 M w" to * « (O «o m" m"« *o h m" to m" « to m 10 to 



*io^io^<*-'*»o^'*w)'^io*tO'*«n'«l'iO'^wnov)^ 
BQQQQQSS2S.OSfl20oooQQOOOO 



s ^ s 



j*i^ 



II 11 S « SJ-g S 8 § 8 S ill's Si 2 g-l al 8 



*^0 

« H 
to W) 



H ineo 

"* •* H 

toi^oo 
VI 0> ts 
O ■*" 
in M M 



O-^tOWMtOf-OMOtO") OOP 00 « WS «*• M 

w to O to OiO t* r^O (otOHvOO.^O'w t^io 
>0 « O O to •4- -^o VI O ^ r- t^oo 00 H 



CO ^<^0 C4 O>00 OOHCICtOiOHr^OlOrt-t^ 

tooo '^ o; ^ ^ "^ *^*^*''!. *2 *^ *'^M o 00 tovo h 

(O^tntOMHHtCtOHMtOM ««««<> 



**>■*!? S" IP !?!? 3" !? S? 3" •^'**^**«^'^^ «"*■** to 
00222.00.20.00200000000000 

0>0tO0>O0t0iOO0vO>0>Oi0t0)O0tOQ>0i0>0)0iQi 



§1 11 y y si's § 8 s il 5 i §Kd si ^^^ ^"^ si 









3j<ii 



•••■••llllliilllilli^^ii 
llllllllllllilllllilli 



% 



o-a 



2S4 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 



t/3 



8 



B 






< 






il 



+ 1 + I I + 1 ++ 1 ++ 1 I I + 1 I I I I I +11 +++ 1 



Oioo *00 0»ommw>5 Oim ^m w« O90 «0Q 00 
H O't-O'tOO O r~»oOitH loOi^ woo t- w «« ^ M 
Oioo oO P; O; ^ c» 0«<0 '^ *^ ^ *^ f^ 1'^ "i. ^l*^ *^ '^ "^ 
«C M t^O « ^ O « Oi ^ M Oioo M N looo »J0*O eJ" m nT 
CO M »ooO O Ooooo Tfiot^w -d-oo Ooo poOidO « Ot 

« (O M -^VO 00 nT ^ »0 WtO ^ M ^ '*00 « M <0 « H « 



*Wm m Oih O 
H Oi O O^ffitOt'^ 



»6 9,q_t;^>ooo 



llllllt'l "§,1° Sal's 

3> Ot Ot 0> O Ok 0> Oi Oi Oi 0> 9 Ot O Oi 






Oico ^«OM CO O 0*O «ooo QOO «oo O t^wtn^o «*) 
coN-fl-ooiN omr^p>«0 &CO m to r* w H ■^<S ^ 

^•^ *1 ^ *1 ^^ N N *0 •* woo ^O ^ ^ XO ^ N H »rt 

«o*^r*^t»-w tnwi ^\o « Oi «co oo ^ H O **0 M 
N eo w« 00 t^ (O ^ « ^« <0 M *>0 00 W M ^ « M eO 



Otoo Sf-o M ^ •* 

H lO Q MOO Q *^ 
00 t- &*0 VO St'O 

g-o di ■^o ■^ 3- 
c-ooo Qoqo 

to N M *0 ^ ^ ^ 



&oi&&&c>&90k&o5ic>&(><>o>c>5i(>dk(> ooioii>&&9 




Jigg'Oias ta 



i i sii«ti« i 2 s-st!ti«-i«t!|t!« s si i el §1 s« 





^ 



III 






llilll 



bw 



■g M 

is 






»fc o 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 



255 






o 
u 



H 

CO 

Q 
1— I 

O 

C 



Eh 



si si 



I 

■S 



t 



+ 1 I I++ ++I I++I I I + I++I I I I l + l l + l 



S<g°3-S 



to O^OcOCO e 



CI tv M M 0> v)CO Q M C4 to to r> O t^O M O I 

t^ Q Q O to *00 OiiOtOHO^I^^OOC*',— --,- - .- -ii. _^ 

«OQ0 00 ^ M^ O '>;'0 \0 O M^ 00 OlOiWOtON fOt^t^ t^OO t^ H O O I> ^ 



Om m o hhmm HOMHMM'Hi-rMH Omh m«hO mhm mm 
CO tO(0 to to to CO CO CO to to to to to to <0 fO (O (O to ^ to I CO to to (O tO WJ 

I Btj i s a y si si I B si a 8-|si 8 g i s y siss ll si g| si 



. v)0 



1 M vQ Oi j; r^OO t 



« M o> to r« 0\'O 00 t> V) n 00 
T 00 0» ^- t»->0 ■* "t ^- M 

1^ c> U2 q 00 ^ "1. '^ 1 1 

^OOmhm 

, - . . _ . - ,. , J<<i ^00 t-vO 

i W N NtOMOO N O «VOOO M •^l'^^^ 

tO>0 too ^00 I *0 to CO ^ V) W O 00 to oJ" »o to cT tfo O MOO 4 tC ^o 
W I MHH MMM MtO 



Oi Oi V) ^ 0» p> wiQO I 
COOOI 



00 *^ t»-oo oo 5 oo o o o tooo Tf CO f 00 MM M o 00 0( ^- r~o ■* »* ^ 
coo 00 ■* o; t^^ "^o w ^ q -^o m o o; o m o cj w qcc ■ ■ " — 

^^o' ■* lo iC M oo c«" tC c> o ^^ r^oo CO t^ d « ^ to 5 



■^ .13 y 

ptj i sJ s s g a I ^ s s g^sj s g I s y SHSi &! ^ ^1 ^ 




jS^SoS 



u ui s 



•o.a.s.a g.i 



SB- 

5.a"^a^££j':£,S£a£|w(£^a':wwMSwlwwg 

dP"' ipm tdo yaw rt"-" tea 

ocdM<ua>vvvc»;vDvXa>a4Ji>a)£:;i:;vuajo4Ja,<i>iu£ 










H'«l| 



si? 






^1 



11,1 

I" 8 
S "fl 



Boo a a 






256 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

tion of the above gains or losses in net earnings during periods of 
depression shows that it cannot be assumed that any given concern 
always will show a falling-off in earnings at such times. The per- 
formance of any given company depends much on the management 
and initiative shown. It is to be noted, however, that the United 
States Steel Corporation in all three periods showed a falling-off in 
net earnings of over thirty per cent; that the General Electric Com- 
pany showed a substantial decrease in earnings in all three periods; 
that the American Woolen Company showed a loss in net profits in 
1908 of over sixty-two per cent, and a change in 1914 from a net 
loss of $677,685 to net profits of $2,788,602; and that the American 
Locomotive Company showed a fluctuation in net earnings from a 
gain of over twelve per cent in 1904 to a loss of over sixty-two per 
cent in 1914. These figures show the extremely fluctuating nature 
of the business of manufacturing and trading concerns. 

Another very important difference between industrial and other 
corporation bonds is the highly competitive nature, in most cases, 
Competitive of the business. The facts that no right of way, such 
busings done by ^^ ^ steam railroad requires, and no franchise, such 
such concerns ^s a street-railway, gas, or electric light and power 
company is likely to require, are necessary for the creation and 
operation of an industrial concern, — together with the fact that 
an industrial concern can operate in an abnost limitless field, — 
make, as a rule, the nxunber of industrial concerns engaged in any 
one business and competing with each other directly much greater 
than the number of steam railroads, and, stiU more, public-service 
corporations, so competing. Under the regulation of rates by the 
Interstate Commerce Commission, railroad competition is drifting 
toward competition between sections of the country rather than 
between individual railroads; and competition between public- 
service corporations under the regulation of state commissions 
gradually is passing away. While industrial concerns are subject 
to a considerable measure of pubUc control, the governing factor in 
their existence is likely always to be competition. 

Owing to the above conditions, the management of industrial 
concerns is a matter of far greater relative importance than the 
management of steam railroads or of public-service corporations 
— especially from the point of view of the safety of their securi- 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 257 

ties. Where an entirely new business can be started without any 
great delay and where conditions of keen competi- q^^ manage- 
tion are likely to prevail, good or bad management gf^^t^e^^ost 
is pretty nearly the whole story. ^ Valuable and efl&- important 
cient plants, large working capital, control of patented safety of in- 
articles or of some necessary raw material, all are highly "^"^^"^ ''°"^^ 
important and may be of great assistance in taking a corporation 
through a time of difl&culty; but imless the plants are used wisely, 
economically, and profitably by the management, they may have 
very little value for any other purpose and may be rendered almost 
useless by the competition of another concern that has as good or 
better plant facilities and more efl&cient management, and the most 
impressive assets as well as other advantages may be dissipated 
under poor management. 

Owing to the fact that the management of industrial concerns 
may change at almost any time, the financing of such concerns 
should be and usually is considered in a different light q^^^^ question 
from that either of steam railroads or of public-service whether com- 

^ , petitive manu- 

corporations. It is a grave question whether strictly facturfng or 

.. ,. 1. Ill trading con- 

competitive manuf acturmg or trading concerns snouid cems should 
be bonded at all. In the minds of many people, pubUc ^ °° ^ 
financing through stock alone, either preferred or common, or 
through one class of stock only, is more legitimate and more satis- 
factory than creating bonded debt. 

In the cases of industrial concerns controlling important and 
valuable patents, — such as the General Electric Company, — or 
in the cases of concerns controlling a large amount of q^^^^^j ^j 
some valuable natural resource like coal, iron ore, valuable pat- 
or phosphate rock, — such as the United States Steel valuable natural 
Corporation or the American Agricultural Chemical ll^e'SZnt ot 
Company, — or concerns owning a large amount of f^^J,?\"'f '^^^ 
valuable real estate, — such as Swift & Company, — poper basis 

, , , , , ... tor bonding' 

the creation of bonded debt may seem more legiti- 
mate and more expedient.^ 

1 Professor Dewing, after an examination of thirty-two industrial reorganizations, 
says " No business ever developed into a conspicuous success or a conspicuous failure, 
except through the ability or lack of ability of men." ((Corporate Promotions and 
Reorganizations [Cambridge, 1914], P- 3-) 

' In certain kinds of business, sometimes called specialty business — like that of 



2S8 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Even in these cases, however, and certainly in all ordinary corn- 
Amount of petitive industrial concerns, the amount of plant 
plant and of asscts compared with the amount of debt should be 

quick assets *^ 

compared with very much greater than in the case either of steam 

greater than in Tailroads or of public-scrvice corporations. Further- 

stelmraiiroads more, there should be in almost every case a large 

°5°JP"^'!'^" amoimt of net quick assets — that is, cash, bills 

service cor- ^ ' ' 

porations receivable, or marketable securities. 

Industrial ^ ahuost evcry case, moreover, it is wiser to have 

be'issued°in'* an industrial bond issue shaped up either with a 
serial form or strong sinking-fund or else as a serial issue, so that 
strong sinking- a reasonable proportion of the debt will be retired or 
"° provided for each year. 

The question that we have discussed in previous chapters in the 
cases of steam railroads and of public-service corporations — the re- 
Relation of lation of such concerns to the public — has reached in 
coSlmsto ^^ case of industrial concerns an interesting stage of 
the public development. What is the relation of our great manu- 

facturing and trading concerns to the pubhc? If such concerns are 
to issue bonds, it is highly important to know their general status. 
Do they exist legally? Do they carry on their business in conform- 
ity with law and with good business usage? Are they subject to 
interference on the part of the Government or to especially destruc- 
tive competition? On what facts and conditions does their status 
depend? In the following pages we will attempt to outline or sug- 
gest possible answers to these questions. 

It may make this phase of our subject clearer if we outline the 
origin and growth of the so-caUed " trust problem." As stated ear- 
Historic forms lier in this chapter, business combinations in the 
andori^^Sof the United States first took the form of partnerships. 
trust question Then, imder the authority of satisfactory corporation 
laws in New York, Massachusetts, Michigan, and other States, 
business began to be organized in the form of corporations. Subse- 
quently there appeared these forms of combination: — 

(i) The gentlemen's agreement. 

This was usually an informal arrangement to maintain prices 

Quaker Oats, Royal Baking Powder, or Baker's Chocolate — a well-established trade- 
mark, built up through advertising, is an asset of great value, but hardly of a kind 
suitable for bondiog. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 259 

and sometimes to regulate production, and was illustrated in the 
cases of the United States Leather Company, the Glucose Sugar 
Refining Company, the National Cordage Company, and the 
United States Shipbuilding Company.' 

(2) The pool. 

Under this plan several concerns engaged in a similar business 
agreed to divide the territory among themselves, to regulate the 
seUing price of their commodity, and generally to establish a com- 
munity of interest. This form of combination was illustrated in 
the cases of the glucose, cordage, and steel business.^ It was finally 
held to be illegal,' and became as far as known practically non- 
existent. 

(3) The strict or true trust. 

Here the several properties intended to be combined were trans- 
ferred to individuals as trustees, who issued certificates of bene- 
ficial interest. The trustees managed the business of the several 
combined properties and paid dividends on the certificates issued. 
Examples of this form of organization were the old Standard Oil 
Trust, the Sugar Trust, the Whiskey Trust, and the National Cor- 
dage Association.^ This form of organization also was held to be 
yiegal,^ and practically passed out of existence.* 

(4) The large corporation — often in the form of a holding company. 

The prohibition of pooling and the illegaUty of true trusts had 
the effect of driving practically all "big business" into the cor- 
porate form.^ 

This is the origin of what has loosely but commonly been called 
the "trust question."' 

There are certain obvious and legitimate advantages of combi- 
Economic nation, or perhaps we may say of great size. Among 

t^mbiSnir these may be mentioned: - 
of great size (j) Ability to handle large orders. 

(2) Ability to buy in large quantities and therefore more cheaply. 

> Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, p. 519. * Ibid., pp. 76, 114, 520. 
' United States v. Addyston Pipe & Steel Co., 175 U.S. 211. 

* Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, pp. 116-17. 

' People V. The North River Sugar Refining Co., 121 N.Y. 582; State v. Standard 
Oil Co., 49 Ohio St. 137. 

• Report of Industrial Commission, vol. xrx, p. 607. 

' Ibid., vol. xni, p. 6. It is interesting to note that the cordage industry passed 
through all four forms of organization. (See Dewing, Corporate Promotions and Reor- 
ganizations, p. 518.) 

8 For above account see Robert L. Raymond in Harvard Law Remew, vol. xvi, pp. 
80-81; Francis Lynde Stetson in Atlantic Monthly, vol. ex, pp. 31-32; and Dewing, 
Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, pp. 518-21. 



26o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

(3) Ability to sell in large quantities and therefore at a smaller 

percentage of profit. 

(4) Ability to utilize waste. 

(s) Ability to save charges of transportation by shipping from 
the plant nearest in location to the consumer. 

(6) Ability to specialize labor. 

(7) Opportunity for experimentation. 

These are what may be called the economic advantages of com- 
bination^ or of great size. 
There are also advantages of one kind or another in the combi- 
nation of competing concerns in some form of organiza- 
wastes of tion. Among these may be mentioned: — 

compe on ^^^ Saving in the cost of management or superin- 

tendence by the elimination of duplicate staffs. 

(2) Reduction in the number of salesmen. 

(3) Greater control of output and prices. 

These may be called some of the savings of the wastes of com- 
petition.2 

Possible dis- Very often these theoretical advantages are offset 

f^ge^sS?"* in practice by factors having an opposite effect. 
operation For instance: — 

(i) Large companies in purchasing a great amount of raw ma- 
terial sometimes push the price up against themselves. 

(2) Large concerns often are less able to avoid over-production 
in a falling market. 

(3) Heavy investment in specialized machinery sometimes makes 
a large concern peculiarly susceptible to changes in trade 
conditions. 

(4) The combination often is imwilling to change its methods 
of production or distribution in accordance with improve- 
ments in technique.' 

To this class of difficulties may be added: — 

(i) The unwieldy size of some combinations has made almost 

impossible the obtaining of management able to cope with 

such a large situation. 
(2) There is likely to be too great diffusion of responsibility in 

the management of very large units. 

' See Raymond in Harvard Law Review, vol. xvi, pp. 82-83. 
' Ibid., pp. 83-84. _ 'See Dewing, pp. SSS^^i and 364-63. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 261 

(3) There is usually a lack of acquaintance on the part of the 
management with individual employees. 

(4) There is likely to be a lack of loyalty or single-mindedness on 
the part at least of some of the officers. 

(5) There is likely to be a lack of attention to the laborious parts 
of the business by higher officials. 

(6) The methods of marketing the product may be too mechan- 
ical. 

(7) There may be prejudice on the part of customers against 
improved methods of conducting the business. 

(8) There may be prejudice on the part of the customers against 
"trusts." 

(9) The combination is likely to be susceptible to political anci 
legislative attacks and sometimes to blackmail.* 

In actual practice, the disadvantages of combination or of large 
size often have more than offset the advantages. 

Such concerns as the Standard Oil Company, the American Brass 
Company, and the American Radiator Company have been able 
to evolve management which has given them in prac- Successful and-. 
tice all the advantages of large-scale operation ; on the iSge-scaie"* 
other hand, other concerns, some of which we shall operation 
discuss later in this chapter, seem to have been handled in such a 
way as to develop most of the disadvantages and very few of the 
advantages of large-scale business. It is interesting if not wholly 
significant that in a time of general depression, such as the latter 
part of 1914 and the early part of 1915, the United States Steel 
Corporation showed record low earnings, whereas the Bethlehem 
Steel Corporation, under the personal management and" initiative 
of Mr. Schwab, showed the largest net earnings in its history. 

Neither the advantages nor the disadvantages of combination 
or of size should be confused with what may be called Distinction 
monopoly control. Monopoly control means the between ad- 
power to control the situation — the power to dictate advantages of 

,,, ,.1 i/-ji • r combination or 

terms to the laborer and the power to fix the price of size and mono- 
goods to the consumer. Briefly, it is the power to do ^"'^ '^°^^'°^ 
as one pleases.^ 

1 See Dewing, pp. SS8-62, and 564-65. 

' See Robert L. Raymond in Harvard Law Reniew, vol. xvi, pp. 82-84. 



262 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

Desire (i) to secure the advantages of size, (2) to save the wastes 
of competition, and (3) to secure monopoly control, have been the 
Motives for three leading reasons for the combination of industrial 

combination conccms.* 

Advantages of K there IS to be combination, there are many 
fo^T^rgan- advantages in combining in the form of a corporation, 
ization Jq g. Corporation: — 

(i) Many persons are able to act as a single legal entity. 

(2) There is continuity of existence. 

(3) The liability of stockholders is limited in amount. 

(4) There is ability to raise a large capital because of the lim- 
ited liability and the convenience of transferring evidence 
of ownership or stock certificates. 

(s) Actual management may be entrusted to a small body of men 
usually called the directors. 

The corporation is the only known form of organization in which 
aD these advantages exist together.'' 

The combining in the form of a corporation immediately places 
the corporation imder possible public control; for the corporation 
The corpora- derives its very existence from the public' If a given 
to°pubUc''^^'^* corporation is engaged in interstate commerce, — and 
control most large corporations are, — it becomes subject not 

only to state, but to federal control. 

Except in a very limited way, this control was not exercised in 
any form by the Federal Government until 1890. The development 
of great combinations of capital in the form of cor- 
the Sherman porations, — coinddcnt with an almost phenomenal 
nu- rust aw gj.Q.^,^ jjj population and resources in the United 
States, — together with a growing fear on the part of the people of 
the economic and social evils possible under the circumstances, led 
to the enactment in i8go of the so-called Sherman Anti-Trust Law.* 
The provisions of this law later were made applicable specifically 

* Another reason often has been the desire of promoters or bankers to make a profit 
out of the promotion of the combination or the dealing in its securities. 

' See Harvard Law Review, vol. xvi, p. 92. Some people would except voluntary 
associations from this statement. 

• See Williston on "History of Law of Business Corporations before 1800," Harvard 
Law Review, vol. n, p. 112. 

« Act July 2, 1890 (26 Stat. L. 209). 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 263 

to imports from any foreign country,^ as well as to foreign and 
interstate commerce as a whole. 

The important provisions of the Sherman Anti- teading pro- 
Trust Law are as follows: — visions of the 

Sbennan Anti- 

Section i. Every contract, combination in the form of ™^ ^^ 
trust or otherwise, or conspiracy in restraint of trade or commerce 
among the several States or with foreign nations is hereby declared 
to be illegal. (Such acts are made criminal and penalties are pro- 
vided.) 

Section 2. Every person who shall monopolize or attempt to monopo- 
lize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons to monop- 
olize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States or 
with foreign nations shall be deemed guilty of a misdemeanor. . . . (Pen- 
alties are provided.) 

These provisions remain in force to-day. Until recently, this 
was the statute under which all federal suits against alleged illegal 
combinations in restraint of trade were brought. 

How has this law worked in practice? To what extent has it been 
enforced? How has it been interpreted by the United States Su- 
preme Court? Are its provisions as now interpreted t^ . . 
wise or unwise? The answers to these questions will Sherman Law 
lead us far in estimating the present status of great 
industrial corporations in their relation to the public. 

The Sherman Anti-Trust Law has been enforced intermittently, 
spasmodically, and at times almost arbitrarily. Under President 
McKinley, it was hardly enforced at all; under Presi- Enforcement 
dent Roosevelt, it was enforced, it has been charged, °^ ^^^ '^'^ 
against his enemies and not enforced against his friends; under 
President Taft, it was enforced apparently impartially, but under 
a conception of the Attorney-General as to what constituted a 
dangerous share of the total business in any given industry. All 
efforts at enforcement have been confined to a comparatively few 
cases, owing to the physical impossibility of instituting court pro- 
ceedings — the only method of enforcement provided — against 
any large number of offenders covered by the act.* 

1 Act August 27, 1894 (28 Stat. L. 570), as amended by Act February 12, 1913 
(37 Stat. L. 667). 
' See J. H. Benton, "The Sherman or Anti-Trust Act," reprinted from Yale Lam 



264 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

The early interpretation of the Sherman Anti-Trust Law by 
Early interpre- the United States Supreme Court established these 
iawTy°thf principles:- 

Supreme Court ^^.^ ^y. combination which directly restrains inter- 
state trade is illegal. 
(.2) A holding company is a combination. 

(3 )Restraint of trade means any restraint and not merely an unrea- 
sonable restraint. 
(4) Direct restraint of trade means restraint in some degree sub- 
stantial, 
(s) Trade is restrained by the ending or limiting of competition among 
the members of the combination as well as when the business of 
others is injured. 

(6) The mere power to restrain trade is sufficient to bring a combina- 
tion within the act. 

(7) This power need not be broad enough to cover the whole country 
or even a large part.* 

Until recently, this drastic and sweeping interpretation of the 
Sherman Anti-Trust Act was the law. 

In its most important phase the law, as thus laid down by the 
United States Supreme Court, was a departure, not only from the 
This interpre- apparent intention of Congress when passing the Sher- 
parTure from ^Qan Act,^ but also from a well-established rule of the 
common law commou law. This rulc was that "restraint of trade 
or commerce " meant a restraint that was unreasonable.' In two of 
the cases in which a majority of the court held the Sherman Act 
applicable to any direct restraints of trade, opinions were delivered 

Journal, March, 1909, pp. 7, 13, 14. This article gives a complete list of suits in equity 
brought by the Attorney-General under the Sherman Act up to January i, 1909. 

1 Robert L. Raymond in Harvard Law Review, vol. xxrn, p. 373. See United States 
V. E. C. Rnight Company, 156 U.S. i; United States b. Trans-Missouri Freight Asso- 
ciation, 166 U.S. 290; United States v. Joint Traflic Association, 171 U.S. 505; Hop- 
kins V. United States, 171 U.S. 578; Anderson v. United States, 171 U.S. 604; 
Addyston Pipe & Steel Co. v. United States, 175 U.S. 21; Montague v. Lowry, 193 
U.S. 38; Northern Securities Co. v. United States, 193 U.S. 197; Swift v. United 
States, 196 U.S. 375; Harriman v. Northern Securities Co., 197 U.S. 244; Board of 
Trade of Chicago v. Christie Grain & Stock Co., igS U.S. 236; Loewe v. Lawlor, 208 
U.S. 274; Continental Wall Paper Co. v. Voight & Sons, 212 U.S. 227; American 
Banana Co. v. United Fruit Co., 213 U.S. 347. The Sherman Law never has been 
interpreted by the Supreme Court as regards foreign commerce. (Public Service 
Regulation and Federal Trade Reporter, January i, 1915, p. 12.) 

' See Congressional Record, vol. xxi, part 4, pp. 3146, 3148. 

' See William F. Dana in Harvard Law Review, vol. xvi, pp. 179, 180. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 265 

insisting on the old common-law meaning, that is, unreasonable 
restraints. 1 

The above interpretation could not last. It made illegal every 
combination directly restraining interstate commerce, whether 
such restraint was reasonable or unreasonable. It . 
made practically every business man in the United tation could 
States liable to criminal prosecution. If strictly and °° ^ 
imiversally enforced, which it was not and could not be, it would 
have brought the business of the United States as a whole to a 
standstill.^ 

In later decisions of the Supreme Court, the law in „ . 

... , , , New mterpre- 

substance if not m words was changed. These deci- tation in the 
sions were in the famous Standard Oil and American andAmerican 
Tobacco cases.' In these cases, the court held: — '^°'''-'="' "^^ 

(i) That the Anti-Trust Act prohibited unreasonable or undue re- 
straint of interstate trade or attempts to monopolize the same in 
any and every form. 

(2) That trade is unduly restrained (a) by agreements which lessen 
competition among those agreeing to an extent which reasonably 
may be thought to injure the competing or consuming pubUc; (b) 
by acts, combinations, or mere conditions of existence which ref>- 
resent a purpose to acquire monopoly control. 

(3) That the Standard Oil Company of New Jersey and the American 
Tobacco Company, as shown conclusively by the purposes and 
results of their conduct, were engaged both in unreasonable or 
imdue restraints of interstate trade and also in attempts to monop- 
olize the same; that therefore they were illegal under both the first 
and second sections of the Sherman Act.* 

In these decisions the Supreme Court practically reestablished 
the common-law nUe iu regard to restraint of trade. 
In reaching this conclusion, the court took as the principal test 

'■ See WMte, J., in United States v. Trans-Missouri Freight Association, 166 U.S. 
2go; Brewer, J., in Northern Securities Co. v. United States, T93 U.S. 197. 

2 See J. H. Benton, from Yale Law Journal, March, 1909, p. 15. According to 
Charles R. Van Hise, the early interpretation of the Sherman Act took us back to the 
principles which prevailed in England from the Middle Ages to 1844. {Public Service 
Regulation, February 15, 1915, p. 99-) 

• Standard Oil Company of New Jersey v. United States, 221 U.S. i (rgii) ; United 
States V. American Tobacco Company, 221 U.S. 106 (1911). 

* See Robert L. Raymond in Harvard Law Redew, vol. xxv, pp. 35-36, and in 
Journal of Political Economy, vol. xx, p. 316. 



266 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

of illegality the injury of the competing or consuming public. It 
, , held that interference with the right of others to trade 

Grounds oi • • • j j i 

dedsions in was an imdue restraint; it considered that oppression 
andAmerican of the public and the use of unfair methods of com- 
Tobacco cases petition constituted attempts at monopoly. In the 
American Tobacco case, the court distinctly stated that it did not 
base its decision (i) on mere size, (2) on the mere fact of combina- 
tion, (3) on the mere extent of control over the trade. In both cases 
the court took its stand on the broad ground: "Is this a case where 
the general public is injured?" The subject of attack was not 
the principle of combination, but monopoly control and unfair 
methods.^ 

The evidence in the Standard Oil case showed that the company 
had received from railroads rebates and discriminations; that it 
Evidence on had made contracts in restraint of trade; that it had 
decUions^ indulged in local price-cutting, in spying on competi- 

were based ^ors, and in the operation of bogus independent com- 
panies.^ The evidence in the American Tobacco case showed that 
the company paid for competing concerns prices entirely out of 
proportion to actual valuations; that in many cases it abandoned 
and dismantled plants purchased; that in practically every case of 
purchase of a competing concern it forced an agreement from that 
concern not to engage in the tobacco business for a long term of 
years; that it lowered at times the price of its product below cost 
to kill off competition; and that generally it engaged in competition 
of a sort which resulted in driving others out of business or com- 
pelling them to enter the combination. The methods by which 
the combination was brought about and control maintained were 
secretive and misleading, showing a conscious wrongdoing with 
intent to obtain mastery.' 

standard ou "^^^ Standard Oil and American Tobacco decisions 

and American brought the interpretation of the Sherman Anti-Trust 

Tobacco cases " , * 

brought inter- Act to a practicable, and mteUigent basis. They were 
Sherman Act to in cvcry scuse of the word "reasonable" decisions, 
a workable basis 'j-jjgy permitted combinations formed to secure the 

1 Hanard Law Reoiew, vol. xxv, pp. 35-53 • For the announcement of similai 
principles, see the recent decision of the English Lord Chancellor in the Salt Monopoly 
case. {Public Service Regulation, February 15, igij, p. 102.) 

2 Harvard Law Review, vol. xxv, p. 35. ' Ibid., pp. 46, 49. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 267 

economic benefits of size or to save the wastes of competition, but 
they refused to permit combinations formed to secure monopoly 
control — that is, formed to do as the combiaations pleased with 
production, wages, and prices. They refused to permit such com- 
binations by refusing to permit unfair methods. 

Combinations formed and capitalized on the basis of monopoly 
control cannot endure if competition is given a fair chance. They 
are inherently imsotmd. Such combinations owe their „ . 

, . , , ... If given a fair 

success, perhaps even their existence, to the abmty to diance compe- 
interf ere with the rights of outsiders — in other words, feat monopoly 
to the use of unfair methods of competition. To pay ""^^°^ 
dividends on a capitalization representing monopoly control, a 
combination must lower wages or raise prices. The truth of this 
will be shown when we take up later in this chapter certain indus- 
trial failures. These failures, where they were not due to inefficient 
management, were due to inability to maintain monopoly control 
in the face of actual or potential competition. To make potential 
competition effective is the basis of a true solution of the trust 
problem.^ 

Potential competition may be made effective: (i) By giving alien 
capital a chance to know all the facts — that is, by publicity; (2) 
by insisting that combinations shall fight competition 
by fair methods only; (3) by preventing the abuse of under wWch 
monopoly during the period necessary for potential comprtWon 
competition to become actual competition — that ^y be made 
is, by some form of government inspection or super- 
vision.^ These conditions will enable outsiders to compete. 

This solution of the problem has been attempted recently in 
the passage by Congress of two laws: * Enactment of 

(1) "An Act to supplement existing laws agamst un- Federaf Trade 
lawful restraints and monopolies and for other La^°^°° 
purposes"; approved October 15, 1914, and com- 
monly known as the "Clayton Anti-Trust Act." 

(2) "An Act to create a Federal Trade Commission, to define its 

* Harvard Law Renew, vol. xxv, p. 56; Ibid., vol. xvi, pp. 88-93; and Dewing, 
Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, p. 558. 

' Harvard Law Review, vol. xvi, pp. 88-93. 

■ Acts of 63d Congress, igi^t4. Stats. L., part i, p. 730, and Acts of 63d Con- 
gress, igi3-i4. Stats. L., part i, p. 717. 



268 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

powers and duties, and for other purposes"; approved September 

26, 1914. 

These two laws were considered in connection with each other. 

Leading pro- The leading provisions applicable to industrial 

cflyton Antt concems of the Clayton Anti-Trust Act are as 

Trust Law folloWS: — 

Section 2. That it shall be unlawful for any person engaged in 
commerce, 1 in the course of such commerce, either directly or in- 
directly to discriminate in price between different purchasers of com- 
modities, which commodities are sold for use, consumption, or resale 
within the United States or any Territory thereof or the District of 
Columbia or any insular possession or other place under the jmisdic- 
tion of the United States, where the effect of such discrimination may 
be to substantially lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in 
any line of commerce: Provided, That nothing herein contained shall 
prevent discrimination in prices between purchasers of commodities on 
account of differences in the grade, quaUty, or quantity of the commod- 
ity sold, or that makes only due allowance for difference in the cost of 
selling or transportation, or discrimination in price in the same or differ- 
ent communities made in good faith to meet competition: And provided 
further, That nothing herein contained shall prevent persons engaged in 
selling goods, wares, or merchandise in commerce from selecting their 
own customers in bona fide transactions and not in restraint of trade. 

Section 5. That it shall be unlawful for any person engaged in com- 
merce, in the course of such commerce, to lease or make a sale or contract 
for sale of goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies or other com- 
modities, whether patented or unpatented, for use, consumption or 
resale within the United States or any Territory thereof or the District 
of Columbia or any insular possession or other place under the jvuisdic- 
tion of the United States, or fix a price charged therefor, or discount 
from, or rebate upon, such price, on the condition, agreement or under- 
standing that the lessee or purchaser thereof shall not use or deal in the 
goods, wares, merchandise, machinery, supplies or other commodities of 
a competitor or competitors of the lessor or seller, where the effect of 
such lease, sale, or contract for sale or such condition, agreement or 
understanding may be to substantially lessen competition or tend to 
create a monopoly in any line of commerce. 

Section 7. That no corporation engaged in commerce shall acquire, 

directly or indirectly, the whole or any part of the stock or other share 

capital of another corporation engaged also in commerce where the effect 

of such acquisition may be to substantially lessen competition between 

1 Meaning interstate or foreign commerce. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 269 

the corporation whose stock is so acquired and the corporation making 
the acquisition, or to restrain such commerce in any section or commim- 
ity, or tend to create a monopoly of any line of commerce. 

No corporation shall acquire, directly or indirectly, the whole or any 
part of the stock or other share capital of two or more corporations en- 
gaged in commerce where the effect of such acquisition, or the use of such 
stock by the voting or granting of proxies or otherwise, may be to sub- 
stantially lessen competition between such corporations, or any of them, 
whose stock or other share capital is so acquired, or to restrain such 
commerce in any section or community, or tend to create a monopoly of 
any line of commerce. . . . 

Section 8. That from and after two years from the date of the ap- 
proval of this Act no person at the same time shall be a director in any 
two or more corporations, any one of which has capital, surplus, and 
undivided profits aggregating more than $1,000,000, engaged in whole 
or in part in commerce ... if such corporations are or shaU have been 
theretofore, by virtue of their business and location of operation, com- 
petitors, so that the elimination of competition by agreement between 
them would constitute a violation of any of the provisions of any of the 
Anti-Trust Laws.' 

These provisions are the gist of the law. 

Other important sections applicable to industrial concerns are: 
one providing that any violation of the penal provisions of the 
Anti-Trust Laws by a corporation shall be deemed ^,, . 

, , , other impor- 

also a crime of the individual directors, oflEicers, or tant provisions 
agents who have authorized such violation; ^ one industrial 
providing that any person, firm, corporation, or asso- '^°°'=*™= 
ciation shall be entitled to sue for and have injunctive relief against 
threatened loss or damage through a violation of the Anti-Trust 
Laws; ' and one vesting authority to enforce sections 2, 3, 7, and 8, 
in so far as they are applicable to industrial concerns, in the Federal 
Trade Commission subject to review by the courts.^ 

The Clayton Anti-Trust Act does not do away with any part of 
the Sherman Anti-Trust Law of 1890. It amplifies Clayton Act 
and supplements that law. In the opinion of ex-Presi- s^£nte^the 
dent Taft, it does not, with the possible exception of Sherman Act 
the so-called tying provision in the sale of patented articles, enlarge 

' The Anti-Trust Laws in the meaoning of this act are: The Sherman Act, portions of 
the Wilson Tariff as amended, and the Clayton Act. 
* Section 14. ' Section 16. • Section 11. 



270 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the field of illegal and criminal effort in respect to restraints of 
interstate commerce or monopolies. In other words, all the leading 
prohibitions concerning restraints of trade in the Clayton Act — 
(i) discriminations in price in sales of goods, (2) sale of goods pat- 
ented or impatented on condition that the purchaser shaU not deal 
in or use the goods of a competitor, (3) acquisition of stock by one 
corporation in another, and (4) acquisition of stock by one cor- 
poration in two other corporations, when the effect of any one of 
these four acts may be substantially to lessen competition, restrain 
interstate commerce, or tend to create a monopoly — with the 
possible exception above noted, were covered by the Sherman Act 
as interpreted by the Supreme Court. The new law is therefore 
chiefly declaratory. ^ It has been pointed out, however, by ex- 
Attomey-General Wickersham that the meaning of the phrase, "to 
substantially lessen competition," used in sections 2, 3, and 7 of the 
Clayton Act, remains to be interpreted by the courts, just as the 
phrase, "restraint of trade," in the Sherman Act has been inter- 
preted.^ 

The Clayton Act expressly exempts from the prohibitions against 
price discriminations and tying contracts, goods not intended for 
Clayton Act "use. Consumption, or resale within the United 
Ta^t^^A States" — in other words, exports.* The Sherman 
to exports j^q^ (joes not do so, but makes illegal every contract 

or combination in restraint of trade "among the several States or 
with foreign nations." * It has been thought desirable that groups 
of American manufacturers should be permitted to join together 
(i) in the maintenance of joint exhibits of their products in foreign 
markets; (2) in conducting cooperative sales campaigns; and (3) in 
pooling expenses and dividing profits.^ How this will be worked 
out remains to be seen. 

The prohibitions against stock ownership in competing corpora- 
tions apply only to ownership by a corporation. There is nothing 
Holding to prevent the ownership by one or more individuals 

companies ^f g^jj qj. j^y pg^^j. q{ jj^g gtock of Competing corpo- 
rations." 

' Public Seroice Regulation, November 1, 1914, pp. 612-13. 

» Ibid., January 15, 1915, p. 37. » Sections 2 and 3. * Section i. 

' Federal Trade Reporter, March 15, 1915, p. 174. 

» See Rush C. Butler and Cornelius Lynda, The Federal Trade Commission and the 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 2/1 

The prohibition of interlocking in the case of industrial corpora- 
tions applies not to officers or employees, but only to directors. 
Opinions have been advanced for and against the interlocking 
wisdom of this prohibition. Mr. James J. Hill thinks directorates 
the prohibition ridiculous because it "can produce nothing but a 
orop of dummy directors." '■ The ideal situation would be preven- 
tion, not of interlocking directors in all cases, but of the abuse of 
their power. A man should not act as buyer and seller in the same 
transaction; but he shoiild be allowed to give the benefit of his 
broad experience in certain cases to more than one board of direc- 
tors. The only solution of this problem is a sense of honor on the 
part of the director, enforced, perhaps, by public opinion. 

The personal-guilt clause of the Clayton Act ^ relates to the 
penal provisions of the Anti-Trust Laws. It fastens guilt for the 
illegal act of the corporation on the individual direc- Personai- 
tors, officers, or agents of the corporation. It proceeds suJt clause 
on the theory that to stop "joy-riding" it is necessary "to arrest 
the chauffeur and not the automobile." ' 

The right of injunctive relief granted by the Clayton Act to any 
person, firm, corporation, or association, against threatened loss or 
damage by a violation of anything in the Anti-Trust Machinery of 
Laws, is a right hitherto held only by the Govern- eDiaicement 
ment.* In many other ways, also, the enforcement of the Anti- 
Trust Laws is made more efficient. The benefit of a decree in a 
government suit accrues to private litigants, and the time con- 
sumed in the government suit is added to the regular period of 
three years in determining the time in which a suit may be brought 
for the recovery of damages. As in the Sherman Law, any individ- 
ual, corporation, or association injured in his business or property by 
reason of anything forbidden in the Anti-Trust Laws may sue for 

Regulation of Business under the Federal Trade Commission and Clayton Laws (Chicago, 
1915), pp. 11-13. In the opinion of Frands Lynde Stetson, holding companies should 
be permitted, but minority stockholders should be protected. {Atlantic Monthly, 
vol. ex, p. 40.) 

1 Federal Trade Reporter, March i, 1915, p. 139. 

' Section 14. 

' Statement of President Wilson as quoted in the Boston Evening Transcript, 
January 14, 1914. 

* See State of Minnesota v. Northern Securities Company et al., 194 U.S. 48, and 
National Fire-Proofing Co. v. Mason Builders' Association, 169 Fed. Rep. 259. 



272 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

and recover threefold damages and costs. ^ The Government, as 
imder the Sherman Law, may proceed in equity to prevent and 
restrain violations of the Anti-Trust Laws.^ 

In a general way, the Clayton Act is part of the legislation in- 
tended to eliminate the so-called "twilight zone" of legality and 
Summary of the illegality. Some people think that in so far as it pro- 
ciayton Act hibits Certain definite practices it weakens the Sher- 
man Law.' The practices prohibited, however, have been for 
many years familiar to business men and have come up again and 
again in the courts. It is to be noted that no practice is prohibited 
in sections 2,3, and 7 of the Clayton Act, unless the practice shall 
have the effect of substantially lessening competition, restraining 
interstate or foreign commerce, or tending to create a monopoly. 
In the last resort, the law in its terms gives to the Circuit Court of 
Appeals and the Supreme Court the discretion which the Supreme 
Court took for itseK in interpreting the Sherman Act. 

Passed at practically the same time as the Clayton Act, and 

considered in connection with it, is the Federal Trade Commission 

,^ , Law. This law creates a commission composed of 

Fcdcrs.! Trade 

Commission five men appointed by the President of the United 
States by and with the advice and consent of the 
Senate. Not more than three of the commissioners shall be mem- 
bers of the same pohtical party. The term of office of each com- 
missioner ultimately shall be seven years; but provision is made 
for the term of one commissioner to mature each year. Each com- 
missioner shall receive a salary of $10,000 a year. The Commission 
shall have authority to employ and fix the compensation of such 
attorneys, special experts, examiners, clerks, and other employees 
as it may from time to time find necessary for the proper perform- 
ance of its duties and as may be appropriated for by Congress. 
The Commission shall succeed the Bureau of Corporations.^ 
The Commission is empowered and directed to prevent persons, 
partnerships, or corporations, except banks and com- 

Prevention of* ., . .. .1,^ 

unfair methods mon camcrs, from usmg imiair methods of competi- 

compe 1 on ^.^^ .^ interstate or foreign commerce. The law says: 

"That unfair methods of competition in commerce are hereby 

' Section 4. ' Section s- 

' See Annalist (New York), April 20, 1914, pp. 488-89. * Sections i, 2, and 3. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 273 

declared unlawful." ^ Whenever the Commission shall have reason 
to believe that any person, partnership, or corporation has been 
or is using any unfair method of competition in interstate or foreign 
commerce, and if it shaU appear to the Commisaon that a proceed- 
ing by it in respect thereof would be to the interest of the public, 
it shall issue and serve upon such person, partnership, or corpora- 
tion a complaint stating its charges in that respect, and containing 
a notice of a hearing upon a day and at a place therein fixed at least 
thirty days after the service of said complaint. Any person, part- 
nership, or corporation may make application and, upon good cause 
shown, may be allowed by the Commission to intervene and appear 
in said proceeding by coimsel or in person. If, upon such hearing, 
the Commission shaU be of the opinion that the method of compe- 
tition in question is prohibited by this act, it shall make a report in 
writing in which it shall state its findings as to the facts, and shall 
issue and cause to be served on such person, partnership, or cor- 
poration an order requiring him or it to cease and desist from using 
such methods of competition. Until a transcript of the record in 
such hearing shall have been filed in a United States Circuit Court 
of Appeals, the Commission may at any time modify or set aside, 
in whole or in part, any report or any order made or issued by it 
under this section.^ The Commission may apply to the United 
States Circuit Court of Appeals for the enforcement of its order, 
and any party ordered by the Commission to cease from unfair 
methods of competition may obtain a review of such order in the 
same court. The findings of the Commission as to the facts, if 
supported by testimony, shall be conclusive. The court may order 
additional evidence taken before the Commission. The court shall 
have power to make and enter a decree affirming, modif)dng, or 
setting aside the order of the Commission. The jurisdiction of the 
Circuit Court of Appeals in this respect shall be exclusive and the 
judgment and decree of this court shall be final — except that the 
same shall be subject to review by the Supreme Court upon certiorari. 
The Commission also shall have authority: — 

(i) To enforce, in so far as they are applicable to in- Other powers 
, . ■ ^. J o 1! ii and duties 

dustnal concerns, sections 2, 3, 7, and 8 of the of the Trade 

Clayton Law. Commission 

> Section 5. * Section 5. 



274 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

(2) To investigate the organization, business, conduct, practices, and 
management of any corporation, excepting banks and common 
carriers, engaged in interstate or foreign commerce and its relation 
to other corporations and to individuals, associations and part- 
nerships. 

(3) To require corporations engaged in interstate or foreign com- 
merce, except banks and common carriers, to file with the Com- 
mission annual or special reports or answers in writing to specific 
questions. 

(4) To investigate, on its own initiative, the manner in which any 
final decree against a corporation to prevent and restrain any 
violation of the Anti-Trust Acts has been or is being carried out.^ 

(5) Upon the direction of the President or either House of Congress, to 
investigate and report the facts relating to any alleged violation 
of the Anti-Trust Acts by any corporation. 

(6) Upon the application of the Attorney-General, to investigate and 
make recommendations for the readjustment of the business of 
any corporation alleged to be violating the Anti-Trust Acts in 
order that the corporation may thereafter maintain its organiza- 
tion, management, and conduct of business iu accordance with law. 

(7) To make pubhc from time to time such portions of the informa- 
tion obtained by it hereunder, except trade secrets and names of 
customers, as it shall deem expedient in the public interest; and 
to make annual and special reports to the Congress and to submit 
therewith recommendations for additional legislation; and to 
provide for the publication of its reports and decisions in such 
form and manner as may be best adapted for public information 
and use. 

(8) From time to time to classify corporations and to make niles and 
regulations for the purpose of carrying out the provisions of this 
act. 

(9) To investigate, from time to time, trade conditions in and with 
foreign countries where associations, combinations, or practices 
of manufacturers, merchants, or traders, or other conditions, may 
affect the foreign trade of the United States, and to report to 
Congress thereon, with such recommendations as it deems ad- 
visable.^ 

(10) To act as a master in chancery in any suit in equity brought by the 
Attorney-General as provided in the Anti-Trust Acts.' 

* On the application of the Attorney-General, it must make such investigation. 

' Section 6. Some people think that this section gives the Trade Commission 
authority to act as a tariff board. 

• Section 7. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 275 

(ii) To obtain, on the direction of the President, information relative 
to any corporation subject to this act from the several departments 
and bureaus of the Government and a detail of such officials and 
employees as he may direct.' 

(12) To have access to, for the purpose of examination, and the right 
to copy any documentary evidence of any corporation being inves- 
tigated or proceeded against; and to require the attendance and 
testimony of witnesses and the production of all such docu- 
mentary evidence relating to any matter under investigation.* 

Upon the appUcation of the Attorney-General of the United 
States, at the request of the Commission, the district courts of the 
United States shall have jurisdiction to issue writs of mandamus 
commanding any person or corporation to comply with the provi- 
sions of this act or any order of the Commission made in pursuance 
thereof.' 

These, with the prohibition of unfair methods of competition, are 
the leading provisions of the Federal Trade Commission Act. 

The Federal Trade Commission Act, in addition to furnishing 
machinery for the enforcement of the Sherman and Clayton Acts, 
itself sets up a new legislative standard — "unfair unfair methods 
methods of competition." The question of what are °^ competition 
vmfair methods of competition, while not defined in the law,* is 
understood in a general way in business practice. The framers of 
the law decided that to attempt to define or enumerate unfair 
methods of competition in advance would be to leave open oppor- 
tunities for evasion and thereby weaken the law. For if only certain 
practices are prohibited, the ingenuity of man will invent new ones 
which may be just as unfair. Mr. Stevens, of the faculty of Politi- 
cal Science of Columbia University, has classified unfair methods 
of competition as follows: Local price-cutting; operation of bogus 
"independent" concerns; maintenance of "fighting ships" and 
"fighting brands"; lease, sale, purchase, or use of certain articles 
as a condition of the lease, sale, purchase, or use of other required 
articles; exclusive sales and purchase arrangements; rebates and 
preferential contracts; acquisition of exclusive or dominant control 

* Section 8. ' Section 9. ' Ibid. 

* "Unfair competition" has a definite meaning in law — the passing-oflf of one's 
goods as those of another. Rathbone, Sard & Co. ti. Champion Steel Range Co., 189 
Fed. Rep. 26, 31; 37 L.R.A. (N.S.) 258; W. R. Lynn Shoe Co. v. Aubum-Lynn Shoe 
Co., 100 Me. 461; 62 Atl. 499, 5°S' 4 L.R.A. (N.S.) 960. 



276 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

of machinery or goods used in the manufacturing process; manipu- 
lation, blacklists, boycotts, whitelists; espionage and use of detec- 
tives, coercion, threats, and intimidation.' Such methods as the 
above. Congress evidently intended to prevent in declaring imfair 
methods of competition unlawful. In general, it intended appar- 
ently to prevent those methods regarded in good business usage as 
unfair and particularly those methods likely to lead to monopoly 
— or, to make a still broader generalization, to prevent those 
methods of competition harmful to the public. ^ The meaning of 
the phrase, however, will have to be interpreted in specific cases by 
the Commission and the courts.' 

The new Federal Trade Commission has been compared by ex- 
President Taf t and others with the Interstate Commerce Commis- 
sion. There are many points of resemblance. As the 

Comparison oi -^ , , , j^ x ii ji*** 

Federal Trade interstate Commerce Law declares undue discnmma- 
withTnterSate ^^^ ^^^ Unreasonable rates unlawful, so the Trade 
Commerce Commission Law declares imfair methods of competi- 

Commission . _ ^ 

tion unlawful. As the former creates a commission to 
determine what rates are unduly discriminating and unreasonable, 
so the latter creates one to determine what are unfair methods of 
competition. Equally inquisitorial powers are conferred on the two 
commissions, and similar processes and hearings are provided in 
case of alleged violation of the law on the complaint of any one or 
on the Commission's own initiative. The Interstate Commerce 
Commission, however, has a wider discretion, free from review 
by the courts, than has the Trade Commission. The Commerce 
Commission not only finds the facts, but exercises in detail the 
legislative function of Congress in regulating rates. All that the 
courts do in review of action by the Commerce Commission is to 
see that it is within the scope and limitations of the general delega- 

1 Annalist (New York), October 26, 1914, p. 340. 

' President Taft considers unfair methods of competition to include only those 
methods and practices the effect and intent of which will bring them within the scope 
and condemnation of the first and second sections of the Sherman Act. {Public Service 
Regulation, November i, 1914, p. 612.) 

' According to the terms of the law, unfair methods of competition are forbidden 
to all persons, partnerships, and corporations, except banks and common carriers, 
engaged in interstate or foreign commerce (see Section $)• For a discussion of the 
treatment of unfair methods of competition in England, France, Germany, and other 
countries see H. D. Nims in the Outlook, February 7, 1914, p. 310. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 277 

tion of power and that it does not deprive the carrier of its property 
without due process of law — in other words, that it does not con- 
fiscate. The function of the Trade Commission also is to find the 
facts, but the final decision as to what are fair or unfair methods 
of competition will rest with the courts. ' 

Ex-President Taft also has compared the fimctions of the Trade 
Commission ia preventing imfair methods of competition with the 
action of a master in chancery. Like a master, the 
Trade Comanission finds the facts; but unlike a mas- cerUmVunc-" 
ter, the decision of the Trade Commission as to the T™de°Commis- 
facts, if supported by legal evidence, is final, whereas f^^^^^^ 
the decision of a master in chancery as to the facts can Master in 

, ,.... 1 ei • 1 r • Chancery 

be reversed, if it is contrary to the weight of evi- 
dence." '^ 

In general, the new Federal Trade Commission has been created 
to carry on the work of the Bureau of Corporations in investiga- 
tions and also to furnish a convenient machinery for General powers 
enforcing the Sherman and Clayton Anti-Trust Laws ^ th "xradf 
and the prohibition in the Trade Commission Act Commission 
against unfair methods of competition. It is a body evidently 
intended to use discretion. Its powers are of three sorts: (i) Inquisi- 
torial; (2) administrative; (3) quasi-judicial. It can investigate, 
except as to financial condition, all corporations engaged in inter- 
state or foreign commerce and the relation of such corporations to 
private individuals, firms, and associations. It can classify corpo- 
rations and ask for information or reports from certain classes and 
not ask for such information or reports from other classes. In other 
words, it can reduce its investigations to a workable and discre- 
tionary basis. In exercising its administrative functions, it must 
force compliance with the terms of the Clayton Act and probably 
of the Sherman Act. In the matter, however, of filing a complaint 
in connection with the use of unfair methods of competition ac- 
cording to the Trade Commission Act, the Commission is left the 
discretion of bringing an action only in cases where it shall appear 
to the Commission that such action will be in the interest of the 
public. This is, of course, a very broad discretion. The quasi- 
judicial functions of the Commission enable it to act in corrective 
1 Pttblic Service Regulation, November i, 1914, p. 613. ' Ibid. 



278 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

processes in aid of the courts, in establishing unfair methods of 
competition, in providing for the readjustment and reorganization 
of corporations under decrees of the courts and in entering consent 
decrees in connection with the Department of Justice. 

The Trade Commission and the Department of Justice imdoubt- 
edly will act in cooperation in enforcing the Anti-Trust Laws. 
Relation be- Either the Commission or the Attomey-CJeneral's 
Federal Trade °^^^ ^^^ ^^^ independently, of course, in a large field. 
Commission It has been suggested by the Attorney-General's office 
Department that probably the principal work of enforcing the 
of Justice Sherman Act will contmue to be done by the Depart- 

ment of Justice, whereas the Trade Commission will act largely 
under the Clayton Law and the prohibition in the Trade Commis- 
sion Law against imf air methods of competition. The Department 
of Justice imdoubtedly will seek the views of the Trade Commission 
regarding dissolution decrees against corporations adjudged to be 
monopolies. It will also undoubtedly tium over to the Commission 
a large number of voluntary complaints that have been sent in dur- 
ing the past few years alleging "unfair" practices, but which do not 
charge or tend to prove the existence of monopoly. The Attorney- 
General's office takes the position that, where cooperation with the 
Trade Commission is not ordered by law, such cooperation will 
depend entirely on the discretion of the Attorney-General.' 

A most important feature of the Trade Commission Act is the 
provision for publicity. The Commission can, if it chooses, hold 
pubUdty open hearings, and it can make public, except trade 

Trade^OTi-''^ secrets and the names of customers, any information 
mission Act which it sees fit. This publicity, it has been pointed 
out, should have three effects: (i) Where excessive profits by cor- 
porations are shown, competition will be encouraged to enter the 
field — that is, potential competition will become actual competi- 
tion; (2) labor will be in a position to imderstand whether or not it 
is being properly paid; and (3) investors will be enlightened as to 
the value of their securities.^ In general, the publicity features of 
the Trade Commission Law are among its most important provi- 
sions. If taken advantage of intelligently and in the proper spirit, 

' Federal Trade Reporter, April i, 1915, pp. 207-08. 
' Ibid., Marcti i, igiSi p. 157. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 379 

they will go far toward bringing about a solution of the so-called 
trust problem and toward enabling investors to appraise the se- 
curities of any given corporation in their true hght. 

Chairman Davies, of the new Federal Trade Commission, in all 
his public utterances lays stress on the fact that the Trade Com- 
mission Law will be interpreted not in terms of men- p^,.^ ^j ^^^ 
ace, but in terms of constructive helpfulness. He calls Trade Com- 

• , . , ,_,.. -I 11 mission as out- 

attention to the fact that the Conmussion gradually lined by chair- 
will come into possession of a vast amount of corre- ""^^ ^"^^ 
lated information in regard to the industries and business of the 
country and that this information, except trade secrets and names 
of customers, will be available to Congress and the people. He 
calls attention also to the fact that the Commission wiU be in a 
position to settle a great many difficulties without htigation. He 
refers to the power of the Commission to stop imfair methods of 
competition as the power which wiU ktU monopoly in the seed or 
cut it off at the roots. For the greatest menace, he says, to the 
296,000-odd small corporations in this country is the unfair meth- 
ods of competition used by the comparatively small number of 
large corporations. The Trade Commission will be in a position, 
like the Interstate Commerce Commission, to give continuous 
administrative action; the Department of Justice can deal only 
with violations of law. Mr. Davies considers the Trade Commis- 
sion the greatest safeguard since the Sherman Law for preserving 
the independence of sm,aU concerns and keeping open the channels 
of trade. If hi§ ideas are followed, the Commission's principal work 
will be to bring business into harmony with the law. He hopes that 
its work will result in a new era of good feeling. ^ 

One of the leading framers of the law feels that as time goes on 
the corrective work of the Commission will diminish and its con- 
structive work will increase.'' Business gradually will ^^^^^ ^^^_ 
become adjusted to the rulings of the Commission and mission in a 
the courts, and business men will set their houses in do^construc- 
order. The Commission has the power to investigate "^^ """'^ 
conditions in foreign countries and to make recommendations 

' See PMic Service Regulation, January i, 1915, pp, 6-7; ibid., January is, 1915, 
pp. 39-42; Federal Trade Reporter, March i, 1915, pp. 134-36; ibid., April i, 1915, pp. 
195-96; Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 100, p. 1551. 

^ Senator Newlands, as quoted in Public Service RegtthHon, February i, 1915, p. 70. 



28o AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

which will aid in the development of our foreign trade. It is in a 
position to make rulings and suggestions which may be of im- 
mense benefit to general business. At the same time, according 
to its declared intention, the Commission will not act as a board of 
advice to business men in entering on any given programme. * It 
will not and should not place itseK in a position to approve in ad- 
vance any given act. As one writer has put it, the board should not 
be a body of men to which business men can nm and ask ques- 
tions.^ At the same time the commissioners, according to their own 
statement, will discuss informally with business men various phases 
of their business.' The whole atmosphere surrounding the enact- 
ment of the Trade Commission Act, irnhke that which prevailed 
at the time of the passage of the Interstate Commerce Law, is 
constructive and helpful.^ 

There are certain precedents applicable to a greater or less degree 
for the creation of the Federal Trade Commission. In Canada, the 
judicial processes have been supplemented by a pro- 
analogies for cedure which, upon complaint of persons injured, 
Trade Com- permits the question of attempted monopolies to be 
mission investigated by a temporary commission appointed 

by the court. In Australia, in 1912, there was created an Interstate 
Trade Commission with a character of permanency and of expert 
qualifications and with broad powers to investigate conditions 
and enforce the laws regarding competition. 

Until the enactment of the Trade Commission Law in the United 
States, the governmental machinery for the prevention of monop- 
oly has been investigation by general legislative 

New act sub- " •• j'-j.^- js= j^i-j. 

stitutes regu- commission or admimstrative officers and the msti- 
l^lston fo?""" tutmg of court proceedings by the Department of 
regulation by Justicc.^ The new act substitutes for what has been 

lawsmt *' . 

called regulation by lawsuit^ regulation by a con- 
tinuous administrative body. 

^ Federal Trade Reporter, April i, 191s, p- 196. 

^ R. L. Raymond in the Journal of Political Economy, vol. 20, p. 324. 
' See the Annalist (New York), April 26, 1915, p. 405. 

' Since the passage of the law the United States Chamber of Commerce has ap- 
pointed a committee to cooperate with the Trade Commission. 
' Commissioner Davies, as quoted in the Boston Evening Transcript, February 4, 

° R. L. Raymond in Journal of Political Economy, vol. 20, p. 319. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 281 

The Trade Commission Law has been criticized adversely on 
these grounds : — Certain criti- 

(i) The Commission has no authority to make a Trade Com- 
favorable report or order. mission Law 

(2) It is not empowered to recommend any rule of conduct for 
the future. 

(3) It is not permitted to allow combinations for the develop- 
ment of foreign trade.-^ 

The last-named power could not be given without amending the 
Sherman Law. The question of recommending any rule of conduct 
for the future has been discussed. As to giving the Commission 
authority to make a favorable report or order, this does not seem 
to us important. If any investigation is made and the Conamission 
does not make an unfavorable report, the presumption is that the 
practices complained of are not illegal. Again, under the publicity 
features of the law, the Commission can give out a great amount of 
information, if it wishes, which will enhance the reputation and 
credit of corporations. 

On more general grounds, there has been a great deal of adverse 
as well as much favorable criticism of the Trade Commission Law. 
Some people, like Senator Sutherland and Robert R. ^^^^^ ^^_ 
Reed, think that the Commission is clothed with un- verse criti- 

r. 1 1 J 1 r asms of me 

constitutional powers. Senator butnerlana speaks 01 Trade Com- 
many powers of the Commission as retroactive. He °"^^'°° 
also questions the constitutional right of the Commission to 
exercise semi-judicial powers over aU corporations engaged in 
interstate and foreign commerce. =* Robert R. Reed considers 
that if Congress has regulative power over all corporations, it 
has no authority to delegate such power.' He considers also that 
there is great danger of the creation and protection of monopoly 
under a federal bureaucracy.^ James J. Hill fears that as time goes 
on the Federal Trade Commission, like the Interstate Commerce 
Commission, will constantly be given increased powers and that 
the authority which it has already over all business is dangerous in 

» See Butler and Lynde, The Federal Trade Commission, pp. 43-4S- 
2 See the Sunday Herald (Boston), April 18, 1915. 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 100, p. 684. 
< AtlanHc Monthly, vol. cvi, p. 260. 



282 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the extreme.^ The law has been criticized also on the ground that 
ordinary business has not reached the stage of development that 
the railroads have reached, and that any such rigid control of in- 
dustry as we have had in the case of railroads would be exceedingly 
harmful.^ Senator Weeks thinks that the Trade Commission Act 
will place all business in a strait-jacket. He calls attention to the 
fact that boards are "long, narrow, wooden things." ' The law has 
also been criticized on the ground that this is a government of 
laws and not of men.* It is to be remembered that objections of 
very much the same general character were raised at the time of 
the passage of the Interstate Commerce Law. 

The Federal Trade Commission Act, the Clayton Act, and the 
Sherman Anti-Trust Law are to be thought of together as embody- 
Soiution of the ^^S ^^^ ^^ federal legislation dealing with the trust 
trust problem problem. This legislation has reached, in our opinion, 

IS to give fair ... ., ... , „, , 

play for com- a fairly satisfactory if mcomplete stage. The real 
Fair p°ay^for solution of the trust problem, — vital to investors as 
combination ^^^ ^^ ^^ ^-^^ public, — in the opinion of the best 
judges, is to give fair play for competition and fair play for combi- 
nation.^ In other words, the solution lies in the working-out of 
economic laws without interference, except in so far as that inter- 
ference is necessary to prevent unfair practices. The interpretation 
of the Sherman Law by the Supreme Court in the Standard Oil and 
American Tobacco cases and the enactment of the Clayton and 
Trade Commission Laws all point to the fact that the highest court 
and Congress have come to the conclusion that unfair practices, 
rather than mere combination, are what should be prevented.* 

The wisdom of this view will appear still more clearly when we 
consider the unfortimate history of some of our great combinations. 
Such combinations do not always have things all their own way, 
even when they are in a position to use unfair methods. If unfair 

1 Federal Trade Reporter, March i, 1915, p. 139. 

' W. L. Clause, as quoted in Federal Trade Reporter, March 15, 1915, I*. 163. 

' Federal Trade Reporter, March 15, 1915, p. 182. 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 100, p. 684, and Public Service Regtda- 
Hon, January i, 1915, p. 5- 

' See Journal of Political Economy, vol. 20, p. 318. 

' The prohibition against holding companies would seem to modify this statement 
considerably. At the same time, as stated earlier, there is nothing in the Clayton Law 
to prevent ownership of two competing corporations by the same individuab. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 283 

methods are prevented, competition almost certainly will prevent 
anything hke monopoly control. If any corporation 
attempts to capitalize its control over markets and micHnery 
a it can maintain this control only by imfair meth- p?^enting^°' 
ods, aU the machinery now exists for bringing such monopoly 

... , ■,-, , < . > 00 control 

control to an end. From the prohibition of unfair 
practices, as laid down by decisions of the Supreme Court under 
the Sherman Law, as laid down in the Clayton Law, and as will be 
laid down under the interpretation of the Trade Commission Act. 
and through its pubUdty features, potential competition will be in 
a position to know all the facts and become actual competition, 
within a reasonable time. 

No laws and no government are perfect. Only as the laws are 
enforced and as the administrative machinery is used by men ^ can. 
it be shown whether they are for good or ill. At the 
same time there is nothing in the experience of the kgisiaSon as it 
United States or of other countries to make us think ^y pjoyt^'' 
that in the long nm the trust legislation, as it exists ^^'^g^ti*'"* 
to-day, will be harmful. It may be very benefidaL If 
we should assume that the great majority of business men are de- 
termined to carry on their business in a dishonorable, unfair, and 
illegal way, it would undoubtedly be difl&cult to enforce the anti- 
trust laws as they exist. If we assume, however, that most busi- 
ness men intend to do somewhere near what is right and that many 
business men are exceedingly glad of the opportunity to understand 
more clearly how to conduct their business in accordance with the 
law, the enforcement of the anti-trust laws and the work of the 
Trade Commission may be positively constructive and benefidal.. 

There is one more suggestion that has been made for public 
control of large industrial units — that is, federal incorporation. 
Some who suggest this step go so far as to suggest Federal 
government control of prices ^ under certain drcum- "»corporation 
stances. Supervision of the issue of securities is ahnost always a 
feature of this plan. Until the present body of law has been tried 

1 The personnel of the new Trade Coaunission has been criticized by ex-President 
Taft and others. The effectiveness of the present Commission's work remains, of 
course, to be seen. (See Federal Trade Reporter, Jime 15, 1915, P- 362.) 

' See William Randolph Hearst in the Boston American, January 26, 1914. 



284 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

out, however, it seems to us hardly necessary to undertake federal 
incorporation. In general, public control of industrial corporations, 
owing to the presence of keen competition, should be much less 
close and much less severe than in the case of steam railroads or of 
public-service corporations. 

It may throw a good deal of light on the actual working-out of 
the so-caUed trust problem, especially in its bearing on the safety 
„ ^ as a class of industrial bonds, to consider in a general 

Corporate pro- . . - . . 

motions and way certam mdustnal promotions and reorganiza- 
tions. Dr. Arthur S. Dewing, of Yale University, has 
published ia the Harvard Economic series a very careful and read- 
able book discussing certain typical corporate promotions and reor- 
ganizations. We will outline briefly some of the general principles 
which he considers established and will illustrate these with a few 
examples. 

The purposes of the promotions or consolidations which Profes- 
sor Dewing considers were mainly two: (i) To realize the economies 
Certain ex- °^ large-scale production; and (2) to eliminate compe- 
periencesin tition or obtain monopoly control. 1 Experience 

economies of /-i 

large-scale showed that often extravagant confidence was placed 

m monopoly" in the economies of large-scale operation. This was 
control u^g ^g^gg with the cordage, malting, asphalt, and ship- 

building promotions. In these instances the expenses of promotion 
and other disadvantages more than offset the estimated economies.'' 
In the matter of monopoly control, thirteen combinations showed 
an average degree of control or average percentage of total produc- 
tion of about fifty-four per cent. In individual cases, the percent- 
age of production ranged from only about seventeen per cent in 
the case of the National Salt Company to about eighty-five per 
cent in the case of the Glucose Sugar Refining Company.' There 
seemed to be no correspondence between the degree of control 
and the subsequent success or failure of the business. The two 
concerns having as large a degree of control as any considered — 

* Dewing, Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, p. 523. 
' Ihid., pp. 4, 537-39. 

• Concerns not reorganized having an unusually large degree of control were the 
American Tobacco Company in the cigarette business and the American Chicle 
Company in the chewing-gum business. Each of these concerns controlled about 
ninety per cent of the American output. {Ibid., p. 325.) 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 285 

the glucose and asphalt combinations — were stifled within two 
years. ^ 

The prospective profits of the combination usually were esti- 
mated and the capitalization arrived at on the basis of past earn- 
ings — a basis which proved very imreliable. The ^ ., 

. , . , . , , Failure of 

average earmngs turned out to be ]ust two thirds the earnings to 

i i- • i J 9 meet estimates 

amount anticipated.^ 

In the matter of capitalization, the average proportion, in the 
case of fourteen combinations, between tangible assets and total 
capitalization was about forty per cent. It is interest- proportion be- 
ing to note that the two concerns having the largest ^IsTt" anTtotal 
percentage of control of any considered — the Glu- capitaUzation 
cose Sugar Refining Company and the Asphalt Company of Amer- 
ica — each had as small a percentage of tangible assets to total 
capitalization as any considered.* This indicates, of course, capi- 
talization of monopoly control. 

Not the proportion between the tangible assets and the total 
capitalization, but the form which the capitalization took, proved 
important ia times of difl&culty. Issue of bonds or Formofcapi- 
obligations entailing a fixed rate of interest often '^ponantThan 
resulted in trouble in times of general depression or amount 
when earnings fluctuated from any cause.^ 

In the cases of thirty-one reorganizations discussed in Professor 
Dewing's book as due to financial difficulties, the failures took 
many forms — ranging from inability to earn even various degrees 
the operating expenses of the business to inability to °^ ^^'"^^ 
earn and pay normal wages, normal interest, and normal profit. 

Examination of the various failures showed the inadequacy of 
mere consohdation as a basis for economic efficiency. From a busi- 
ness point of view there were two leading causes of ^ ,. , . 

^ . .... Leadmg busi- 

failure: (i) Inability to obtam admimstrative man- ness causes 
agement capable of handUng a large situation; and 
(2) inability to dominate the industry in the presence of actual or 
potential competition.^ 

' Dewing, Corporate Promotions and Reorganizations, p. 527- 
' Ibid., p. 546- The promotion of the American Hide and Leather Company illus- 
trated an extreme case of failure to realize the estimates. 

• IMd., pp. 531-33- * I^^-' P- S34. ' Ibid., p. 558. 



286 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

There were almost always present three sources of competition: 

(i) Old competitors not absorbed by the combination; (2) old 

competitors who had sold out; and (3) new competi- 

7h.r66 sources 

of possible tors attracted by the exorbitant profits promised in 
compe ition promotion circulars.' 

In all the failures discussed in Professor Dewing's book, with the 
possible exception of the American Bicycle Company, the direct 
Direct cause cause of failure was the deflection of working capital 
of failure to the payment of interest and dividends ; or, to put it 

deflection of . \ ■^ , , . , , , • j . j 

working capi- m another way, the placmg of bonds on untried mdus' 
of interestand trial enterprises and the lack of conservatism in de- 
dividends claring dividends. In the year before failure or reor- 

ganization, eighteen out of twenty-four corporations paid either 
unearned interest or imeamed dividends. The motives for pajdng 
unearned dividends usually were: (i) To make a market for the 
company's securities; (2) to return an income on the holdings of 
directors. Evidence goes to show that if the assets had been con- 
served, failure in most cases could have been avoided and a larger 
ultimate return to security-holders obtained.* 

, , ., A brief summary of some of the causes of failure in 
lire in certain the cascs of Certain large industrial concerns may be 
m VI ua cases ^^ interest,' and will be found in the table on pages 
287-88. These are not all the failures discussed in Professor Dew- 
ing's book, but they are the leading ones. 

A consideration of the causes of failure in individual cases to- 
gether with the causes in general discussed earlier 
industrial con- leads One to the following conclusions: — 
undertaken * (i) That attempts to Capitalize and exercise mon- 
with great care opoly control, unlcss backed up by unfair 

methods, are futile.^ 

' Dewing, Corporate Promotions and Reorganisations, p. 563. 

' Dewing, pp. SS^S^, SSlS^- 

' Ibid., pp. 16-17, 24-25, S7-6i, 6S-70, 79, 83-86, 93-98, 112-13, 123-2S1 133, 141, 
147, 150-51, 157-59, 164, 166-69, 177-79, 182, 185-86, 197, 203-04, 210-12, 214, 220- 
21, 225-26, 232, 234, 236-37, 239-42, 248, 249, 259, 263-64, 268, 286-89, 294-96, 304, 
318-24, 330-31, 335, 340-43, 346, 354-56, 360, 363-64, 367, 371-72, 374-76, 399, 411- 
13, 432-33, 437, 441-43, 445, 447, 45i, 462-65, 496-99, 5o8. 

* Attempts to exercise monopoly control require usually either (i) maintaining 
prices on an artificial level by absorbing all the surplus supplies, as the National Cord- 
age Company attempted to do; or (2) cutting prices to kill competition, as the Asphalt 
Company and the Com Products Company in its early days tried to do. (Dewing, 
p. 600.) 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 
BUSINESS FAILURES 



287 



Concern 



United States Leather Company 



National Starch Manufacturing 
Company 



National Starch Company 
Glucose Sugar Refining Company 

Com Products Company 

National Cordage Company 
United States Cordage Company 



Standard Rope & Twine 
Company 

Standard Cordage Conipany 



Westinghouse Electric & Manu- 
facturing Company (two 
reorganizations) 



National Salt Company 



Causes of failure 



Tanning industry not suited to large-scale produc- 
tion. Small plant investment, but large working 
capital required. Raw material purdiased and 
finished product sold under conditions of keen 
■competition. General business depression 
1893-98. Issue of 8% cumidative pn-eferred 
stock largely to acquire unproductive timber 
lands. 

Poor condition of some of the plants. Heavy fixed 
and txjntingent charges. Competition. Busi- 
ness depression following the panic of 1893. 
Mismanagement. 

Increase in fixed charges. Attempt at monopoly 
control. Mismanagement. 

Poor condition of plants and inadequate provision 
for renewals. Overcapitalization. Competition. 
Mistaken trade policy and unwise dividend 
policy. Expensive litigation. 

Capitalization of monopoly control. Adverse 
trade conditions including vigorous competi- 
tion. Neglect of depreciation and obsolescence. 
Unwise pajTnent of dividends. Inefficient 
management. 

Capitalization of monopoly control. Payment of 
large dividends. Neglect of business by officers 
for speculation in company's securities. 

Inadequacy of reorganization of National Cordage 
Company. Inability to control competition. 
"Banker" management. 

Keen competition. Lack of single-mindedness on 
the part of officers. 

Heavy burden of debt. Inefficiently equipped 
mills. 

Lack of conservatism of Mr. Westinghouse. 
Rapid expansion involving heavy plant invest- 
ment. Lack of profit in foreign subsidiaries. 
Lack of working capital. Unconservative divi- 
dend policy. Accumulation of large floating 
debts. 

Attempt at monopoly control. Extravagant con- 
tracts. Inabihty to maintain monopoly prices 
— due to overproduction and the mcrease of 
competition. 



288 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 
BUSINESS FAILURES (continued) 



Concern 



United States Realty & Con- 
struction Company 



American Bicycle Company 



Pope Manufacturing Company 
(1907) 



American Malting Company 



New England Cotton Yam 
Company (1903) 



Union Mills Company 



Mount Vemon-Woodberry Cot- 
ton Duck Company 

United States Cotton Duck 
Corporation 

Consolidated Cotton Duck 
Company 

International Cotton Mills 
Corporation 

Asphalt Company of America 
National Asphalt Company 



United States Shipbuilding 
Company 



Causes of failure 



Overestimate of earning power and overcapitali- 
zation. Speculation in land and securities. 
Difficulties arising from relations with labor. 
Unsound methods of accounting. Financial 
depression of 1903. 

Passing of the bicycle craze and general collapse 
of the industry. 

Attempt to manufacture automobiles and conse- 
quent necessity for new equipment. Lack of 
working capital. 

Inability to control competition. Failure to real- 
ize economies of large-scale production. Lack 
of loyalty on the part of officers. PajTnent of 
unearned dividends. 

Incapable management. Unwise trade policy. 
Increased costs of raw material and labor. 
Unconservative dividend policy. 

Difficulty of managing so large an enterprise. 
Burdensome lease of the New England Cotton 
Yam Company. 

Industry not suited to consolidation. Unwise 
issue and retention of mortgage bonds. Inabil- 
ity to obtain management able to cope with the 
situation. Competition. Inadequate charges 
to depreciation. Attention to market for com- 
pany's securities to the neglect of the business. 
Complicated financial structure. 



Capitalization of monopoly control. Heavy fixed 
charges. Development of new process for mak- 
ing asphalt. Interference of Venezuelan Gov- 
ernment. Severe competition. Lack of loyalty 
of higher officers. 

Shipbuilding at time of promotion unusually un- 
profitable. Promotion under conditions of in- 
flation and misrepresentation. Placing of 
bonded debt on the properties. Financial de- 
pression of 1903. Lack of working capital. 
Unavailability of the earnings of the Bethlehem 
Steel Company, the only prosperous subsidiary. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 289 

(2) That good management is the most important factor in 
success. 

(3) That the competitive and fluctuating conditions surrounding 
industrial enterprises make the bonding of such concerns 
advisable only imder carefuUy chosen circumstances and 
carefully guarded restrictions. 

To state the problem ia another way: Generally speaking, only 
those concerns organized to prosper under conditions of competi- 
tion should be bonded, and then only to an amount the fixed 
charges on which can be met easily in times of depression. ■• 

Whether bonded or not, the financial structure of an industrial 
concern should be built with a view to its permanent adaptability 
to the industry. In order to succeed, the concern „ , 

-' ^ ' General con- 

must pursue a sound trade policy and a sound finan- ditions neces- 

. , , . „ . , , , . sary to success 

aal poucy. bome of the most conspicuous successes of industrial 
among industrial concerns are not bonded at all, '^°°*^^™^ 
pursue in general the policy of manufacturing a first-class product 
and selling it on a small margin of profit or at a reasonable price, 
and make no attempts at monopoly control. Among such concerns 
may be mentioned the American Radiator Company, the General 
Chemical Company,* and the Ford Motor Company. 

In reorganizations, efforts usually have been made to remedy 
two sets of conditions: (i) Trade conditions; (2) errors of capitali- 
zation. Sometimes the policy has been pursued of ^^^ amzations 
attempting to increase control of the market — as aim to correct 
in the cases of the National Starch Manufacturing tions and errors 
Company, the Glucose Sugar Refining Company, the ° "^^^^ ^^*'°° 
National Salt Company, and the Asphalt Company of America. 
As to correcting errors of capitalization, efforts in this direction — 
as in railroad reorganizations — have been directed principally 
toward lightening the burden of fixed charges.' 

Industrial reorganizations have been formulated mainly on the 
theory that the difficulties to be corrected were in- Capitalization 
herent in the particular concern imder consideration an^iJTranrLd 
rather than due to temporary general conditions — reorganizations 

* This is without taking into consideration control of patents or of valuable sources 
of raw material or ownership of real estate referred to earlier in this chapter. 
' Dewing, pp. 544> 601-02. ' Ibid., pp. 602-03. 



290 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

as has been the case so often in raibroad reorganizations. In 
practically all railroad reorganizations, the total capitalization has 
been greater after reorganization than before. In thirty-two indus- 
trial reorganizations considered by Professor Dewing, on the other 
hand, the total of new securities has been only eighty-nine per cent 
of the old. There has been, however, an increase in the proportion 
of bonds — in which these reorganizations have been markedly 
unlike the leading railroad reorganizations of 1893 to 1898.' 

In twenty-seven industrial reorganizations, the new fixed 
^. , , charges have been seventy-eight per cent of the old. 

Fixed charges ° ..,,,,.,, 

in industrial Frequently the prmapal of the lien has been mcreased, 
reorgamza ons j^^^ ^^ interest rate on the new bonds has been 
less than on the old.'' 

As in railroad reorganizations, where there has been foreclosure, 
minority bondholders have been paid off in accordance with the 
„ , foreclosure price. This is almost sure to be much 

Treatment of 

bondholders in less than the face value of the debt. In the case of 
reorgamza ons ^^ Asphalt reorganization, minority bond-holders 
received only eleven per cent of the par value of their bonds. 
Bondholders who have gone into reorganizations, whether after 
foreclosure or not, usually have received new income bonds or 
preferred stock.' Sometimes the debt has not been disturbed, as 
in the case of the United States Leather Company debentures.* 
We give on page 291 a table showing reorganiza- 
bondhoiders m tions involving Sacrifices by bondholders.* An exam- 
reorgamza ons jj^g^^jgj^ pf j^g table shows that in two cases — that of 

the Standard Rope and Twine Company and that of the National 
Asphalt Company — there was an assessment on bondholders. 
The new securities obtained in exchange for old bonds were: in two 
cases — the United States Cordage Company and the Standard 
Rope and Twine Company — income bonds; in one case — the 
National Cordage Company — first preferred stock; in one case — 

1 Dewing, pp. 611-14. • Ibid., pp. 611-13. » Ibid., p. S94. 

♦ Ibid., p. 35- Other usual features of industrial reorganizations have been: 
Surrender by preferred stockholders of their claim to cumulative dividends and the 
acceptance of a security bearing a lower rate of income; severe cutting-down of the 
par value of the holdings of common stockholders; and furnishing of new money either 
by bankers or by assessment of old security-holders. 

' Ibid., p. S94. 



mOUSTWAL BONDS 



291 




292 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

the American Bicycle Company — second preferred stock; in two 
cases — Mt. Vemon-Woodberry Cotton Duck Corporation and 
the Asphalt Company of America — preferred stock to the extent 
of fifty per cent of the old bonds; and in one case — the National 
Asphalt Company — common stock to the extent of forty per cent 
of the old bonds. 

AH industrial reorganizations considered have sought to relieve 

the accumulated and unmanageable floating debt brought about 

by the deflection of money from the needs of the busi- 

Summary of , 

industrial ness to the payment of interest and dividends. All 

reorganizations • j.- i_ i j. i j. • i 

reorganizations have sought also to improve, when 
necessary, trade conditions. As a whole, they have sought "to 
achieve the financial rehabilitation of the corporation along lines 
leading to permanent success." '■ 

AH the considerations discussed so far in this chapter are of a 
Necessa to Dio^e or less general nature. In trying to determine 
consider each the Safety of any given industrial bond issue, it is 
issue on its necessary to confine one's attention to the individual 
own men s property and business and _the conditions surroimd- 
ingit. 

Examples of strong industrial bond issues are: American 
Agricultural Chemical 5% October i, 1928; General Electric 5% 
Examples of September i, 1952; Swift & Company 5% July i, 
strong indus- 1944; Wcstem Electric 5% December 31, 1922. The 
American Agricultural Chemical Company controls 
a large amount of phosphate rock — a material necessary for the 
manufacture of commercial fertilizers; owns and operates over 
fifty plants in various parts of the United States; has a large 
amount of net quick assets; and has shown its ability to make good 
net earnings over a long series of years and even in times of general 
business depression. The General Electric Company controls valu- 
able patents; has an unusually large amoimt of net quick Eissets 
compared with its debt; and has shown its ability to earn even 
imder adverse circumstances many times the interest charges on 
its bonds. Swift & Company have a plant investment over twice 
the amount of the mortgage bonds, and must have at all times net 
quick assets equal at least to the amoimt of the debt. The Western 

1 Dewing, p. 614. 



INDUSTRIAL BONDS 293 

Electric Company has total assets over four times the amount of 
its debt, and must always have net quick assets at least double 
the amount of these bonds outstanding. Many other examples 
of strong industrial bond issues could be given. 

We give below prices on July 3, 1914, or the near- prices of lead- 
est date, of certain leading industrial bond issues SS"' 
listed on the New York Stock Exchange.' •" '914 

PRICES JULY 3, 1914 OF LEADING INDUSTRIAL BONDS — 
PRICES "AND INTEREST." 
Isstie Prica- 

American Agricultural Chemical 5% 1928 looi 

American Hide & Leather 6% 1919 i02| 

American Ice Securities 6% 1925 89 

American Thread 4% 1919 94|> 

American Tobacco 6% 1944 i2i|, 

American Writing Paper 5% 1919 65 

Baldwin Locomotive Works 5% 1940 103I 

Bethlehem Steel 5% 1926 99 

Central Leather 5% 1925 99f 

Com Products Refining 5% 1931 94I 

Distillers Securities 5% 1927 S8§ 

E. I. du Pont Powder 4^% 1936 86 

General Electric 3!% 1942 79 

General Motors 6% 1915 loof 

International Paper 6% 1918 99I 

International Steam Pump 5% 1929 44 

New York An: Brake 6% 1928 97 

Republic Iron & Steel 5% 1934 104I; 

Standard Milling 5% 1930 88 

The Texas (Oil) 6% 1931 102 

Union Bag & Paper 5% 1930 85! 

U. S. Realty & Improvement 5% 1924 83I 

U. S. Rubber 6% 1918 io2f 

U. S. Steel s% 1963 ^°3 

Western Electric 5% 1922 ioi| 

Westmghouse Electric & Manufacturing 5% 1931 9Sf 

This table indicates the wide variation in degree of safety of differ- 
ent issues. We have here bonds selling aU the way from 44 per cent 
of their par value to 121^ per cent. The "income basis" or net 
' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 99, p. 35. 



294 AMERICAN AND FOREIGN INVESTMENT BONDS 

return of some of the issues hardly is worth trying to figure; that of 
some of the highest priced issues — such as American Agricultural 
Chemical 5 per cents, American Tobacco 6 per cents, Baldwin 
Locomotive 5 per cents, General Electric 3^ per cents, Republic 
Iron and Steel 5 per cents, United States Steel 5 per cents, and 
Western Electric 5 per cents — is less than 5 per cent. 

The European War has changed greatly the business and pros- 
pects of many of our leading industrial concerns. Those companies 
Effect of the receiving orders for mimitions and other war supplies 
onindustri^" ^^^^ shown a great increase in business. Among these 
bonds juay be mentioned the Bethlehem Steel Corporation, 

E. I. du Pont de Nemours Powder Company, and the Westing- 
house Electric and Manufacturing Company. The bonds of all 
these companies were selling in July, 1915,' at considerably higher 
prices than they sold in July, 1914. 

We have not meant to say in this chapter that aU industrial 
bond issues are less safe than all railroad or public-service issues. 
Selection of Throughout this book we have tried to lay stress on 
industrial bonds the fact that each bond issue of any kind must be 
requires judged on its own merits. At the same time we do feel 

great care ^^^ ^^ Conditions surroimding the issue of industrial 

bonds prompt greater care in the selection of such bonds than do 
the conditions surrounding any other well-known classes of invest- 
ment bonds. 

> See Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. loi, p. 37. 



CONCLUSION 

Tms book has been completed in the midst of a period of world- 
wide upheaval. The relation of peoples to their governments, the 
trade relations between the great nations of the world, and the rela- 
tive positions of those nations in the leadership of civilization are 
in process of change. One fact only, perhaps, is clear even now: 
that the United States rapidly is attaining a position of power 
which it never has held before. Not only is the broad basis for the 
safety of American securities greater than ever before, but the 
United States is approaching the position of furnishing the leading 
market for the securities of other nations. 

It is hoped that this book has thrown some light on the leading 
principles governing investment in bonds. 



THE END 



APPENDIX 
COUNTY AND MUNICIPAL DEFAULTS 

EARLY PERIOD 

Elizabeth, New Jersey, defaulted interest on its city bonds February 
I, 1879. The cause of the default was the spirit of speculation and the 
desire for local improvements prevailing from 1869 to Elizabeth, 
1873. The dty loaned its credit liberally for improve- New Jersey 
ments, and levied assessments by the linear foot to reimbmrse itself. In 
1875, a court decision held that assessments should be made according 
to the "present" benefit derived by property-owners from the improve- 
ments. As many of the improvements had deteriorated greatly in value, 
the dty thereby was burdened directly with a debt of about $3,000,000.^ 
Later, the city had difl&culty in collecting taxes.^ Citizens then set up 
claims of unconstitutionality and illegality in the issue of the bonds. 
Judgments were obtained, however, by bondholders.^ June 3, 1880, the 
New Jersey Supreme Court confirmed the judgment of the lower court, 
upholding the validity of the bonds.* The United States Circuit Court 
denied a motion for the appointment of a receiver or trustee for the city.° 
Later the legislature gave authority to Elizabeth to compromise this 
debt.' At first, fairly Uberal terms for the bondholders were sug- 
gested.^ Elizabeth soon put forward the claim, however, of inability 
to pay more than fifty cents on a dollar. In 1882, the debt with interest 
amoimted to $6,700,000, while the total value of the taxable property 
was only $12,182,035.* Later, the court issued an order for the city to 
show cause why it should not pay its debt. A similar previous order had 
caused five out of eight assessors to resign before the order was served 
against them.' In July, 1888, a resolution of the City Council was 
passed authorizing the Mayor, Comptroller, and the Commissioners of 
the Sinking-Fund to issue 4% adjustment bonds for old obligations of 
the city at a rate not higher than fifty per cent of their par value and 
accrued interest.'" 
Memphis, Teknessee, defaulted interest January i, 1873.'* In 1877, 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 146. 

' Ibid., vol. 29, p. 120. ' Ibid., vol. 29, p. 563. » Ibid., vol. 35, p. 602. 

• Ibid., vol. 29, p. 277. • Ibid., vol. 32, p. 312. » Ibid., vol. 39, p. 581. 

* Ibid., vol. 30, p. 589. ' Ibid., vol. 32, p. 368. " Ibid., vol. 47, p. 50. 

'' Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, January 26, 1878, 
p. 10. 



298 APPENDIX 

the so-called " Flippen" compromise of fifty cents on a dollar of principal 
Memphis, and interest in new thirty-year 6% bonds was arranged.^ 

Tennessee -phe Mayor of the city, in a message to the City Council 

a few years before, had referred to the judgment of the United States 
Circuit Court on certain bonds of the city of Memphis. The Mayor said 
that for one lot of $67,000 bonds issued, the city had received only 
$17,789.17. It was the duty of the city, said the Mayor, to resist pay- 
ment beyond "price or sum realized, or the price paid for them by the 
holder," with the legal rate of iuterest added. A local newspaper esti- 
mated the whole amount of questionable bonds as about $2,450,000. It 
claimed that the city never had realized more than an average of forty- 
two cents on a dollar of this amoimt — " Say it realized fifty cents, which 
will answer as probably covering cost of litigation." * 

Owing to a yellow-fever epidemic in 1878, the dty again was unable to 
take care of its obligations. A repudiation meeting of citizens was held.* 
January 29, 1879, the Tennessee Legislature passed two bills repealing 
the city charter of Memphis and creating the "Taxing District of Shelby 
County." ^ The lower court appointed a receiver for the city,* but thk 
action later was invalidated by the United States Supreme Court.^ 
Later still, the United States Circuit Court at Memphis held the taxing 
district liable for the old debt of the city.'' This old debt, not previously 
compromised, finally was funded at fifty cents on a dollar into new bonds 
bearing interest for the first three years, from January i, 1881, at 3%, 
for the next tliree years at 4%, and thereafter at 6%. The lower interest 
rates were to be capitalized, so as to give the holders 6%. The "Flip- 
pen" compromise bonds were exchangeable at par.* Including capitali- 
zations, the settlement was effected at an average rate of 60.53%. From 
July, 1889, interest on the so-called "Tax District" 4-6 per cents and on 
the "Flippen" stamped bonds was paid at the rate of 6% per annum.' 

PiTTSBTTRG, PENNSYLVANIA, after the Construction of the Pennsyl- 
vania Railroad, wanted more rapid and more direct communication with 
Pittsburg, the West. It subscribed to the capital stock of five railroad 

Pennsylvania companies and issued in payment $1,800,000 dty bonds 
at 6%. A few years later, owing to general finandal disasters, the rail- 
way stocks declined in value and paid no dividends. The dty, having 
rehed on these dividends, failed to pay the interest on its bonds. Suit 
was brought, judgment obtained, and the railroad stocks levied on. The 
city permitted the stocks to be sold at a sacrifice and a large part brought 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 25, p. 114. ' Ibid., vol. 18, p. 526. 
' Ibid., vol. 27, p. 678 and vol. 31, p. 328. * Ibid., vol. 28, p. 121. 

5 Ibid., vol. 28, p. 173. " Ibid., vol. 32, p. 70. ' Ibid., vol. 34, p. 604. 

' Ibid., vol. 37, p. 202. 
' Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, July 28, 1888, p. 10. 



APPENDIX 299 

only ten cents on a dollar. The city later proposed a compromise by 
which the 6% bonds were exchanged for 4% bonds having fifty years to 
run. The greater part were exchanged. Some creditors refused to accept 
and brought suit for interest on the old bonds. The judgments, amount- 
ing to over $500,000, were paid in currency in 1871.' 

Again in 1877, the city defaulted in interest on certain bonds.* The 
cause of this default was extensive improvements, including newly 
paved streets. Bonds to pay for these improvements were issued by the 
city, but were supposed to be paid out of special assessments. The law 
permitting issue of these special assessment bonds was declared illegal 
by the Supreme Court of the State.' In March, 1879, ^ ^^'^ ^°^^ ^^s 
subscribed to pay the overdue interest on these Pittsburg 7 per cents, 
known as the "Penn Avenue" bonds.* 

St. Clair County, Missotjki, in 1870 issued bonds in aid of the 
Tebo & Neosho Railway. The proposed railroad never was built, and 
the taxpayers repudiated the bonds,* Holders of the g^ q^;^ 
bonds resorted to the courts over and over again without County, 
avail. The State Supreme Court held the county not '^^°"" 
liable. The United States Circuit Court, however, on the theory that 
the bondholders were innocent purchasers, ordered a tax levy to pay 
principal and interest. This amounted, at the time of the decision, to 
nearly $900,000, although the issue of bonds was only $200,000.' The 
debt had grown to be about one third of the assessed value of the whole 
county. Members of the County Court persistently refused to make a 
levy. Several members served jail terms for contempt, and one of the 
qualifications for oflSce in the county was a willingness to go to jail 
rather than be a party to the levy.^ AJl the bonds of this county are still 
in litigation.* 

LATER PERIOD 

Galveston, Texas, defaulted December i, 1901, in interest due on 
limited debt bonds of 1881.° The default was due to the great storm of 
September 8, 1900, in which over 7500 persons were lost Galveston, 
and fully as many more left the city to seek employment '^^^^ 
elsewhere.^* In tie final settlement, there was simply a reduction of 

* Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 13, p. 242. 

' Ibid., vol. 24, p. S19. ' Ibid., vol. 24, p. 591- * ^*«*m vol. 28* p. 302. 

6 Ibid., vol. 66, p. 819 and vol. 89, p. 1293. ' Ibid. 

' Ibid., vol. 89, p. 1293. 

8 State and City Section, C(WJ>»erct(rf a«rf FJwoBcio/ Cfo-owfete, May30, I9i4,p. 124. 
» Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 73, p. 1273. 

i" State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 1914, 
p. 19s, and Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 71, p. 564. 



3CO APPENDIX 

interest from s% to 25% for a period of five years from December i, 
1901.* This was agreed to willingly by most of the bondholders.^ 

MiDDLESBORO, KENTUCKY, was a flourishing town in the early nineties, 
and was the center of what was considered to be a staple iron and steel 
Middlesboro, manufacturing district. An English syndicate was inter- 
Kentucky ested in developing the iron business there, but after many 
years the quality of the ore ran out and this large EngUsh plant was 
abandoned. Later, other plants moved away, taking with them a great 
deal of the population. The character of the city changed entirely, and 
it was not long before the new population began to question the debts 
settled on it by the old and to demand a readjustment. Interest was 
defaulted and the matter taken to the courts by bondholders.^ The 
United States Circuit Court declared the debt vaUd and binding. An 
agreement between a bondholders' committee and the city provided as 
follows: From October i, 1905, interest was reduced from 6% to 4%, 
and a lump sum of $28,000 was agreed on for overdue interest, judg- 
ments, etc., to be paid in fourteen annual installments of $2000 each, 
beginning on or before December 31, 1907.' 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 74, p. H02. 

' Information received from bankers. 

' Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 84, p. 404. 



REFERENCES FOR CERTAIN COUNTY AND 
MUNICIPAL DEFAULTS 

AusHn, Texas. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 

1914, p. 193. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 69, p. 91 ; vol. 70, pp. 46 and 
7SS; vol. 71, p. 45 ; vol. 73, p. 459; vol. 74, p. 590. 
Birmingham, Alabama. 
State and City Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 

April 13, 1901, p. 171. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 61, p. 338. 
Cairo, Illinois. 
State and City Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 
April 1897, p. 97. 
Dallas County, Missouri. 
State and City Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 

April 29, 1893, p. 113. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 69, p. 1074; vol. 87, p. 1039; 
vol. 90, p. 63; vol. 94, p. 1263; vol. 96, p. 1241; vol. 98, p. 626. 
Elizabeth, New Jersey. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 28, p. 146; vol. 29, pp. 120, 
277, and 563; vol. 30, p. 589; vol. 32, pp. 231, 253, 312, and 368; 
vol. 35, p. 602; vol. 37, p. 342; vol. 39, p. 581; vol. 40, p. 625; vol. 
42, p. 93; vol. 46, p. 828; vol. 47, p. so. 
Evansville, Indiana. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 41, pp. 494 and 527; vol. 43, 
p. 607; vol. 44, p. 335; vol. 45, p. 112. 
Fort Worth, Texas. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 

1914, p. 195- 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 66, p. 775; vol. 67, p. 1072; 

vol. 69, p. 711; vol. 72, p. 100; vol. 76, p. 223; vol. 79, p. 1291. 
Galveston, Texas. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 

1914, p. 195. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 71, p. 564; vol. 73, p. 1275; 

vol. 74, p. 1102. 



302 APPENDIX 

Green County, Kentucky. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 

1908, p. 163. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 77, p. 48; vol. 78, p. 1234; 

vol. 81, p. 1059; vol. 84, p. 949; vol. 96, p. 1507. 
Macon County, Missouri. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, Nov. 26, 

1904, p. 2354. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May, 

1908, p. 124. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 79, p. 1352; vol. 80, p. 179; 

vol. 92, p. 1191; vol. 93, p. 548. 
Memphis, Tennessee. 
Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, January 

26, 1878, p. 10; July 28, 1888, p. 10. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 18, p. 526; vol. 25, p. 114; 

vol. 27, p. 678; vol. 28^ pp. 121 and 173; vol. 31, p. 328; vol. 32, 

p. 70; vol. 34, p. 604; vol. 36, p. 221; vol. 37, p. 202; vol. 38, p. 509; 

vol. 39, p. 727. 
Middleshoro, Kentucky. 

Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 84, p. 404. 
Mobile, Alabama. 
Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, February 

26, 1876, p. 10; May 31, 1879, p. 10; February 25, 1882, p. ii; July 

30, 1887, p. 10. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 16, p. 661; vol. 17, p. 19; 

vol. 21, p. 302; vol. 25, p. 382; vol. 28, pp. 224 and 327; vol. 29, 

P- 374- 
Mt. Vernon, Indiana. 

Commercial and Financial Chronicle, voL 39, p. 383. 
Nebraska City (Otoe County), Nebraska. 
State and City Section, Camtnercial and Financial Chronide, May 30, 

1914, p. 131. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 72, p. 302. 
New Orleans, Louisiana. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 27, pp. 228 and 628; vol. 28, 
p. 352; vol. 30, pp. 466, 494, and 650; vol. 31, pp. 606-07; vol. 35, 
pp. so and 763; vol. 47, pp. 50 and 17a. 
Pittsburg, Pennsylvania. 
Commercial and Financial Chronide, vol. 13, p. 242; vol. 24, pp. 519 
and 591 ; vol. 28, p. 302. 
St. Clair County, Missouri. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 30, 
1914, p. 124. 



APPENDIX 303 

Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 66, p. 819; vol. 89, p. 1293. 
St. Joseph, Missouri. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 23, pp. 135 and 175; vol. 25, 

p. 408; vol. 28, p. 477; vol. 32, p. 659; vol. 43, p. so. 
Savannah, Georgia. 
Investors' Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, January 

26, 1878, p. 13. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 25, pp. 41 and 382; vol. 26, 

pp. 18 and 625; vol. 27, pp. 123, 173, and 568. 
Superior, Wisconsin. 
State and City Supplement, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, 

April 10, 1897, p. no. 
State and City Section, Commercial and Financial Chronicle, May 28, 

1904, p. 2149. 
Commercial and Financial Chronicle, vol. 73, pp. 801 and 11 24; vol. 74, 

pp. no and 590; vol. 78, p. 1569; vol. 79, pp. 2107 and 2807; vol. 

93. P- 301- 



[Copy] 

THE SUPREME COURT 

OF KANSAS 

ToPEEA, Nov. 7, 1914. 
GooDALE & Nash, 
Boston, Mass. 
Deas Sirs: — 

Answering yours of the 3rd inst. beg to advise that the case you refer 
to was the case of Levison vs. Finney, No. 18934, and was never reported 
for the reason that the case never came to a final hearing on the matter 
of levying tax. At the time the application was made for the writ, this 
court held that it had jurisdiction to require the levy to be made and 
give the defendant time to answer raising any question it desired as to 
the vaUdity of the indebtedness; it also restrained the defendant from 
making any levy for the ciurrent year, but did not preclude the levy of a 
tax for the purpose indicated, subject to change on order of the court. 

Yours truly, 

D. A. Valentine, 

Clerk Supreme Court, 



RAILROAD LAWS 

LAWS rOEBIDDING COMBINATION AND CONSOLIDATION 

Massachusetts: Acts, 1907, chap. 585. 

Minnesota: General Laws, 1907, chap. 395. 

Oklahoma: Constitution of Oklahoma, adopted 1907, art. ix, sees. 8, 9. 

Pennsylvania: Laws of Pennsylvania, 1907, nos. 254 and 281. 

Utah: Laws of Utah, 1907, chap. 93, sec. 6. 

LAWS ORDERING CHANGES EST CONSTRUCTION OF ROAD OR 
ROLLING-STOCK 

Illinois: Laws of Illinois, 1907, p. 476 (safety appliances). 
Indiana: Acts, 1907, chap. 205 (block signak). 

Acts, 1907, chap. 118 (safety appliances). 
Kansas: Laws of Kansas, 1905, chap. 346; ibid., 1907, chap. 277. 
Michigan: Public Acts, 1907, chap. 312, sees. 13, 34 and 35; ibid., chap. 

234 (automatic couplers). 
Minnesota: General Laws, 1905, chaps. 208, 280. 

General Laws, 1907, chaps. 54, 202, 276, 333, 396. 
Missouri: Laws of Missouri, 1905, pp. 100, 106, 107. 

Laws of Missouri, 1907, pp. 181, 182 (safety appliances). 
Montana: Laws of Montana, 1905, chap. 29; ibid., 1907, chap. 59 
(cattle-guards and fences). 
Laws of Montana, 1907, chap. 54 (size of cabooses). 
New York: Laws of New York, 1907, chap. 208, p. 403 (steam-cocks, 

etc., on locomotives). 
North Dakota: Laws of North Dakota, 1907, chaps. 209, 210, 211. 
Ohio: Laws of Ohio, 1906, p. 342, act approved April 16, 1906, sec. 9; 

ibid., pp. 46, 75. 
South Carolina: Acts, 1906, no. 2. 
South Dakota: Session Laws, 1907, chap. 212. 
Texas: Laws of Texas, 1905, chaps. 56 and 133. 
Laws of Texas, 1907, chaps. 32 and 155. 
Virginia: Acts of Assembly, 1906, chaps. 298 and 302. 
Vermont: Laws of Vermont, 1906, no. 118, sees. 18 and 27; nos. 119 and 

120. '-"i 

Washington: Laws of Washington, 1905, chap. 164, sec. 10 (spark- 
arresters). ' 



306 APPENDIX 

Washington: Laws of Washington, 1907, chap. 138, and chap. 226, 

sees. 13-14 (safety appliances). 
Wisconsin: Laws of Wisconsin, 1905, chap. 264, sec. 17, chap. 348. 
Laws of Wisconsin, 1907, chap. 595. 

LAWS SHORTENING HOURS OF LABOR 

Connecticut: Public Acts, 1907, chap. 242. 
Indiana: Acts, 1905, chap. 169, sec. 674. 

Acts, 1907, chap. 131. 
Iowa: Laws of Iowa, 1907, chap. 163. 
Kansas: Laws of Kansas, 1905, chap. 342. 
Laws of Kansas, 1907, chap. 280. 
Minnesota: General Laws, 1907, chap. 253. 
Missouri: Act approved March 25, 1905. 
Laws of Missouri, 1905, p. 112. 
Montana: Laws of Montana, 1907, chap. 5. 
New York: Laws of New York, 1907, chaps. 523 and 627. 
Nevada: Statutes, 1907, chap. 186. 
North Carolina: PubUc Laws, 1907, chap. 456. 
North Dakota: Laws of North Dakota, 1907, chap. 207. 
Oregon: General Laws, 1905, chap. 143. 
South Dakota: Session Laws, 1907, chap. 220. 
Texas: General Laws, 1907, chap. 51. 
Washington: Laws of Washington, 1907, chap. 20. 
West Virginia: Acts, 1907, chap. 59. 
Wisconsin: Laws of Wisconsin, 1907, chaps. 575 and 655. 

LAWS HELD TTNCONSTITUnONAL 

Among railroad regulative laws that have been held to be unconsti- 
tutional, the following may be mentioned: — 

Laws of Wisconsin, 1907, chap. 266, p. 402: providing that an upper 
berth in a sleeping-car shall, when unoccupied, be closed at the option 
of the occupant of the lower berth.- State v. Redmon, 134 Wis. 89, 114 
N.W. 137. 
Laws of Alabama, 1907, p. 711: fixing maximum freight and passenger 
rates on business within the State, and providing that on violation the 
railroad company and its agents should be liable respectively to pen- 
alty and to criminal prosecution, so that a railroad could not test the 
validity of the statute without risk of bankruptcy. Central of Georgia 
Railway Co. et al v. Railroad Commission of Alabama, 161 Fed. Rep. 

925- 
Laws of North Dakota, 1907, chap. 199, p. 327: providing for a maximimi 



APPENDIX 307 

passenger rate of two and one half cents per mile and further providing 
for mileage books at two cents per mile, good for purchaser and such 
adult members of his family as he may designate. This latter provi- 
sion was held invalid as being discriminatory. State v. Great Northern 
Railway Company, 17 N.D. 370, 116 N.W. 89. 

Laws (Washington), 1905, p. 238, sec. 2: arbitrarily fixing the weight of 
standards for limiber cars at one thousand pounds, and requiring such 
weight to be deducted from the net weight of the limiber on all car- 
loads received for shipment, regardless of the actual weight of such 
-standards. State v. Great Northern Railway Company, 43 Wash. 658, 
86 Pac. 1056. 

Acts of Assembly (Virginia), 1906, chap. 256: fixing a maximum rate for 
mileage books not applicable to passenger fares generally. Common- 
wealth V. Atlantic Coast Line Railway Company, 106 Va. 61, 55 S.E. 
572. 

Session Laws (Nebraska), 1905, chap. 105, sees, i and 6: requiring rail- 
road to build switches at request of owner of elevator and providing 
no compensation. Missouri Pacific Railway Company v. Nebraska, 
217 U.S. 196. 

Laws (Illinois), 1907, p. 746: fixing maximum passenger fares so low'as 
to involve confiscation. Trust Company of America s. Chicago Pacific 
and St. Louis Railway Company, 199 Fed. Rep. 593. 

Acts (West Virginia), 1907, chap. 41 : fii^g maximum passenger fares so 
low as to be confiscatory. Coal and Coke Railway Company v. Conley 
et al, 67 W.Va. 129, 67 S.E. 613. 

The above are merely typical examples and by no means a complete 
list of such cases. 



3o8 



APPENDIX 



s 



^^1 



^00 H « ^ 



+ 1 I l + l + + +1 I +1 + 1 I 



C* H 

M n 

M 
1 + 



-^tOf*) too H H Ot 

^ »!« ' M to « C< 

I I I-H-+I I 



il 



HMHHMH MIIM M>HM 



H M M M ^ 
0> OOl Ol Ol 






HHHMHHHH 



CO *0 to PO (O ^ *0 to to *0 TO to 



M ^ to to *0 
H H H H M 

Qi Oi 9 O O 



to to 

M H 



toto^tototototo 









RAaaA 









en 

w 



o 
(J 












Si 8 I 



r«.0 ■<^ lo t» to 

q M « foo •* 

* 4-0 *d looo 

M « et H 



ssss 



+ 1 + 1 I I +1+ +1+ +111 +1 MM M 



eaters 111 111 1215 11 S"^'o %% "8 



Oi 0> 9 Oi C 






M O W 



l^llll 



QQQ 



£i^ 






Pl^ 



8adg 



o4 



®iSl 



^H to M>0 to 

«q q ^ 



++ + I +1+ 



« M H 

I 1 + 



d to ; 

• MM 

++I 



I I+++ 



ig 



H M M M 



g'S'3' 



V) -4- -^ 



MMM H MHMM 



g.a -a :a 



ff ff ff 3" ff 5* 

& Ot Oi Oi Q> O 



^ to ^ to *^ tO ^ to 



lia I s 



QQQ |S;^Q 






s a,l § e 2 








I 







%i 






•C EW -ftio 






jj'^^b-cowS.gg.o.s 
iple'B'E'sllii 



soa 



I 









APPENDIX 



309 



in 



O 
U 






o 

o 
1^ 












1+1+ I I I +1 



^ Wl ^ ^ »0 

M H M M l-l 

O* Oi Oi 0» Oi 



"> ^ CO t^ 

o> o> o> o> 






< O Q 



too 

Old 






. H CO 



I 1+ + + I 



OiCO c 

00c 



00 t^CO 

000 



t* fcpj ^ 

< s p 



+++ + + I 



irt Tf m V) 

Sd 81 s 

^ CO ^ /? (? ^ 

' Oi & c> o> o> Ot 



u 'S 

das §"g,s y 



S= 



1.1 







ZPh 



I.2|.5.S| 



|w.al 



■^■a<3|S^ 






CO - >o " 
Choooo - 



CO 2"^- H 

w - . ■* 
VO 10 Q, ■* 

O.'iS'T; »0 



fSK 



■5 I =■ 

cd O ui 

§. '-' I 
©■=. -^^.B 
it ||w 

« a «> o b>; 
10 ■* ■* ■^ if ■* ■* 

O . H M M W M Q 

Oo OiOiOiO>OiOi 

Mb H H H M M W 
fiOO CO"'-'"'"' 

njoo cd Ed 



.S 
'O ft) m 

III 

§11 
a ai' 



•^ 00 10 iv -^ nj ™ iu TO i« iv , n " - 

O. > g _ 10 Oi*» aO.OiOiO.Oirto£r? 



Oi fO ■ - Oi . _ "* , _ 

r* f~ C'oo o," K.S 2 

Tt-io •-■ Ol 



ri'o s ooS'^- 
> 2 -»"0= "^ *-* 






U 
u 

u 

a 
ft) 



1.8 



la -^ 

if! •§'3 .a 



$~ S« S5 i c oj- tl 




a coS "2 &*^ o>o.&o»s o." Oct" 



- ■;.« ".a """"£"00 

-■ -'^ n'S o a a d-o a ,n a a «, 



~ 3" ^ C03 



g, "^ ^,00 g 5. a a O* O. Oil" O..SJ' o. o>;« 
H tOOOpCl 



INDEX 



Accounts, supervision of public-service 
coiporation, by state commissions, 232. 

Alabama, debt history of, 122-124. 

American investments in foreign countries, 
70-71. 

American securities held abroad, 6^-70. 

Anglo-French dollar loan, 88-91. 

Argentine Republic, special security for 
certain bonds of, 5. 

Arkansas, debt history of, 109-110. 

Assessed valuation: for all States, 1912- 
1913, 98, 99; percentage of debt to as- 
sessed valuation for all the States, 98, 
99; relation between true value of prop- 
erty and, 98; of counties and incor- 
porated places, 141. 

Assessments: in railroad reorganizations, 
186, 188-191 ; in public-service reorgani- 
zations, 246-248; in industrial reorgani- 
zations, 290-291. 

Assets offsetting national debts, 17-19. 

Atchison, Kansas, attempted bad faith by, 

1SS> 304. 

Atchison, Topeka & Santa F£ Railroad 
Company: causes of failure of, 167; 
siunmary of reorganization of, 187; 
foreclosure price compared with debt 
of, 187; what security-holders received 
in reorganization of, 188; market value 
of new securities received in reorganiza- 
tion of, 193. 

Austria-Hungary: price of Austrian and 
Hungarian bonds 1913, 7; racial origin 
of, 9; outline of history of, 13; popula- 
tion, wealth and debt of, 15-17; assets 
offsetting national debt of, 18; national 
debt charge compared with national in- 
come, 20; national debt charge com- 
pared with total government expendi- 
ture, 21; growth in population of, 22, 23; 
growth in wealth of, 24-25; increase in 
debt of, 27, 29; debt history of, 39-40; 
form of government in, 62; character of 
population of, 63; military position of, 
64; economic position of, 65; foreign 



commerce of, 67, 68; position of, among 
nations, 73; prices of Austrian rentes, 
77; cost of present war to, 76, 78; total 
losses of present war to, up to July 31, 
1915, 79; war loans put out since begin- 
ning of present war up to October 23, 
1915, 82, 83; war prices of govermnent 
bonds, 91, 92; state-operated railways 
in, 176. 

Bad faith, cases of, 155; attempt at, by 
Atchison, Kansas, 155, 304. 

Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Company: 
causes of failure of, 167; summary of 
reorganization of, 187; what security- 
holders received in reorganization of, 
191; market value of new securities re- 
ceived in reorganization of, 193. 

Banking business, ix, 65, 68. 

Banking commissions, 68. 

Bohvia, government loans in default, 59. 

Bond business in the United States, z. 

Bond investment, framework of, 3. 

Bonding, of industrial concerns, 237. 

Bonds: investment in, a modem develop- 
ment, ix; as a channel of investment, i; 
what they represent, 3; principal classes 
of investment, 3 ; the two great markets 
for, 3 ; framework of bond investment, 3 ; 
safety of , 3-4; United States and for- 
eign government, 5-93; state, 94-139; 
county, municipal, and district, 140- 
161; special assessment, 140; steam- 
railroad, 162-197; public-service cor- 
poration, 198-250; industrial, 251-294; 
municipal refunding, 150; first mort- 
gage, 162; consolidated mortgage, 162; 
general mortgage, 162; debenture, 162; 
plain, 162; income, 162; convertible, 
162; equipment, 162-163; collateral 
trust, 162-163; terminal, 163; guaran- 
teed, 163. 

Boston Sliding Scale Act, 206. 

Bulgaria, special security for certain 
bonds of, 5-6. 



312 



INDEX 



California: debt history of, 112-113; fa- 
vorable factors affecting credit of, 137; 
joint use of facilities by public-service 
corporations in, 216; California Com- 
mission on determining fair value as a 
basis for rates, 221; local regulation of 
public-service corporations in, 233. 

Capitalization : of American and European 
railways compared, 194; gross and net, 
of all railroads, 197; regulation of pub- 
lic-service, by state commissions, 230- 
232; total, in industrial and railroad 
reorganizations, 289-290. 

Certificates of public convenience and ne- 
cessity, of public-service corporations, 
209, 212-213; conditions regulating is- 
suance of, 213. 

Certification: of state bonds, 131; of 
county, municipal, and district bonds, 
157-158. 

Chicago City Railway Company, fran- 
chise of, 206. 

Chicago Railways Company, franchise of, 
206. 

Chicago Union Traction Company, re- 
organization of , 241, 243, 244, 246, 248. 

Circuit Coiurt of Appeals: jurisdiction of, 
in enforcement of Clayton Act, 272; 
appeal from Federal Trade Commission 
to, 273. 

Civilization, changes in leadership of, 9- 
10. 

Clayton Anti-Trust Law: enactment of 
the, 267; leading provisions of the, 268- 
269; amplifies and supplements the 
Sherman Anti-Trust Law, 269-270; in 
regard to exports, 270; holding com- 
panies, 270; interlocking directorates, 
271; personal-guilt clause in the, 271; 
machinery of enforcement of the, 271- 
272; simmiary of the, 272. 

Cleveland Railway Company, franchise 
of, 206-207. 

Colombia, government loans in default, 
59- 

Combination: forms of, 258-239; econom- 
ic advantages of, 259-260; disadvan- 
tages of, 260-261; successful and im- 
successful large-scale operation, 261; 
distinction between advantages and 
disadvantages of, and monopoly control, 
261; motives for, 262; advantages of 
corporate form of, 262. 



Commission form of government, 157. 

Commissions: regulation by state, of 
public-service corporations, 207-233; 
modem public-service, 208, 209, 210- 
212; present state, having jurisdiction 
over street-railway, gas, electric-light 
and power or telephone companies, 209, 
210-212; leading principles of regula- 
tion of publicrservice corporations by 
state, 209, 212-232; authority of, over 
rates of public-service corporations,2i8; 
authority of, to approve or disapprove 
issue of public-service securities, 230- 
232; judicial review ofjdedsions by state 
commissions, 232-233. 

Competition: railroad, 164-165, 166, 256; 
public-service corporation, 256; govern- 
ing factor in existence of industrial con- 
cerns, 256; saving of the wastes of, 260; 
monopoly control and, 267; potential 
and effective, 267; imfair mediods of, 
272-273, 275-276; three sources of pos- 
sible, in failure of industrial concerns, 
286. 

Consolidated mortgage bonds, 162. 

Consolidations: attitude of state com- 
missions toward public-service corpora- 
tion, 213-214; basis on which, are per- 
mitted in various States, 214; purposes 
of industrial promotions and, 284. 

Constitutional limitations in regard to 
creation and payment of state debt, 
129-131; of local debt, 143-152. 

Convertible bonds, 162. 

Corporations: various classes of public- 
service, 198; origin and development of 
bu^ess done by public-service, 199- 
202; points of similarity in different 
classes of public-service, 202; rate of 
return on capital invested in public- 
service, 219; broad relation of public- 
service, to the people, 238-239; develop- 
ment of, as a means of carrying on 
business, 251-252; fluctuating nature of 
business done by industrial, 252; net 
earnings of some leading industrial, 252- 
255; competitive nature of business 
done by industrial, 256; importance of 
good management of industrial, 256- 
257; question as to whether competitive 
industrial, should be bonded, 257; con- 
ditions which may furnish proper basis 
for bonding of industrial, 257-258; ad- 



INDEX 



313 



vantages to industrial concerns in com- 
bining in form of, 262; subject to pub- 
lic control, 262; suggestion of federal 
incorporation of industrial, 283-284; 
causes of failure in special cases of in- 
dustrial, 287-288; caretakenin bonding 
of industrial, 286-289. 

Costa Rica, government loans in default, 
59- 

Cost of service as a basis for rates, 218- 
219. 

Cost of war: to leading nations involved, 
76-77, 78-81; comparison of present, 
with that of previous wars, 80. 

County bonds: definition of, 140; meansof 
recovery on defaulted, 140; factors gov- 
erning safety of, 140-141, 152-153, i57; 
laws in regard to issue of, in Massachu- 
setts, 143-146; comparison of Massachu- 
setts laws with those of other States in 
regard to issue of, 146-152; purposes of 
issue of, 148-150; issue of, for improper 
or tmwise purposes, 149-150; length of 
time which bonds may run, 150-151; 
vote of people to authorize, 151; pay- 
ment of, by sinking-fund or serial meth- 
od, 151; amount and character of popu- 
lation important factors in safety of, 
i5?-iS3; record of, 153-157, 297-303; 
causes of default in, 154-155, 297-303; 
settlements made with bondholders on 
defaulted, 155-156, 297-303; legality of 
issue and certification as to genuineness, 
157-158; safety of, 161. 

Credit: of nations shown by prices of their 
bonds, 7, 8; bearing of historical devel- 
opment on, 15; certain factors deter- 
mining national, 15, 58, 63-71; normal 
conditions vs. the war, 15; most impor- 
tant factor in estimating national, 58; 
considerations in estimating state, 94- 
95, 132-137; summary of factors bear- 
ing on state, 137. 

Creditor nations, 65-70. 

Debenture bonds: definition, 162; reme- 
dies for non-payment of, 163. 

Pebt: of leading civilized nations, 15-17; 
percentage of national, to resources, 16; 
assets offsetting national, 17-19; bur- 
den of national, 19; comparison of na- 
tional debt charge with national income, 
19, 20; coinp&rigon of S3.tiQnaJ debt 



charge with total government expendi- 
ture, 19, 21; increases in national, 26-29; 
changes in national, charges, 29-30; 
debt histories of leading nations, 30-57; 
summary of national, histories, 57-58; 
war, 81-84; debt statements of various 
States, 95-97; percentage of net, to as- 
sessed valuation for all the States, 98, 
99; changes in total of state, 1790-1913, 
98-100, 101; reason for comparative 
freedom of our States from, 100; impor- 
tance of state history of, 100; debt his- 
tories of all defaulting States, 100-128; 
summary of state debt histories, 128- 
129; provisions for debt-making in state 
constitutions, 1 29-131; proportion of 
net, to assessed valuation, 141; of coun- 
ties and incorporated places, 141; of ten 
largest cities in the United States, 141- 
142; quasi-municipal debt-creating cor- 
porations, 142-143; burden of, on local 
communities, 142-143 ; constitutional 
and statutory provisions in regard to 
local, 143-152; comparison of Massa- 
chusetts laws with those of other States 
in regard to local, 146-152; position of 
the legislature in regard to local, 146- 
147; limitations on local, 147-148; ex- 
ceptions in regard to creation of local, 
147-148; limiting and removing tax 
limit, 148; methods of paying local, 151; 
incre^e in local, 1890, 1892, and 1913, 
158-159; local, 1913, 159; local, in Great 
Britain, France, and Germany, 159; 
proportions between local, state, and 
national, 159; relation of, to assets of 
steam railroads, 163; ratio of, to assets 
of public-service corporations, 203; 
amount of plant and of quick assets of 
industrial concerns compared with, 258. 

Debt charges: comparison with national 
incomes, 19-20; comparison with total 
government expenditures, 19, 21; 
changes in, 29-30. 

Debt history: of leading nations, 30-57; 
of France, 30-33; Great Britain, 34-39; 
Austria-Himgary, 39-40; United States, 
41-49; Russia, 49-51; Italy, 51-52; 
Germany, 52-55; Japan, 55-57; sum- 
mary of national, 57-58; government 
loans in default, 58, 59; importance of 
state, 100; of all defaulting States, 100- 
1^8;, of Fennsylv9,nia, 103; Maryland, 



314 



INDEX 



103-104; Indiana, 104-105; Illinois, 
10S-106; Michigan, 106-107; Florida, 
107-108; Mississippi, 108-109; Arkan- 
sas, 109-110; Minnesota, iio-iii; 
Texas, 111-112; California, 11 2-1 13; 
Virginia, 114-117; West Virginia, 117- 
118; North Carolina, 118-119; South 
Carolina, 119-121; Georgia, 121-122; 
Alabama, 122-124; Tennessee, 124-125; 
Louisiana, 125-127; Missouri, 127-128; 
of New York, i28;Ohio, i28;Massachu- 
setts, 128; summary of state, 128-129. 

Debtor nations, 65-70. 

Default: collection of government bonds 
in, 6; nations in default in 1874, 57; 
loans of independent governments in, 
between 1877 and 1912, 58, 59; collec- 
tion of state bonds in, 94; three periods 
of, of state bonds, 100-129; first period 
of, of state bonds, 100, 102-110; second 
period of, of state bonds, 100, 110-113; 
third period of, of state bonds, loo-ioi; 
113-128; means of recovery on county, 
municipal, and district bonds in, 140; 
causes of, in county, municipal, and dis- 
trict bonds, 154-155; settlements made 
with bondholders on defaulted county, 
municipal, and district bonds, 155-156, 
297-303; remedies for collection of rail- 
road bonds in, 163; railroad bonds in, 
165. 

Depreciation: general rule for treatment 
of, in estimating fair value, 224-225; 
treatment of, under various circum- 
stances, 225; summary of, question, 
225-226; United States Supreme Court 
on, 226. 

District bonds: definition, 140; means of 
recovery on defaulted, 140; factors gov- 
erning safety of , 140-141, 152-153, 157; 
laws in regard to issue of, in Massa- 
chusetts, 143-146; comparison of Massa- 
chusetts laws with those of other States 
in regard to issue of, 146-152; purposes 
of issue of, 148-150; issue of, for im- 
proper or unwise purposes, 149-150; 
length of time which bonds may run, 
150-15 1 ; vote of people to authorize, 
151; payment of, by sinking-fund or 
serial method, 151; amount and char- 
acter of population important factors in 
safety of, 152-153; record of, 153-157; 
causes of default in, 154-155; settle- 



ments made with bondholders on de- 
faulted, 155-156; legality of issue and 
certification as to genuineness, 157-158; 
safety of, 161. 

District Courts, jurisdiction of, in enforce- 
ment of the Federal Trade Conmiission 
Law, 275. 

Domestic commerce of the United States, 
66. 

Earnings: railroad, 169-170, 239; stability 
of gross, of public-service corporations, 
239; net, of public-service corporations, 
240; net, of industrial concerns, 252- 
256, 308-309. 

Economic position, of nations, 64-65. 

Ecuador, government loans in default, 59. 

Electric Ught and power, origin and devel- 
opment of, industry, 200-201. 

Electric railways, origin and development 
of, 199-200. 

Elizabefi, New Jersey, default by, 154, 
156, 297, 301. 

England, early goverrmient borrowing in, 
ix-x; development of, 10. See Great 
Britain. 

Equipment bonds, 162-163. 

Expenditure: debt charge compared with 
government, 19, 21; government, ne- 
cessity for reduced, after the war, 85-86. 

Failures: of railroads, 165-168; of public- 
service corporations, 240-248; of indus- 
trial concerns, 285-288. 

Fair value of property, 219, 220, 222. 

Federal licensing or incorporation of rail- 
roads, 172-173; of industrial corpora- 
tions, 283-284. 

Federal Trade Commission: make-up of, 
272; power of, to prevent unfair methods 
of competition, 272-273; appeal to de- 
cision of Circuit Court of Appeals from, 
273; other powers and duties of the, 
273-275; comparison of, with Inter- 
state Commerce Commission, 276-277; 
comparison of certain functions of, 
with the action of a master in chancery, 
277; general powers and functions of 
the, 277-278; relation between the, and 
the Department of Justice, 278; pub- 
licity features, 278-279; policy of the, 
as outlined by Chairman Davies, 279; in 
a position to do constructive work, 279- 



INDEX 



3IS 



280; precedents and analogies for the, 
280; new Federal Trade Commission 
Law substitutes regulation by, for regu- 
lation by lawsuit, 280. 

Federal Trade Commission Law: enact- 
ment of the, 267-268, 272; leading pro- 
visions of the, 272-275; publicity 
features of the, 278-279; criticisms of 
the, 281-282. 

Financial stability depends on the people, 

132, 139, 153- 

First-mortgage bonds: definition of, 162; 
remedies for non-payment of, 163. 

Fixed charges: in railroad reorganizations, 
186; in public-service reorganizations, 
247-248; in industrial reorganizations, 
290. 

Florida, debt history of, 107-108. 

Foreclosure price, in railroad reorganiza- 
tions, 187, 192; relation between, and 
value of railroad property, 187, 192; in 
pubUc-service reorganizations, 241, 243, 
246; in industrial reorganizations, 290. 

Foreign commerce of leading nations, 66- 
68. 

Foreign or colonial investments: of Great 
Britain, 65, 68-69, 7°j 88-8g, 90; of 
France, 65, 70, 72, 88-89, 9°; of Ger- 
many, 70; of the United States, 70-71. 

Foreign remittances, 68, 69. 

France: early government borrowing in, 
ix; early local loans in, x; government 
bonds of, s; prices of French rentes, 1913, 
7; racial origin of, 9; outUne of history 
of, lo-ii; population, wealth, and debt 
of, 15-17; assets offsetting national debt 
of, 18; national debt charge compared 
with national income, 19, 20; national 
debt charge compared with total gov- 
ernment expenditure, 19, 21; growth 
in population of, 21, 22, 23; growth in 
wealth of, 24, 25, 26; increase in national 
income of, 26; increase in debt of, 27, 29; 
debt history of, 30-33; form of govern- 
ment in, 60; character of population of, 
63; military position of, 64; economic 
position of, 65 ; foreign commerce of , 67, 
68; foreign investments of, 65, 70, 72, 
88-89, 9°) position of, among nations, 
72; prices of French rentes, 74, 75, 76, 
77; cost of present war to, 76, 78; total 
losses of present war to July 31, 1915, 
79; war loans put out since beginning of 



present war up to October 23, 1915, 82, 
83; war prices of French bonds, 91-92; 
Anglo-French dollar loan, 88-91; state 
operated railways in, 174, 176; regula- 
tion of railways in, 177-178. 

Franchises: description of public-service 
corporation, 204; burdensome restric- 
tions in public-service corporation, 204- 
205; length of public-service corpora- 
tion, 205; revocable licenses or indeter- 
minate permits, 205; consent of local 
authorities to installation of property, 
205; difficulties in bringing about solu- 
tion of franchise question, 205 ; best kind 
of, 205-206; of Chicago City Railways 
and Chicago Railways, 206; of Cleve- 
land Railway, 206-207; interesting 
franchise arrangements, 206-207; pub- 
he-service corporation, said to exist to 
enable bankers to sell bonds, 212; fran- 
chise value, 228-229. 

Freights, 68, 69, 70. 

Funds: investment of, difficult, i; when 
they should be invested, 1. See Sinking 
funds. 

Galveston, Texas, default by, 155, 299- 
300, 301. 

Gas industry, origin and development of, 
199, 200. 

General mortgage bonds: definition of, 
162; remedies for non-payment of, 163. 

Georgia, debt history of, 121-122. 

Germany: government bonds of, 5; prices 
of German bonds, 1913, 7; racial origin 
of, 9; outline of history of, 11-12; pop- 
ulation, wealth, and debt of, 15-17; 
assets offsetting national debt of, 17- 
18; national debt charge compared with 
national income, 20; national debt 
charge compared with total govern- 
ment expenditure, 21; growth in popu- 
lation of, 22, 23; growth in wealth of, 
24, 25, 26; increase in national income 
of, 26; increase in debt of, 27, 29; debt 
history of, 52-55; form of government 
in, 61-62; character of population of, 
63; military position of, 64, 72; eco- 
nomic position of, 65 ; foreign commerce 
of, 67, 68; foreign investments of, 70; 
position of, among nations, 72-73; 
prices of Prussian consols, 1880-1912, 
77; cost of present war to, 76, 78, 79; 



3i6 



INDEX 



total losses of present war up to July 31, 
igiS, 79; war loans put out since be- 
ginning of present war up to October 
23, 191S, 82, 83; war prices of German 
bonds, 91, 92; state-operated railways 
in, 174, 175-176; municipal ownership 
and operation of public utilities in, 235, 
236. 

Going concern value, 227-228. 

Government: early, loans, ix; early, bor- 
rowing in France, England, and the 
United States, ix-x; forms of, of leading 
nations, 58, 60-63; commission form of, 

IS7- 

Government bonds: description of, 5; how 
payable, 5; of United States, Great 
Britain, France, and Germany, 5; spe- 
cial security for some, 5-6; no method of 
collecting defaulted, 6; can be issued for 
any purpose, 6; prices of, 1913, 7; in de- 
fault, 58, S9; prices of British consols 
and French rentes, 74-75; prices of lead- 
ing, 1873-1912, 74, 76, 77; proper at- 
titude of American investors toward 
foreign, 87-88; war prices of, 91-93; 
summary of factors entering into values 
and prices of, 93. 

Government ownership of railroads: 173- 
176; two forms of, 173; extent of, 174; 
arguments in favor of, 174-175; argu- 
ments against, 175; results of, 175-176. 

Great Britain and Ireland: government 
bonds of, 5; price of British consols, 
1913, 7; racial origin of, 9; development 
of, 10; population, wealth, and debt of, 
15-17; assets offsetting national debt 
of, 17; national debt charge compared 
with national income, 20; national debt 
charge compared with total government 
expenditure, 21; growth in population 
of, 20-21, 22, 23; growth in wealth of, 
23, 25, 26; increase in national income 
of, 26; increase in debt of, 27, 29; debt 
history of, 34-39; form of government 
in, 60; character of population of, 63; 
military position of, 64; economic posi- 
tion of, 65; foreign commerce of, 67, 68; 
colonial and foreign investments of, 
65, 68-69, 7°> 88-89, 90; position of, 
among nations, 72 ; prices of British con- 
sols, 74, 75, 76, 77; cost of present war 
to, 76, 78; total losses of present war up 
to July 31, 1915, 79; war loans put out 



since beginning of war up to October 23, 
1915, 81-82; war prices of British bonds, 
91, 92; Anglo-French dollar loan, 88- 
91; regulation of railways in, 177; muni- 
cipal ownership and operation of public 
utilities in, 235, 236. 
Greece: special security for certain bonds 
of, 6; government loans in default, 1877, 

59- 
Gross earnings: of railroads, 165, 239; of 

pubUc-service corporations, 239. 
Guatemala, government loans in default, 

S9- 

Historical development: United States, 
10; Great Britain, 10; France, ro-ii; 
Germany, 11-12; Italy, 12-13; Austria- 
Hungary, 13; Russia, 13-14; Japan, 14- 
15; bearing of, on credit, 15. 

Holding companies: public service, 198; 
industrial, 268-269, 270. 

Honduras, government loans in default, 

59- 
Hudson River Electric Power Company, 

reorganization of, 243, 245-246, 248. 
Hungary. See Austria-Hungary. 

lUinois, debt history of, 105-106; favor- 
able factors affecting credit of, 137. 

Income: national, jg, 20, 26; of railroads, 
170. 

Income bonds, 162. 

Incorporation, federal: of railroads, 172- 
173; of industrial concerns, 283-284. 

Indiana: debt history of, 104-105; fran- 
chises in, 205. 

Industrial bonds: definition of, 251; de- 
velopment of the issue of, 251-252; 
most important factor in safety of, 256- 
257; should be issued in serial form or 
have sinking fund, 258; necessary to 
consider each issue of, 292; examples of 
strong, 292-293; prices of leading, 1914, 
293-294; effect of European war on,294; 
care required in selection of, for invest- 
ment, 294. 

Industrial concerns: origin and develop- 
ment of, 251-252; fluctuating nature of 
business done by, 252; net earnings of 
some leading, 252-256, 308-309; com- 
petitive nature of business done by, 256 ; 
importance of good management of, 
256-257; question as to whether com- 



INDEX 



317 



petitive, should be bonded, 257; condi- 
tions which may furnish proper basis 
for bonding of, 257; plant and quick 
assets compared with debt of, 258; rela- 
tion of great, to the public, 258; com- 
bination of, 258-259; origin of the 
"trust" question, 259; large-scale opera- 
tion and monopoly control by, 261, 284- 
285; Sherman Anti-Trust Law, 262- 
267; Clajfton Anti-Trust Law, 267-272; 
suggestion of federal incorporation of, 
283-284; failureof earnings tomeetesti- 
mates, 285; various degrees of failure of, 
285 ; leading business causes of failure of, 
285; proportion between tangible assets 
and total capitalization, 285; sources of 
possible competition, 286; direct cause 
of failure of many, 286; causes of failure 
of certain large, 286, 287-288; bonding 
of, 286-289; general conditions neces- 
sary to success of, 289; reorganizations 
of, 289-292; total capitalization in re- 
organizations of, 289-290; fixed charges 
in reorganizations of, 290; treatment of 
bondholders in reorganizations of, 290; 
table showing sacrifices made by bond- 
holders in certain reorganizations of, 
291; summary of reorganizations of, 292. 

Interborough Rapid Transit Company 
agreement, 207; made effective only 
through public-service commission, 207. 

Interest on foreign capital, 68, 69, 70, 90. 

Interstate Commerce Commission: estab- 
lishment of, 168; increase in powers of, 
168-169; unable to handle problem of 
railway regulation, 178; federal valua- 
tion of all railroads under auspices of, 
181 ; comparison of Federal Trade Com- 
mission with the, 276-277. 

Investment: in bonds a modem develop- 
ment, be; of funds diflScult, 1; leading 
channels of, i; three principal kinds of, 
1; funds should be invested when re- 
ceived, i; framework of bond, 3; muni- 
cipal bonds among safest mediums of, 
161; selection of industrial bonds for, 
requires great care, 294. 

Investments: colonial and foreign, of 
Great Britain, 65, 68-69, 7°, 88-89, 90; 
of France, 65, 70, 72, 88-89, 90; of Ger- 
many, 70; of the United States, 70-71. 

Invisible trade balance, 68-71; colonial 
and foreign investments of nations, 68- 



71; Interest, tourist expenditures, re- 
mittances to friends, freights, 69; 
American securities held abroad, 69- 
70; lending countries, 70. 

Issue of securities: conflict of authority in 
approval of, by railroads, 170; federal 
supervision of the, by railroads, 179- 
180; authority of commissions to ap- 
prove or disapprove, 230-232; in New 
York State, 230-231; wisdom of com- 
mission control of the, 231-232; pub- 
licity method of control of the, 232. 

Italy: price of Italian bonds, 1913, 7; 
racial origin of, 9; outline of history of, 
12-13; population, wealth, and debt of, 
15-17; assets offsetting national debt 
of, 18; national debt charge of, 20; na- 
tional debt charge compared with total 
government expenditure, 21; growth in 
population of, 22, 23; growth in wealth 
of, 24, 25; increase in debt of, 27, 29; 
debt history of, 51-52; form of govern- 
ment in, 60-61 ; military position of, 64; 
economic position of, 65; foreign com- 
merce of, 67, 68; position of, among na- 
tions, 73; prices of Italian rentes, 77; 
war loans put out by, since beginning of 
present war up to October 23, 1915, 82, 
83; war prices of Italian bonds, 91, 92; 
state-operated railways in, 176; muni- 
cipal ownership and operation of public 
utilities in, 236. 

Japan: special seciuity for certain bonds 
of, 5; prices of Japanese bonds, 1913, 7; 
racial origin of, 9; outline of history of, 
14-15; population, wealth, and debt of, 
15-17; assets offsetting national debt of, 
18; national debt charge of, 20; national 
debt charge compared with total gov- 
ernment expenditure, 19, 21; growth in 
population of, 23; increase in debt of, 
27, 29; debt history of, 55-57; form of 
government in, 62-63 j character of pop- 
ulation of, 63; military position of, 64; 
economic position of, 65; foreign com- 
merce of, 67, 68; position of, among na- 
tions, 73; prices of Japanese bonds 
1903-1912, 77; war prices of Japanese 
bonds, 91; state-operated railways in, 
176. 

Judicial review, of public-service com- 
mission decisions, 232-233. 



3i8 



INDEX 



Laws: constitutional, in regard to state 
debts, 129-131; Massachusetts, in re- 
gard to creation and payment of local 
debt, 143-146; comparison of Massa- 
chusetts, with those of other States in 
regard to local debt, 146-152; Sherman 
Anti-Trust Law, 262-267; Clasrton 
Anti-Trust Law, 267-272; Federal 
Trade Commission Law, 267-268, 272- 
282; railroad, 305-307. 

Legalty of issue: of state bonds, 131; of 
municipal bonds, 157-158. 

Length of time to run : of state bonds, 131; 
of county, municipal, and district bonds, 
150-151. 

Liberia, government loans in default, 59. 

Literacy: of nations, 63; by States, 135- 
136. 

Loaning credit: of States, 131 ; of counties, 
mimicipaUties, and districts, 149-150. 

Local debt: early, in France and the 
United States, x; proportions between 
county, dty and school district, 159; in 
1913, 159; proportions between national, 
state and, 159. 

Los Angeles, local regulation of public- 
service corporations in, 233. 

Louisiana, debt history of, 125-127. 

Market for bonds, 3. 

Maryland, debt history of, 103-104. 

Massachusetts: debt record of, 128; stat- 
utory provisions in regard to local debt 
in, 143-146; comparison of Massachu- 
setts laws with those of other States in 
regard to creation of local debt, 146- 
152; limiting debt and removing tax 
limit in, 148; purposes for which county, 
municipal, and district bonds are issued 
in, 144-146, 148-149; length of time 
which municipal bonds may run in, 144- 
146, 150; method of paying local debt 
in, 151; street-railway, gas and electric- 
light franchises in, 205; early state com- 
missions in, 208; municipal ownership 
and operation in, 234. 

Memphis, Tennessee, defaults by, 155, 
156, 297-298, 302. 

Metropolitan Street Railway Company, 
New York, reorganization of, 246-248. 

Mexico: special security for certain bonds, 
6; government loans in default, 58, 59. 

Michigan, debt history of, 106-107, 



Michigan Telephone Company, reorgani- 
zation of, 241-242, 246, 248. 

Middlesboro, Kentucky, default by, 154, 
300, 302. 

Military position of nations, 64. 

Minnesota, debt history of, iio-iii; de- 
cisions in, rate cases, 170-172. 

Mismanagement of local finances, 157. 

Mississippi, debt history of, 108-109. 

Missouri, debt history of, 127-128. 

Monopoly: recognition of, in cases of pub- 
lic-service corporations, 202, 203-204, 
209. 

Monopoly control: combination and, 261; 
competition and, 267; capitalization of, 
267, 285, 287, 288; machinery for pre- 
venting, 282-283; certain experiences 
in, 284-285. 

Mortgage: real-estate, 2; first, bonds, 162, 
163; consolidated, bonds, 162; general, 
bonds, 162. 

Mxmidpal bonds: definition of, 140; 
means of recovery on defaulted, 140; 
certain factors governing safety of,i4o- 
141, 152-153, 157; laws in regard to is- 
sue of, in Massachusetts, 143-146; com- 
parison of Massachusetts laws with 
those of other States in regard to issue 
of, 146-152; purposes of issue of, 144- 
146, 148-149; issue of, for improper or 
unwise purposes, 149-150; length of 
time which bonds may run, 144-146, 
150-151; vote of people to authorize, 
151; payment of, by sinking fund or 
serial method, 151; amount and char- 
acter of population important factors 
in safety of, 152-153; leading munici- 
pal securities in the United States, 
153; record of, 153-157; causes of 
default in, 154-155, 297-303; cases of 
bad faith with, 155; settlements made 
with bondholders on defaulted, 155- 
156, 297-303; mismanagement of local 
finances, 157; commission form of gov- 
ernment, 157; legality of issue and certi- 
fication as to genuineness, 157-158; in- 
crease in issue of, 158-159; increasing 
issue of, to acquire pubUc utilities, 159; 
prices of, 1902-1912, 160; war prices 
of, 160-161; safety of, 161. 

Municipal ownership and operation: possi- 
ble municipal purchase of public utili- 
ties, 159, 214-21S, 234; in Massachu- 



INDEX 



319 



setts, 234; in other States, 234-235; in 
Europe, 235-236; wisdom of, in the 
United States, 236. 

National income: compared with debt 
charge, ig, 20; growth in, of leading 
nations, 26. 

Nations: no legal remedy against default- 
ing, 6; can borrow for any purpose, 6; 
racial origin of the leading modem, 9; 
changes in leadership among, 9-10; 
growth in population of, 20-23; growth 
in wealth of, 23-26; growth in income of, 
26; growth in debts of, 26-29; forms of 
government of various, 58, 60-63; char- 
acter of population of, 63 ; military posi- 
tion of, 64; economic position of, 64-65; 
trade position of, 66; foreign commerce 
of, 66-68; invisible trade balance, 68- 
71; lending, 70; situation of the leading, 
71-73; reduced expenditures necessary 
for national solvency, 85-86; status of, 
after the war, 86-87. 

Net earnings: of railroads, 169-170, 240; 
of public-service corporations, 240; and 
receiverships of railroads, gas and elec- 
tric companies and industrials, 240; of 
industrial concerns, 240; in 1903 and 
1904, 253; 1907 and 1908, 254; 1913 and 
1914, 255; of industrial concerns for 
three periods, 308-309. 

New Hampshire, statement by Public- 
Service Commission, of proper treat- 
ment of depreciation in estimating 
value as a basis for rates, 225-226. 

New York State: debt record of, 128; 
favorable factors affecting credit of, 
136-137; basis on which public-ser- 
vice consolidations are permitted in, 
214; regulation of issue of securities 
of public-service corporations in, 230- 
231. 

North Carolina, debt history of, n8- 
119. 

Northern Pacific Railroad Company: 
causes of failure of, 167; summary of 
reorganization of, 187; what security- 
holders received in reorganization of, 
190; relation between foreclosure price 
and debt of, 187, 192; market value of 
new securities received in reorganiza- 
tion of, 193. 

Notes, short term, 163. 



Ohio, debt record of, 128. 

Operation: possible government, of rail- 
roads in the United States, 173-175; re- 
sults of state, of railways in Europe, 
175-176; municipal, of public-service 
corporations in Massachusetts, 234; 
municipal ownership and, of public- 
service corporations elsewhere in the 
United States, 234-235; municipal 
ownership and, of pubHc-service cor- 
porations in Europe, 235-236; munici- 
pal, of public utilities and govern- 
ment, of railroads, 236; possible ad- 
vantages and disadvantages of large- 
scale, of industrial concerns, 259-261; 
successful and unsuccessful large-scale, 
of industrial concerns, 261; certain ex- 
periences in large-scale, 284-285. 

Original cost method in estimating value 
as a basis for rates, 220. 

Overhead charges, allowance for, in esti- 
mating value as a basis for rates, 226- 
227. 

Ownership: government, of railroads, 173- 
17s; two forms of government, of rail- 
roads, 173; extent of government, of 
railroads, 174; arguments in favor of 
government, of railroads, 174-175; ar- 
guments against government, 175; re- 
sults of state operation in Europe, 175- 
176; regulation vs. government, 177; 
municipal, of public-service corpora- 
tions in Massachusetts, 234; municipal, 
of pubUc-service corporations elsewhere 
in the United States, 234-235; mimici- 
pal, of pubUc-service corporations in 
Europe, 235-236; municipal, of public 
utihties more feasible but less necessary 
than government ownership of raihoads, 
236; govenmient, of telephone lines, 
237-238; government, of water-power 
developments, 238. 

Paraguay, government loans in default. 

Peace, possible basis of, 84-85. 
Pennsylvania, debt history of, 103. 
Peru, government loans in default, 59. 
Pittsburg, Pennsylvania, defaults by, 154, 

156, 298-299, 302. 
"Plain" bonds, 162. 
Population: of leading nations, 15-16; 

growth in, of leading nations, 20-23; 



320 



INDEX 



character of, important in estiffiating 
national credit, 63 ; amount and increase 
of, by States, 1900-1910, 132, 133; 
color of, by States, 1900-1910, 132, 134; 
literacy of, in the United States, 13s, 
136; an important consideration in 
safety of local debt, 152-153; amoimt 
and character of, important factors in 
estimating safety of public-service cor- 
poration bonds, 202-203. 

Prices: of government bonds, 7, 74-76, 77, 
91-93; of state bonds, 137-139; of muni- 
cipal bonds, 160-161; of railroad bonds, 
196; of public-service corporation 
bonds, 198-199, 250; of industrial bonds, 
293-294. 

Promotions: corporate, and reorganiza- 
tions, 284; purposes of industrial, and 
consolidations, 284. 

Public: relation of railroads to the, 169- 
170; relation of public-service corpora- 
tions to the, 204, 238-239; relation of 
telephone companies to the, 237-238; 
relation of water-power developments 
to the, 238; relation of industrial con- 
cerns to the, 258; corporations subject 
to control of the, 262. 

Public properties: value of state, 98; value 
of local, 158. 

Public-service commissions: regulation of 
railroads by State, 169; establishment 
of early, 208; establishment of modem, 
208; present, having jurisdiction over 
street railway, gas, electric light and 
power and telephone companies, 210- 
212. 

Public-service corporations : issue of muni- 
cipal bonds to acquire public utilities, 
149, 159; origin and development of 
business done by, 199-202; points of 
similarity in different classes of, 202; 
monopolistic character of, 203-204; 
franchises of, 204-207; regulation by 
state commissions of, 207-208; present 
state commissions having jurisdiction 
over, 209, 210-212; leading principles of 
state regulation of, 209, 213-232; recog- 
nition of monopoly principle, 209; cer- 
tificates of pubUc convenience and ne- 
cessity, 2og, 212-213; consolidations of , 
213-214; possible municipal purchase 
of, 214-215; valuation of, as a basis for 
rates, 220-230; state vs. local regulation 



of, tsS't Uniform Utilities Bill, 233; 
mimidpal ownership of, 234-236; bread 
relation of, to the people, 238-239; 
stability of gross earnings of, 239; net 
earnings and receiverships of, 240; re- 
ceiverships and reorg^iizatlons of, 240- 
248; summary of situation of, 248; finan- 
cial plan of, should be broad, flexible, 
and firm, 249-250. 

Public-service corporation bonds: princi- 
pal classes of, 198; prices of some lead- 
ing, 198-199; size and character of com- 
munity served an important factor in 
safety of, 202-203; ratio of debt to as- 
sets of, 203; how regulation by state 
commissions affects safety of, 208; ex- 
amples of strong, 248-249; prices of, 
250; war prices of, 250; final test of, 250. 

Purpose of issue: of government bonds, 6; 
of state bonds, 94, 129-131; should be 
of a strictly public character, 129, 148- 
149; of county, municipal, and district 
bonds, 144-149; unwise or improper 
purposes, 149-150. 

Quasi-municipal corporations, 142. 

Racial origin of leading modem nations, 9. 

Railroad bonds: definition of, 162; various 
kinds of, 162; payable from property or 
earnings, 163; certain factors governing 
safety of, 163, 195; remedies for non- 
payment of, 163; a popular mediima of 
investment, 164; conditions to be con- 
sidered before investing in, 164-165; de- 
faults on, 165 ; examples of strong, 195- 
196; prices of, 196; war prices of, 196. 

Railroads: beginning and growth of, 164; 
growth in mileage of, 164, 166; competi- 
tion of, 165, 256; gross income of, 165, 
239; subject to conflicting regulation, 
165; cost of financing and operating, 
165; receiverships and reorganizations 
of, 165-166; leading causes of railroad 
troubles, 166; difficulties of, since 1893- 
98, 166, 168; failmes of various, 166, 
167; summary of causes of railroad 
troubles, 168; establishment of Inter- 
state Commerce Commission, 168; in- 
crease in powers of the commission, 
168-169; regulation of, by state legisla- 
tures and public-service commissions, 
168-169; relation of, to the public, 



INDEX 



^n 



169-170; arbitration of wages on, 170; 
Regulation by States of issues of securi- 
ties, 170; possible exclusive control of, 
by Federal Government, 170; Minne- 
sota rate cases, 170-172; Shreveport 
rate cases, 172; comparison of Minne- 
sota and Shreveport cases, 172; federal 
licensing or incorporation of interstate, 
i72-i73;govemment ownership of, 173- 
17s; government ownership and opera- 
tion of, in Europe, 17-18, 175-176; 
regulation of, 177-180; regulation of, in 
Great Britain and Ireland, 177; regula- 
tion of, in France, 177-178; regulation 
of, in Europe, 178; outline for exclusive 
federal regulation of all, in the United 
States, 178-180; supervision of securi- 
ties of, 179-180, 232; regulation of, rates, 
179-181 ; rates should be reasonable and 
compensatory, 180; bases of rate-mak- 
ing, 180; limits of high and low railroad 
rates and ideal rate, 180-181; federal 
valuation of, 181-183; valuations of, 
made by certain States, 183, 184; possi- 
ble result of federal valuation of, 183; 
suggested railroad reforms, 183, 185; 
objects of proper regulation of, 185 ; two 
periods of reorganizations of, 185-186; 
reorganization of Atchison, Topeka & 
Santa F6 Railroad Company, 187, 188, 
193; Union Pacific Railway Company, 
187, 189, 193; Northern Pacific Rail- 
road Company, 187, 190, 192, 193; 
Baltimore & Ohio Railroad Company, 
187, 191, 193; relation between fore- 
closure price and value of property, 187, 
192; rights of minority bondholders 
in foreclosure, 192; capitalization of 
American and European, compared, 
194; passenger rates of American and 
European, compared, 194-195; freight 
rates of American and European, com- 
pared, 194-195; comparison of efficiency 
of American and European, 194-195; 
magnitude of railroad industry, 196- 
197; gross and net capitalization of all, 
197; importance of service performed 
by American, 197; should be subject 
to federal regulation, 197; laws, 305- 

307- 
Railways, origin and development of 

street and electric, 199-200. 
Rate-making: bases of railroad, in the 



United States, 180; principles of, for 
public-service corporations, 218. 

Rates : regulation of railroad, 1 79-181 ; rail- 
road, should be reasonable and compen- 
satory, 180; bases of railroad rate-mak- 
ing, 180; limits of high and low railroad, 
and ideal rate, 180-181; comparison of 
American and European passenger, 194- 
19s; comparison of American and Eu- 
ropean freight, 194-195; railroads are 
entitled to fair, 197; regulation of pub- 
lic-service corporation, by state commis- 
sions, 215; interrelationship of service 
and, of public-service corporations, 217; 
authority of commissions over, of pub- 
lic-service corporations, 218; bases of, 
for public-service corporations, 218- 
219; fair return on fair value of prop- 
erty, 219; rate of retittn for public-ser- 
vice corporations, 219; variable rate of 
return, 219; valuation of public-service 
corporations as a basis for, 220-230; 
summary of valuation as a basis for, 
229-230. 

Real estate: advantages and disadvan- 
tages of, as an investment, 2; mort- 
gages, 2. 

Receiverships: railroad, 165-168, 240; 
public-service, 240; industrial. 240; net 
earnings and, of railroads, gas and elec- 
tric companies and industrials, 240. 

Reforms, suggested railroad, 183, 185. 

Refunding bonds, 150. 

Regulation: railroad, by Interstate Com- 
merce Commission, 168-169; railroad, 
by state legislatures and public-service 
commissions, 169; state, of issues of new 
railroad securities, 170; of American rail- 
roads by Federal Government alone, 
170; govemmehtownership w., 177; rail- 
way, in Great Britain and Ireland, 177; 
of railways in France, 177-178; of rail- 
ways in Europe, 178; outline for exclu- 
sive federal, of all interstate railroads, 
178-180; of railroad rates, 179-181; rail- 
roads should be subject to federal, r97; 
of public-service corporations by state 
commissions, 207-208; leading princi- 
ples of state, of public-service corpora- 
tions, 209, 213-232; principal sources of 
material used in discussing state, of 
public-service corporations, 209; of rates 
and service by state commissions, 215; 



322 



INDEX 



of service, 213-217; of rates, 218-230; 
fair return on fair value of property, 
219; rate of return, 219; fair value of 
property, 220; of capitalization of pub- 
lic-service corporations by state com- 
missions, 230-232; supervision of ac- 
coiuits and ordering of reports of public- 
service corporations, 232; state w. local, 
of public-service corporations, 233; of 
telephone lines by Federal Govenmient, 
237-238; of water-power companies, 
238. 

Reorganizations: railroad, 185-194; two 
periods of raflroad, 185-186; general 
summary of two periods of railroad, 186; 
assessments in railroad, 186, 188-191; 
earlier railroad, less effective than later, 
186; Atchison, Topeka & Santa F6 Rail- 
road, 187, 188, 1Q3; Union Pacific Rail- 
way, 187, 189, 193; Northern Padfic 
Railroad, 187, 190, 192, 193; Baltimore 
& Ohio Railroad, 187, 191, 193; factors 
determining apportionment of new se- 
curities in railroad, 192 ; market value of 
securities received in certain railroad, 
192-194; public-service, 240-248; Mich- 
igan Telephone Company, 241-242, 246, 
248; Chicago Union Traction Company, 
24r, 243, 244, 246, 248; Hudson River 
Electric Power Company, 243, 245, 246, 
248 ; Metropolitan Street-Railway Com- 
pany, 246-248; summary of four pubhc- 
service, 246, 248; corporate promotions 
and, 284; industrial, 289-292; aim of in- 
dustrial, 289; total capitalization in rail- 
road, 289-290; total capitalization in 
industrial, 289-290; fixed charges in in- 
dustrial, 290; treatment of bondholders 
in industrial, 290; sacrifices made by 
bondholders in certain industrial, 290- 
292; sumtmary of industrial, 292. 

Replacement, cost of, theory, 220. 

Reports: ordering of, of public-service cor- 
porations by state commissions, 232; 
may be asked by Federal Trade Com- 
mission, 274, 277. 

Reproduction new, cost of, theory, 220. 

Repudiation, attitude of the people to- 
ward, 128-129, 156. 

Russia: prices of Russian bonds, 1913, 7; 
racial origin of, 9; outline of history of, 
13-14; population, wealth, and debt of, 
15-1 7 ; assets offsetting national debt of. 



18; national debt charge compared with 
national income, 20; national debt 
charge compared with total government 
expenditure, 21; growth in population 
of, 22, 23; growth in wealth of, 25; in- 
crease in debt of, 27, 29; debt history 
of, 49-sr; form of govenmient in, 62; 
character of population of , 63; military 
position of, 64; economic position of, 
65; foreign commerce of, 67, 68; posi- 
tion of, among nations, 73; prices of 
Russian bonds, 1873-1912, 77; cost of 
present war to, 76, 78; total losses of 
present war up to July 31, 1915, 79; 
war loans put out since beginning of 
present war up to October 23, 1915, 
82, 83: war prices of Russian govern- 
ment bonds, 91, 92. 

St. Clair County, Missouri, default by, 
IS4, 156, 299, 302. 

Santo Domingo, government loans in de- 
fault, 59. 

Securities: American, held abroad, 69-70, 
90; of colonial and foreign countries 
held by Great Britain, 65, 68-69, 70, 
88-89, 9°; foreign and colonial, held by 
France, 65, 70, 72, 88, 89, 90; foreign 
and colonial, held by Germany, 70; 
foreign, held in the United States, 70- 
71; supervision of railroad, 179-180; 
approval of public-service, 230-232; 
wisdom of commission control of the 
issue of public-service, 231-232; pub- 
licity method of control of issue of, 232. 

Service: regulation of, by state commis- 
sions, 215; three leading elements of, 
215; safety of, 215-216; extent of, 216; 
joint use of facilities by public-service 
corporations, 216; character of, 216- 
217; other principles in regulation of, 
217; regulation of, should be efficient 
and flexible, 217; interrelationship of, 
and rates, 217; cost of, as a basis for 
rates, 218-219. 

Sherman Anti-Trust Law: enactment 6f, 
262-263; leading provisions of the, 263; 
enforcement of the, 263; early interpre- 
tation by the United States Supreme 
Court of the, 264-265; early interpreta- 
tion a departure from common law, 
264-265; later interpretation by the 
Supreme Court of the, in the Standard 



INDEX 



323 



Oil and American Tobacco cases, 265- 
267; grounds of decisions in Standard 
Oil and Tobacco cases, 265-266; evi- 
dence on which decisions were based, 
266; decisions in Standard Oil and To- 
bacco cases brought to a workable 
basis, 266-267; in regard to exports, 
270. 

Short-term notes, 163. 

Short-term paper, i. 

Shreveport rate cases, decisions in, 172. 

Sinking fimds: national, of France, 31, 32; 
national, of Great Britain, 34, 33, 37, 
38; national, of the United States, 44, 
46; of Russia, so; of Germany, ss', of 
Japan, 56; municipal, 151; industrial, 
258. 

South Carolina, debt history of, 119-121. 

Special assessment bonds, 140. 

State bonds: description of, 94; purpose of 
issue of, 94, 129-131; collection of de- 
faiilted, 04; factors determining safety 
of, 94-95, 137; certification of, 131; 
vote of people to authorize, 131; length 
of time to run, 131; examples of general 
considerations governing safety of, 136- 
137; prices of, 1872-1912, 137-138; war 
prices of, 138-139; most important fac- 
tor determining safety of, 139. 

States: early borrowing by our, x; debt 
statements of various, 95-97; percent- 
age of net debt to assessed valuation for 
all, 98, 99; changes in total debts of all, 
98-100, loi ; debt histories of all default- 
ing, 100-128; constitutional restrictions 
on debt making of, 129-131; amount 
and increase of population by, 132-133; 
population by color by, 132, 134; liter- 
acy by, 135-136; regulation by, of is- 
sues of new railroad securities, 170. 

Statutory limitations in regard to creation 
and payment of local debt, 143-152. 

Stocks: as a channel of investment, i; na- 
ture of, 2; classes of, 2. 

Supreme Court of the United States: on 
valuation as a basis for rates, 221-222, 
223, 224, 226; on valuing land, 223; on 
pavement over mains, 224; on depreda- 
tion, 226; interpretation of the Sherman 
Anti-Trust Law by the, 264-267, 272; 
appeal to the, in enforcement of Clayton 
Act, 272; in enforcement of Federal 
Trade Commission Act, 273. _ ^, 



Tax limits, 148. 

Telephone: origin and development of the, 
industry, 201-202; relation of, com- 
panies to the public, 237-238; report of 
Postmaster-General of the United 
States on telegraph and telephone lines, 
237; ownership or regulation by Federal 
Government of, lines, 237-238. 

Tennessee, debt history of, 124-125. 

Terminal bonds, 163. 

Texas, debt history of, 111-112; favorable 
factors affecting credit of, 137. 

Tourist expenditures, 68, 69, 70, 88. 

Trade position of nations, 66^71. 

Trust legislation: Sherman Anti-Trust 
Law, 262-267; Clayton Anti-Trust Law, 
267-272; Federal Trade Commission 
Law, 267-268, 272-282; existing anti-, 
283. 

"Trust question": origin and develop- 
ment of the, 258-259; true solution of, 
282. 

Turkey, government loans in default, 59. 

Uniform Utilities Bill, 233. 

Union Pacific Railway Company: cause of 
failure of, 167; relation between fore- 
closure price and debt, 187; summary of 
reorganization of, 187; what security- 
holders received in reorganization of, 
189; market value of new securities re- 
ceived in reorganization of, 193. 

United States: early government borrow- 
ing in the, x; early state and local loans 
in the, x; development of the bond busi- 
ness in the, x; government bonds of 
the, 5; prices of bonds of the, 1913, 7; 
racial origin of the, 9; development of 
the, 10; population, wealth, and debt of 
the, 15-17; assets offsetting national 
debt of the, 17; national debt charge 
compared with national income, 19, 20; 
national debt charge compared with 
total government expenditure, 19, 21; 
growth in population of the, 22, 23; 
growth in wealth of the, 24, 25, 26; in- 
crease in national income of the, 26; in- 
crease in debt of the, 27, 29; debt history 
of the, 41-49 ; form of government in the, 
58, 60; character of population of the, 
63; military position of the, 64; eco- 
nomic position of the, 65; domestic com- 
merce of the, 66; foreign commerce of 



324 



INDEX 



the, 67, 68; payments by the, to settle 
foreign trade, 69; American securities 
held abroad, 69-70, 90J foreign invest- 
ments of the, 70-71; position of the, 
among nations, 71; prices of bonds, 76, 
77; war prices of bonds, 93. 
Uruguay, government loans in default, 
59- 

Valiiation: assessed, for all States, 1912- 
1913, 98, 99; relation between true 
value of property and assessed, 98; as- 
sessed, of coimties and incorporated 
places, 141; assessed, and net debt of 
local communities, 141; federal, of rail- 
roads, 181-183; factors to be considered 
in federal, of railways, i8i; not conclu- 
sive in making rates, 182; benefits to 
be derived from, of railroads according 
to Mr. Prouty, 182; summary of rail- 
way, 182-183; railroad, made by certain 
States, 183, 184; possible result of fed- 
eral, 183; of public-service corporations 
as a basis for rates, 220-230; leading 
theories of, as a basis for rates, 220; 
original cost theory, 220; cost of repro- 
duction theory, 220; cost of replace- 
ment theory, 220; best modem practice 
favors considering all elements in de- 
termining fair value as a basis for rates, 
221-222; United States Supreme Court 
on, as a basis for rates, 221-222; 
methods of treatment of certain de- 
tails of, 222-223; land, 223; United 
States Supreme Court on valuing land, 
223; present vs. unit prices, 223-224; 
pavement over mains, 224; United 
States Supreme Court on pavement 
over mains, 224; treatment of depreda- 
tion, 224-226; United States Supreme 
Court on depredation, 226; overhead 
charges, 226-227; development expense 



or going concern value, 227-228; good- 
will, 227; franchise value, 228-229; sum- 
mary of, as a basis for rates, 229-230. 

Value: fair, of property, 219, 220; allow- 
ance for overhead charges in estimating, 
226-227; going concern, or develop- 
ment expense, 227-328; franchise, 228- 
229. 

Venezuela, government loans in default, 
S9- 

Virginia, debt history of, 1 14-1 17. 

Vote of people: to authorize state bonds, 
131; to authorize county, mimidpal, 
and district bonds, 151. 

Voting trusts, 192. 

War: estimated direct cost of present war, 
76-77, 78-79, 80-81; comparison with 
cost of previous wars, 80; total losses of 
present, to date, 79-80, 81; loans, 81- 
84; possible basis of peace, 84-85; ne- 
cessity of reduced expenditures, 85-86; 
status of nations after the, 86-87. 

War prices: of government bonds, 91-93; 
state bonds, 138-139; munidpal bonds, 
160-161; railroad bonds, 196; public- 
service corporation bonds, 250; indus- 
trial bonds, 294. 

Water companies, 198. 

Water-power developments, relation of, to 
the public, 238. 

Wealth: estiinated,of leading nations, 15- 
17; growth in, of leading nations, 23-26. 

West Virginia, debt history of, 11 7-1 18. 

Wisconsin: franchises in, 205; basis on 
which public-service consolidations are 
permitted in, 214; regulation of service 
by. Commission, 215; Commission on 
determining fair value as a basis for 
rates, 221; amount allowed by. Commis- 
sion for overhead charges in estimating 
iaii value, 227. 



CAMBRIDGE . MASSACHUSETTS 
U . S . A